American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2013, 103(3): 129–134 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.3.129

Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater during Periods of Slack? Evidence from Twentieth-Century Historical Data† By Michael T. Owyang, Valerie A. Ramey, and Sarah Zubairy* A key question that has arisen during recent debates is whether government spending multipliers are larger during periods of slack. Some researchers and policymakers have argued that while government spending multipliers are estimated to be modest on average, they might become greater during times when resources are underutilized. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012, forthcoming)—henceforth, AG—test this hypothesis and find larger multipliers during recessions in both quarterly post-World War II US data and in annual cross-country panel data since 1985. Their findings suggest multipliers near zero during expansions but between 1.5 and 2 during recessions. Fazzari, Morley, and Panovska (2012) confirm these findings using different methods and measures of slack in US data since 1967. Gordon and Krenn (2010) find that multipliers are larger before mid-1941 than after in their analysis of US data from 1919 to 1953. In addition, numerous cross-state analyses estimate bigger multipliers during periods of slack. On the other hand, Crafts and Mills (2012) analyze ­government spending multipliers in UK data from

1922 to 1938—a period of considerable slack— yet find multipliers between 0.5 and 0.8. This paper contributes to this debate by using newly constructed historical data for the United States and Canada to examine whether government spending multipliers are larger during periods of significant slack. The fluctuations in government spending and unemployment during the two World Wars and the Great Depression were large, so data from this period are potentially rich sources of information on time variation in government spending multipliers. In contrast to some of the previous findings, we do not observe higher multipliers during times of slack in the United States. For Canada, we find evidence for multipliers that are substantially higher during periods of slack in the economy. I. Data

We construct historical data for both the United States and Canada on GDP, the GDP deflator, government spending, population, and the unemployment rate. We choose to use quarterly data, which requires interpolation, rather than annual data, because agents often react quickly to news. As the online data Appendix outlines, we use various higher frequency series to interpolate existing annual series. In addition, we use narrative methods to extend Ramey’s (2011) “news” variable reflecting changes in the expected present value of government spending in response to military events. We extend the series back in time for the United States and construct a preliminary news series for Canada based on events around WWII and the Korean War. Because of data availability, our sample extends from 1890:I to 2010:IV for the United States and from 1921:I to 2011:IV for Canada. Our measure of slack is the unemployment rate. For the United States, we use 6.5 percent as the threshold based on Bernanke’s recent announcement about policy. This results in

* Owyang: Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166-0442 (e-mail: [email protected]); Ramey: Department of Economics, University of California, San Diego, 9500 Gilman Drive, La Jolla, CA 92093-0508 (e-mail: [email protected]); Zubairy: Bank of Canada, 234 Wellington St., Ottawa, ON K1A OG9 (e-mail: [email protected]). The authors thank Robert Barro and Gordon Liao for use of their Canadian newspaper excerpts; Michelle Alexopoulos for providing us with some of the historical Canadian data; and Alan Blinder for alerting us to discrepancy in an earlier version of the data. We are also grateful to Oscar Jorda and Garey Ramey for very helpful suggestions and to Kate Vermann for research assistance. The views expressed herein should not be taken to be the official opinions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Bank of Canada. † To view additional materials, and author disclosure statement(s),visit the article page at http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.3.129. 129

130

MAY 2013

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS News (percent of GDP)

News (percent of GDP) 60

60

40

40 20

20

0

0 1900

1920

1940

1960

1980

1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

2000

Unemployment rate

Unemployment rate

20

15

15

10

10

5

5 1900

1920

1940

1960

1980

2000

1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Year

Year Figure 1. US Unemployment and Military Spending News

Figure 2. Canadian Unemployment and Military Spending News

Note: Shaded areas indicate time periods when the unemployment rate is above the threshold.

Note: Shaded areas indicate time periods when the unemployment rate is above the threshold.

o­ ne-third of the observations being above the threshold. For Canada, we use 7 percent; even with the higher threshold 50 ­ percent of the observations are above the threshold. Figures 1 and 2 show the unemployment rate and the military spending news shocks for the two countries. As Figure 1 shows, the largest military spending news shocks are distributed across periods with a variety of unemployment rates in the United States. For example, the largest news shocks about World War I and the Korean War occurred when the unemployment rate was below 6.5 ­percent. In contrast, the initial large news shocks about WWII occurred when the unemployment rate was still very high. Formal tests indicate that the news variable has significant explanatory power and high instrument relevance for government spending in the United States, overall and separately across the two unemployment states. The Canadian data extend back only to 1921, and, thus, do not include WWI. Figure 2 shows that the initial large news shocks of WWII occur when the unemployment rate is still elevated, but later ones arrive when the unemployment rate is quite low. All of the Korean War news shocks occur when the unemployment rate is low. Formal tests suggest that the preliminary military

news v­ariable for Canada has somewhat lower explanatory power and instrument relevance than for the United States. II.  Econometric Method

Following AG (forthcoming), we use Jordà’s (2005) local projection technique to calculate impulse responses. This method easily accommodates state dependence and does not impose the implicit dynamic restrictions involved in VARs. We estimate a set of regressions for each horizon h as follows:

[ 

(1) ​zt+h ​ ​ = ​It−1 ​ ​ ​ ​α​A h​ + ​ψ​A h(​​  L )​​yt​−1​

]

new​st​​ + ​Ω​A h(​​  L )​​g​t−1​ + ​βA h ​ ​ ​ _ ​     ​ ​Yt−1 ​ ​



+  (1 − ​I​t−1​)

[ ​



​ αB h ​ ​ + ​ψB​  h​​( L )​​yt​−1​

]

new​st​​ + ​Ω​B h​​( L )​​g​t−1​ + ​βB h  ​ _ ​​    ​  ​   ​Y​t−1​

+  quartic trend + ​εt​​.

VOL. 103 NO. 3

Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater During Periods of Slack?

z is a function (discussed below) of either real per capita GDP (​  Y )​or government spending (G), y and g are the logs of these variables, and “news” is the change in the expected present value of government spending caused by m ­ ilitary events. h is the horizon, and the functions of L denote polynomials in the lag operator. I is a dummy variable that takes the value of one when the unemployment rate is above a threshold. We allow all of the coefficients (except those on trend terms) to vary according to whether the unemployment rate is above (“A”) or below (“B”) the threshold. The shock we identify is to the news variable. As an illustration of the method, we estimate the two-quarter-ahead impulse response of z by regressing ​z t+2 ​ ​on the variables on the right-hand side of equation (1). We use the estimate of β ​ ​A, 2​ for the high unemployment rate state and ​β​B, 2​ for the low unemployment rate state. We estimate separate regressions for output and government spending at each horizon h. The standard way to define the z is as the log of real GDP and government spending. However, the calculated impulse response functions do not directly reveal the government spending multiplier because the percent changes must be converted to dollar equivalents. Virtually all analyses using VAR methods obtain the spending multiplier by using an ad hoc conversion factor based on the sample average of Y/G. Our investigations reveal that this widely used method can lead to biases in multiplier estimates. In particular, we find that this method often generates multipliers greater than unity even when auxiliary specifications show that private spending falls when government spending increases. This bias occurs because the ratio of Y/G varies greatly over the sample period we consider. Thus, we instead use the variable definitions of Hall (2009) and Barro and Redlick (2011) that convert GDP and government spending changes to the same units. In particular, our ​ ​)/​Yt−1 ​ ​ and z variables are defined as (​Y​t+h​ − ​Yt−1 (​Gt+h ​ ​ − ​Gt−1 ​ ​)/​Y​t−1​. The first variable is approximately equal to ln(​Yt+h ​ ​) − ln(​Y​t−1​) and, hence, is analogous to the standard VAR specification. The second variable can be rewritten as ​G​t+h​ − ​Gt−1 ​Gt+h ​ ​ − ​Gt−1 ​ ​ _ ​ ​ _ ​Gt​−1​ (2) ​ _      ​     · ​     ​  = ​   ​  ​Yt−1 ​ ​ ​Yt−1 ​ ​ ​Gt−1 ​ ​

​Gt​−1​ ​ ​) · ​ _ ​    ≈ (ln ​Gt​+h​ − ln ​Gt−1 ​Yt−1 ​ ​

131

GDP

Government spending 0.8 0.6

0.7

0.5

0.6 0.5

0.4

0.4 0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2 0.1

0.1

0 5

10

15

20

0

Quarter

5

10

15

20

Quarter

Figure 3. US Response of Government Spending and GDP to a News Shock Equal to 1 percent of GDP, Linear Model Note: Grey areas are 95 percent confidence intervals.

Thus, this variable converts the  percent changes to dollar changes using the value of G/Y at each point in time rather than the average over the entire sample. This means that the coefficients from the Y equations are in the same units as those from the G equations, which is required for constructing multipliers. It would be difficult to perform this variable transformation if we were using standard VAR methods to compute impulse responses; it is easy to do so in the Jordà framework. III. Results

Figure 3 shows the responses of government spending and output to a military news shock in the linear model using the US data. The bands are 95 percent confidence bands and are based on Newey-West standard errors that account for the serial correlation induced in regressions when the horizon h > 0. After a shock to news, output and government spending begin to rise and peak at around 12 quarters. Multipliers are derived from the estimated​ β​A, h​ and ​βB, h ​ ​ from the Y and G equations. We compute multipliers over three horizons: as the cumulative responses through two years, four years, and at the peaks of each response. As indicated in the first column of the top panel of

132

MAY 2013

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS Table 1—Estimated Multipliers

Government spending

Linear High Low model unemployment unemployment (1)

(2)

(3)

United States   2 year integral 0.72   4 year integral 0.81  Peak 0.88

0.76 0.78 0.83

0.72 0.88 0.93

Canada   2 year integral 0.67   4 year integral 0.79  Peak 0.57

1.60 1.16 0.65

0.45

0.7

0.4

0.6

0.35

0.5

0.44 0.46 0.49

0.3

0.4

0.25

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.15 0.1

0.1

Note: The integral measures are computed as the ratio of the sum of coefficients from the Y and the G equations. The peak measure is the ratio of the coefficients at their respective peaks.

0.05

0

0

−0.1 5

10

Quarter

Government spending

GDP

15

20

5

10

15

20

Quarter

Figure 5. Canada Response of Government Spending and GDP to a News Shock Equal to 1 percent of GDP, Linear Model

1.4 1.2

Note: Gray areas are 95 percent confidence intervals.

0.7

1

GDP

0.8

0.6

0.8

0.5 0.4

0.6

0.3 0.4

0.2

0.2

0.1 0

0 5

10

Quarter

15

20

−0.1

5

10

15

20

Quarter

Figure 4. US Response of Government Spending and GDP to a News Shock Equal to 1 percent of GDP, State-Dependent Model Notes: Solid lines are responses in the high unemployment state; lines with circles are responses in the low unemployment state. Ninety-five percent confidence intervals are shown.

Table 1, the implied multipliers are below one and range from 0.7 to 0.9. These results are consistent with those of Barro and Redlick (2011) and Ramey (2011). The key question of this paper is whether the linear model masks a higher multiplier during times of slack. Figure 4 shows the responses when we estimate the state-dependent model. Similar to many preexisting studies (e.g., AG

forthcoming), we find that output responds more robustly during high unemployment states. However, note that government spending also has a stronger response during those particular states. Consequently, columns 2 and 3 of Table 1 show that some of the implied multipliers are slightly lower during the high unemployment state in the US data and are always below unity. These results are not due to our particular specification, for we find similar results if we use other unemployment values for the threshold, use a smooth transition threshold model as in AG (2012, forthcoming), or use the standard log variables for the dependent variables. In addition, we find that when we apply the Jordà method to AG’s (2012) post-WWII data, based on either shocks to news or government spending, there is no significant difference in the responses across states. Further investigation is necessary to understand why the Jordà method, used by AG (forthcoming) on a panel of countries, produces results that are different from the STVAR model used by AG (2012) on US data. Figure 5 shows the results for the linear model using the Canadian data. Both government spending and output rise in a sustained manner, though the estimated government spending responses are rather erratic. As the first column

VOL. 103 NO. 3

Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater During Periods of Slack? GDP

Government spending 1

0.7 0.6

0.8

0.5 0.6 0.4 0.4

0.3

0.2

0.2 0.1

0

0 5

10

15

20

5

Quarter

10

15

20

Quarter

Figure 6. Canada Response of Government Spending and GDP to a News Shock Equal to 1 percent of GDP, State-Dependent Model. Note: Solid lines are responses in the high unemployment state, lines with circles are responses in the low unemployment state. Ninety-five percent confidence intervals are shown.

133

using newly constructed historical data for the United States and Canada. Using Jordà’s (2005) local projection method, a threshold model based on the level of the unemployment rate, shocks to military news, and definitions of variables that obviate the need for ad hoc conversion factors, we find no evidence that multipliers are higher during periods of slack in quarterly US data from 1890 to 2010. In all states, multipliers appear to be between 0.7 and 0.9. In contrast, estimates using quarterly Canadian data from 1921 to 2011 indicate that multipliers are typically greater during periods of slack. The multipliers are around 0.5 during the nonslack state but are above unity during the slack state at many horizons. It is important to point out, though, that because we do not adjust for the fact that taxes often rise at the same time as government spending, these estimated multipliers are not necessarily equal to pure deficit-financed multipliers. In addition, our measure of spending is government purchases, which does not include transfers, so our analysis does not shed light on transfer payment multipliers. REFERENCES Auerbach, Alan J., and Yuriy Gorodnichenko.

of Table 1 shows, the implied multipliers are below unity in the linear model. Figure 6 shows the results from the statedependent model. The responses of government spending and GDP are not very different for the first two years across states but then diverge starting in the third year when both government spending and GDP climb significantly in the high unemployment state. Table 1 shows that the implied multipliers are greater during periods of slack in Canada. For example, using the multipliers based on the integral through two years, the value is 1.6 when the initial shock hits during the high unemployment state in contrast to only 0.44 when it hits in the low unemployment state. Thus, the Canadian estimates suggest that multipliers are substantially greater in the high unemployment state. The exact values depend on the horizon since the estimated responses tend to be erratic. IV. Conclusions

We have investigated the proposition that multipliers are greater during periods of slack

2012. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2): 1–27.

Auerbach, Alan J., and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. Forthcoming. “Fiscal Multipliers in Reces-

sion and Expansion.” In Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis, edited by Alberto Alesina and Francesco Giavazzi. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Barro, Robert J., and Charles J. Redlick. 2011. “Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 51–102. Crafts, Nicholas, and Terence C. Mills. 2012. “Rearmament to the Rescue? New Estimates of the Impact of ‘Keynesian’ Policies in 1930s Britain.” Unpublished. Fazzari, Steven M., James Morley, and Irina Panovska. 2012. “State-Dependent Effects of

Fiscal Policy.” Unpublished.

Gordon, Robert J., and Robert Krenn. 2010.

“The End of the Great Depression 1939–41: Policy Contributions and Fiscal Multipliers.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 16380.

134

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS

Hall, Robert E. 2009. “By How Much Does GDP

Rise If the Government Buys More Output?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 183– 231. Jordà, Òscar. 2005. “Estimation and Inference of Impulse Responses by Local Projections.”

MAY 2013

American Economic Review 95 (1): 161–82.

Ramey, Valerie A. 2011. “Identifying Govern-

ment Spending Shocks: It’s All in the Timing.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 1–50.

Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater during Periods of Slack ...

Page 1. 129. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2013, 103(3): 129–134 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.3.129. A key question that has arisen during recent debates is whether ... To view additional materials, and author disclosure statement(s),visit the article page at http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.3.129.

647KB Sizes 0 Downloads 221 Views

Recommend Documents

Keynesian government spending multipliers and ...
The European spending plans would result in a reduction in private sector spending for con- ..... would even have an incentive to go slow on domestic stimulus while encouraging other countries, ..... Reduction in health insurance contributions.

What determines government spending multipliers?
bi,t-1: beginning-of-period debt stock, expressed as a share of GDP fci,t-1: dummy variable indicating a financial crisis ..... C is twice as much. Response of I strengthens over time. ▷ Current account worsens, real depreciation. ▷ Policy mix: i

Keynesian government spending multipliers and ...
Research Network electronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1705013. ..... than the sustained stimulus advocated by advisers of the U.S. administration. ..... European Monetary System with policy focused on German targets to a monetary ...

Government Spending Multipliers under the Zero Lower ...
Aug 28, 2017 - This result is consistent with the tests conducted on U.S. data by Ramey and ..... Evidence from the American Recovery and Rein- vestment ...

Zero Lower Bound Government Spending Multipliers ...
Jan 10, 2018 - change in the fiscal experiment that accounts for the large changes in government spending multipliers. 1 ... Firms face quadratic price adjustment cost following Rotemberg (1982). Their optimal pricing behavior yields ... The model ca

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in ...
of modest multipliers in aggregate data, often below unity. ..... have advantages. ... big government spending shocks hitting the economy when there was not much .... estimate state-dependent fiscal models, employing it in their analysis of ...

Government Spending and Interest Rates
Sep 25, 2017 - public-sector credit demand be Bs = (1 − γ)G. Then a weakly negative ...... externality on TFP. Next, define the natural rate of interest to be: rn.

Government Spending and Interest Rates
Apr 5, 2018 - bates about the merits and consequences of austerity. If spending shocks stimulate output without tightening credit markets in the short-run, ...

Output Response to Government Spending
Abstract: Using 25 years of military spending data for more than a hundred countries, ...... from large outliers and observations that appear to be data entry errors.

The Effects of Government Spending under Limited Capital Mobility ...
Conditioning on more home bias in government spending, a fixed exchange ...... 11Ilzetzki and Vegh (2008), using data of 27 developing countries, obtain ...

Government fragmentation and public spending ...
table 1. For the sake of simplicity, in this example I assume that pre and post-ban elections are identical except for the ban of Batasuna. Figure A in table 1 shows the ... Table 1: Example: Total, Mechanical and Behavioral Effects ...... of absolut

Government Spending Composition, Technical Change ...
Business Research in 1982, and the Federal Technology Transfer Act in 1986); and ... price competition11 at all dates, which implies that in equilibrium only the top ... e− ∫ s t r(τ) max (θ − γ,0)wH(s)ds, with 0 < γ < 1/2. The ability para

When is the Government Spending Multiplier Large?
monetary shock, a neutral technology shock, and a capital-embodied technology .... Firms The final good is produced by competitive firms using the technology,.

When is the Government Spending Multiplier Large?
Consequently, the Taylor rule would call for an increase in the nominal interest rate so that the zero bound would not bind. Equation (3.8) implies that the drop in ...

Understanding the Size of the Government Spending Multiplier: It's in ...
May 2016. Abstract. Despite intense scrutiny, estimates of the government spending ..... impulse responses may be different depending on the state of the business ..... trend for each variable.18 The error bands cover 90 percent of the posterior ...

Government Spending in a Simple Model of ...
types of capital, and the model can be extended, along the lines of. Lucas (1988), Rebelo .... ment owns capital and the national accounts omit an imputed rental income on ...... ern Business Cycle Theory, edited by Robert J. Barro. Cambridge ...

The Effects of Government Spending under Limited Capital Mobility ...
spending concentrates more on traded goods, part of the increased demand for ...... spending stimulates economic activity mainly through the demand-side effect. ...... business-cycle implications of exchange-rate management,” Carnegie- ...

Government Spending, Shocks, and the Role of ...
provided in the online appendix. The last year ... federal aid could generate an income effect that results in a greater demand for state-level expen- ditures. Also ...

Understanding the Size of the Government Spending Multiplier: It's in ...
meterizing the impulse response functions with a small number of Gaussian functions, which offers effi ...... (contractionary) multiplier was close to linear: For small business cycle ..... Evidence from 20th Century Historical Data" American Eco-.

Understanding the Size of the Government Spending ...
and Zubairy, 2016) contains larger and more numerous positive shocks than negative ... (according to our results) do not depend on the state of the business cycle. ..... trend for each variable.20 The error bands cover 90 percent of the posterior ...

Explaining the Effects of Government Spending Shocks
varying degree of success in qualitatively matching the response of a few variables of ..... where ait is aggregate absorption of good i and includes cit, git and iit.

Understanding the Size of the Government Spending ... -
do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond and San ...... (contractionary) multiplier was close to linear: For small business cycle ...