Combatant Recruitment and the Outcome of War Ahmed Saber Mahmud Johns Hopkins University

Juan F. Vargas Universidad del Rosario

Abstract What determines who wins a civil war? We propose a simple model in which the power of each armed group depends on the number of combatants it is able to recruit. This is in turn a function of the relative ‘distance’ between the group leadership and potential recruits. We emphasize the moral hazard problem of recruitment: …ghting is costly and risky so combatants have the incentive to defect from their task. They can also desert altogether and join the enemy. This incentive is stronger the farther away the …ghter is from the principal, since monitoring becomes increasingly costly. Bigger armies have more power but less monitoring capacity to prevent defection and desertion. This general framework allows a variety of interpretations of what type of proximity matters for building strong cohesive armies ranging from ethnic distance to geographic dispersion. Di¤erent assumptions about the distribution of potential …ghters along the relevant dimension of con‡ict lead to di¤erent equilibria. We characterize these, discuss the implied outcome in terms of who wins the war, and illustrate with historical and contemporaneous case studies.

We are grateful to Johannes Münster, two anaonymous referees and participants at the WZB 2008 Conference on Causes and Consequences of Con‡ict. We thank Hend Alhinnawi for useful research assistance. Contact: [email protected], [email protected]

1

1

Introduction

In the early 1980s the Shining Path launched an insurrection in Peru with the support of thousands of peasants. After an initial retreat, the army’s counterattack in 1984 was led by the deadly Rondas Campesinas militias. Widespread fear created by the Rondas led to massive desertions of insurgents from the Shining Path. This pattern soon became self-enforcing and the rebel group eventually lost the war to the government. Civil war in Peru lasted less than two decades and within that window it witnessed the sudden change from the rebels’relative success to their de…nite defeat. Almost two decades before the onset of the Peruvian war, a low scale con‡ict was already maturating in Colombia with the formation of two rebel groups: FARC and ELN. Like its Andean neighbor, the Colombian government also promoted the formation of paramilitaries in the 1980s to contend the rapid expansion of the guerrillas. However, neither side ever generated sizable levels of desertion nor were them able to secure enough manpower to dominate the enemy by force. Civil war in Colombia persists to date after over four decades. The average duration of civil wars has increased steadily since the end of the second World War, reaching 16 years in 1999 (Fearon, 2004). This trend suggests an increasing di¢ culty in ending intrastate con‡icts. On the other hand, Toft (2006) argues that two thirds of the circa 120 civil wars that ended between 1940 and 2000 did so by military victory of either party. Why do some societies experience relatively balanced contests without any clear winner in the short run? What determines who wins the war? Why are some countries immune to rebellion? When can the rebels gather enough forces to overwhelm the government? In this paper we think of these questions with a simple model of how the technology of recruitment of combatants determines the outcome of (an existing) war. Our model does not provide an account of what triggers the onset of con‡ict–whether ethnic cleavages, social grievances, economic opportunity, etc. (see Fearon and Laitin, 2003 and Collier and Hoe- er, 2004 for empirical analyses of the causes of civil war). Rather, we take con‡ict between two parties as given and analyze how the distribution of potential combatants along the most salient con‡ict dimension, whatever it be, together with the monitoring technology available to the groups’ leaderships, shape the likelihood that a speci…c party results victorious. We develop a model that relates this likelihood to the recruitment process and show that one possibility is that no clear winner rises in the short run. In this sense, although the model is not strictly dynamic, it relates to the literature on con‡ict duration.1 In particular, our results are in line with Montalvo and 1 The analysis of the determinants of the duration of civil war has been predominantly empirical. Regan (2002) studied the e¤ect of foreign intervention on civil war termination. Collier et al. (2004) and Fearon (2004) studied the impact of socioeconomic and political factors on the hazard of peace by looking at a di¤erent type of Survival models at the crosscountry level. Montalvo and Reynal Querol (2007) also make use Survival models, but focus their analysis on the impact of ethnic polarization on the duration of war.

2

Reynal-Querol (2007) as polarization makes con‡ict less likely to be resolved in the short run. In this respect, our paper …ts in the broader research agenda of Joan Esteban and Debraj Ray, who have proved that when the population is divided into clusters with respect to some observable characteristic, and present substantial within-group homogeneity but between-group heterogeneity, the resulting polarization is closely linked to the generation of social tensions and violent unrest (Esteban and Ray, 1994 and Duclos, Esteban and Ray, 2004). We build on the rent seeking literature as our model features a contest over an exogenous asset by two groups. The power of each group depends on the number of combatants the group is able to hire vis-a-vis the size of the enemy’s army. By focusing on the recruitment problem, we introduce a moral hazard element to the baseline contest. When violence is at play, compliance is costly and combatants have incentives to shirk. They can also desert altogether and join the rival group. Performance cannot be enforced in court so the resulting relational contract has to be self-enforcing (MacLeod and Malcomsom, 1989). In our model this occurs through two constraints: a no-shirking constraint (a la Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984) and a no-desertion constraint. When met simultaneously, these constraints make the compensation o¤ered to each combatant incentive compatible. Each group starts recruiting at its closest proximity and as the army expands further recruitment takes place farther away. Monitoring then becomes costlier and non-compliance incentives get stronger. Hence, bigger groups have more power but less monitoring capacity to prevent defection and desertion. This general framework opens the ‡oor for a variety of interpretations of what type of proximity matters for building strong and cohesive groups, ranging from ethnic distance to geographic dispersion. These dimensions are also present in Skaperdas (2008), where con‡ict breaks out whenever the State fails to extend the monopoly of violence over the entire territory, which is facilitated by geographic and ethnic distance. While we focus on moral hazard, previous work on recruitment in civil war has also emphasized the problem of adverse selection. Weinstein (2005, 2006) identi…es a rebel "resource curse" by which the abundance of resources facilitates recruitment on the basis of short-term rewards, attracting opportunistic soldiers who lack commitment and are not strongly identi…ed with the cause of the rebellion. The absence of such resources, however, provides the incentives for a much solid recruitment practice, based on ideological commitment and the promise of some kind of reward if longer-term objectives are achieved. The moral hazard problem of recruitment is not a novel idea. It …rst appeared in Polo (1995) who studied how internal cohesion shapes the e¤ectiveness of organized crime enterprises. Gates (2002) draws from Polo’s analysis, but focuses on recruitment in rebellion. In turn, we extend Gates’analysis by looking at the implications of the distribution of potential …ghters along the relevant dimension of con‡ict. Indeed, di¤erent assumptions about the distribution of agents lead to a substantially di¤erent set of equilibria. We characterize the universe of these, discuss the implied outcome in terms of who wins the war and how soon this happens, and illustrate the di¤erent cases with historical and 3

contemporaneous case studies. The paper is organized as follows: In section 2 we present the set up of the model and the set of constraints for recruitment to be incentive compatible. Section 3 characterizes the equilibria that result from di¤erent assumptions about the distribution of agents along the relevant con‡ict dimension, and discusses examples that illustrate our argument. Section 4 concludes and discusses several potential extensions of the model.

2

Set Up of the Model

Consider a continuum of mass 1 of potential combatants distributed over the unit space [0; 1] according to some distribution f (x), which can take any form [Figure 1 illustrates four potential shapes of f (x)]. Two groups: the government G; and a rebels R; …ght every period over the control of an indivisible prize of value K; which could be interpreted as the rents from holding political power.2 The two groups prepare for war by recruiting …ghters from the pool of available potential combatants. For that purpose, each group i 2 fG; Rg o¤ers simultaneously a compensation wi to every recruit in its ranks.3 The expected utility for group i at any given period is: Ui = Si (ni ; nj )K

ni wi

(1)

where Si 2 (0; 1); the probability of defeating the rival, is concave in group i’s military capability, represented in turn by the number of combatants ni , @Si < 0: The second term of (1) emphasizes that group i gives the same while @n j wage wi to every one of its …ghters. This is equivalent to assuming that all recruits have exactly the same skill and that no di¤erential wages can be o¤ered without inducing misbehavior from the underpaid. In this sense, as we will show, the wage of all combatants will be determined by the incentive-compatible compensation of the last …ghter hired. Clearly, group i will recruit combatants as long as the marginal bene…t, @Si @wi 4 @ni K; is not exceeded by the marginal cost, wi + ni @ni : However, both the government and the rebels have to provide a compensation such that their …ghters remain loyal. In particular, in order to ensure compliance we apply to this context the Shapiro-Stiglitz (1984) no shirking condition. 2 The indivisibility of the prize makes it more likely that war occurs even under complete information (Fearon, 1995). In this paper, however, we don’t model the decision on whether to engage in an armed dispute or not. Rather, we take such dispute as given an explore the conditions under which there can be a winner and the determinants of who the winner is. 3 Armed groups in many civil wars often forcibly recruit in addition –or as opposed– to providing material compensations. In this model one can think of w as some sort of subsistence level reward, which does not have to be monetary (but can have some monetary component). Indeed, w may pick up any food, shelter and uniform received by the combatant. The existence of w does not prevent recruitment to be enforced by force. In fact, as it will become clear, in this model non-compliance is punished with death. 4 The latter expression takes into account the feedback e¤ect of the army’s size into wages. We will come back to this issue in more detail.

4

Non-compliance can take a variety of forms including refrainment from carrying out the assigned task; secretly providing information to the enemy, or completely switching sides. Among these potential forms of noncompliance, we consider the …rst and the third possibilities, abstracting from the existence of spies. Compliance is risky since combatants of group i run into the risk of being killed by the enemy, which happens with probability (1 i ): That is, i is the probability that a …ghter from group i survives a clash. Of course, the risk of being killed in combat does not exist if the task is not carried out. However, noncompliance also entails some risk. If left unpunished, a single shirking episode may trigger waves of defection, so we assume that combatants who get caught shirking are executed. Non-compliers are caught with probability (1 pi ): That is, pi is the probability of getting away shirking. Desertion in civil war is widespread and involves not only individuals but also larger groups. Among other reasons, forced recruitment may explain the lack of serious commitment to one’s principal. A large share of the irregular armies across civil wars is composed by conscript soldiers (e.g. child soldiers; Beber and Blattman, 2009). This is so even in cases in which there are additional elements to expect greater cohesiveness like the case of ethnic wars. For example, rebel “turncoats”have been used extensively by incumbent forces in di¤erent con‡icts (Kalyvas, 2006). In our model, shirkers who survive capital punishment can either stay with their current group or desert altogether and join the lines of the enemy.

2.1

Incentive Compatibility

Given a set of compensations W = fwG ; wR g as well a set of probabilities P = f G ; R ; pG ; pR g; …ghters have the choice of whether or not to shirk, s; and if they decide to do so, whether or not to desert, d: The actions of …ghters can be described formally as: s : W P ! f0; 1g and d : W P js = 1 ! f0; 1g: Let 2 (0; 1) be the rate at which the future is discounted. The instantaneous utility of a …ghter of group i who does not shirk can be represented by the value function: V i (s = 0; d = 0) = V i (0; 0) =

wi + V i (0; 0)

i

where s = 0; d = 0 imply that …ghter i neither shirks nor deserts. The expression assumes that the value of being killed by the enemy, which happens with probability (1 i ), is 0: This equation means that a complier who survives receives today’s compensation plus the discounted continuation value. Rearranging: V i (0; 0) =

i wi

1

(2) i

The value of compliance to group i is then increasing in the compensation offered by the group, in the probability of surviving in combat and in the discount rate.

5

Shirkers who are not caught as such can stick to their original army or switch sides. The expected lifetime utility of a shirker is: V i (1; 0) = wi + [pi V i (1; 0)]

(3)

A shirker does not run today into the risk of being killed in combat so she fully enjoys the compensation wi . But tomorrow she can get caught with probability (1 pi ) and get killed, the value of which is 0: As in Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) if the agent escapes punishment the value recurs. Rearranging: V i (1; 0) =

wi 1

(4)

pi

The value of shirking is increasing in the compensation and in the discount factor, but decreasing in the probability of being caught not complying. Shirkers who also desert (s = 1; d = 1) can be hired by the enemy or not.5 Let q = f0; 1g be an indicator for whether hiring occurs (q = 1) and u be the outside option. The most likely scenario for a deserter who gets hired by the enemy is that she becomes a complier to her new group.6 We assume this is the case for analytical tractability. Hence, the expected lifetime utility of a …ghter who, in addition to shirking, deserts is: V i (1; 1) = wi +

pi qV j6=i (0; 0) + (1

q)u

(5)

A deserter is also a shirker so there is no present risk of dying in combat. If she avoids punishment from her original group she may or may not join the enemy. Not being hired gives the …ghter her outside option u: In turn, if she gets hired she will receive the continuation value of a complier V j (0; 0): Substituting (2) –with i = j–into (5) and rearranging: V i (1; 1) = wi + pi q

j wj

1

+ (1

q)u

(6)

j

Because desertion implies shirking, its value is increasing in the wage of the left-behind group. It is also increasing in that of the receiving group, in the probability of escaping punishment, in the probability of surviving a combat against the former comrades and in the discount rate. Recall that hiring a combatant requires that the marginal cost does not exceed the marginal bene…t. In addition, to guarantee that …ghters will stay in and comply, the compensation o¤ered to …ghters needs to be such that the value 5 Deserters are valuable both as informants and to weaken the enemy by promoting further desertions. This is the case, for instance, of Colombian right wing militias who have absorbed many former guerrilla …ghters (Gutierrez, 2004). 6 The intuition of this is twofold. First, deserters who are accepted in new groups are likely to be monitored more than other combatants to reduce the likelihood of enlisting spies. Second, deserters can change group because they are strongly motivated by the ‘cause’of the enemy. This makes it more likely that they comply to their new group.

6

of compliance must be at least as large as the best alternative option, either to shirk or to both shirk and desert: V i (0; 0)

maxfV i (1; 0); V i (1; 1)g

Thus, a necessary condition for a …ghter to be hired by group i is that the no-shirking and no-desertion constraints are met. In short, wi has to be such that the following incentive compatibility condition (ICC) is met:7 i wi

1

max i

wi 1

pi

; wi + pi q

j wj

1

+ (1

q)u

(7)

j

The incentive compatible compensation o¤ered to …ghters by group i is increasing in the probability of getting away shirking, pi ; in the probability of surviving combat against the former comrades if the …ghter joins the enemy, j ; and in the wage paid by the opponent, wj : It is decreasing in the probability of surviving combat given compliance to the current group, i . Our basic set up draws on the principal-agent framework for recruitment laid out by Polo (1995) and followed by Gates (2002). However, in what follows we illustrate how small variations in the recruitment opportunities have radical implications for the outcome of the game. We illustrate the di¤erent potential equilibria with historical and contemporaneous case studies of civil war.

3 3.1

Analysis Equilibrium Wage

Recall that (1 i ) is the probability that a …ghter from group i gets killed in combat. We assume that this probability is increasing in the size of the enemy’s @ i < 0 and army and decreasing in the size of one’s own army. This implies @n j @ i @ni

> 0: Further, we assume that i (ni ; nj ) 2 (0; 1) for all values of ni and nj . That is, there is always a positive probability of surviving and of getting killed. Further, recall that non-compliers can get away shirking with probability pi : What determines such probability? Let zi be the location of group’s i leadership in the unit space and xf the positioning of potential …ghter f: Let jxf zi j be the distance between group i’s leadership and …ghter f (Figure 2): Assume that pfi ;the probability that …ghter f escapes punishment after defecting the task imposed by group i, is an increasing function of such distance. That is @pfi @jxf zi j

> 0. The further away a …ghter is, the more di¢ cult it is to monitor her so it gets easier to shirk and get away with it. There is widespread evidence that geography shapes political allegiance in civil war. Drawing from her …eldwork in Nicaragua, Horton (1998) argues that 7 Note that if the compensation w were exogenous, this set-up would be that of a classical rent-seeking model. Here, however, we endogenize w in the sense that it has to be incentive compatible to ensure compliance.

7

peasants from peripheral regions with scarce military and political presence of the Sandinista state tended to align with the Contras, for their geographical proximity and hence in‡uence. In contrast, in towns with e¤ective state rule, no anti-Sandinista voice was heard. Seidman (2002) refers as “geographical loyalty” the tendency during the Spanish Civil War to side with the camp that controlled the area where one lived in; and Tone (1994) shows that during the Napoleonic occupation, geographical proximity to the French in the Spanish region of Navarra was inversely proportional to participation in anti-French insurgencies. Insurgents were predominantly recruited in frontier towns which the French could not e¤ectively occupy. However, note that in this model ‘distance’is not necessarily a geographical measure. The concept can be interpreted broadly, including for instance ethnic or ideological distance. The strategy space of the group leaderships is very simple. Given the set of probabilities P = f G ; G ; pG ; pR g as well as the location in the unit space of potential …ghter f , and the implied monitoring capacity over her given by the distance jxf zi j, each principal decides whether to o¤er the incentive compatible compensation to all …ghters (from her position up to where f is located), or else refrain from hiring f . We can rewrite the optimal wage contract in (7) as: ) ( wi 1 h pi (jxf zi j) ; i (ni ; nj ) wi i max (n ;n ) w 1 wi + pi (jxf zi j) q 1 j ij (nji ;njj) + (1 q)u i (ni ; nj )

where we make explicit that both group sizes (ni and nj ) and the distance between the group leadership and the last …ghter hired determine all the endogenous variables of the incentive compatibility constraint. These are the probabilities of survival in combat ( i and j ) and the probability of getting away shirking (pi ). Thus the incentive compatible wage is not constant. However, in a static framework like this model compliance is ensured by the fact that the recruitment process takes part only once.

Proposition 1 In equilibrium the wage o¤ ered by group i to its combatants ultimately depends on the number of i’s own …ghters relative to the number of …ghters of the enemy, as well as on the distance between i’s leadership and the last …ghter hired, f : wi = wi (ni ; nj ; jxf zi j) The equilibrium wage o¤ered by group i to a …ghter located at xf increases in nj because the probability of getting killed in combat increases with the size of the enemy’s army. However the e¤ect of an increase in ni on the equilibrium wage is not unambiguous: One the one hand there is a direct e¤ ect whereby the equilibrium wage decreases in ni because the probability of surviving combat increases with the size of one’s own army, so the required incentive-compatible compensation decreases. On the other hand, recall that the wage of all combatants will be determined by the incentive-compatible compensation of the last 8

…ghter hired. The farther away she is from the leader, the easier it is for her to get away shirking and hence the greater the incentive-compatible compensation should be (indirect e¤ ect). The ambiguous e¤ect of ni on the equilibrium wage can be illustrated as follows: @wi @wi d jxf zi j dwi = + (8) dni @ni @ jxf zi j dni |{z} | {z } direct e¤ect (<0)

indirect e¤ect (>0)

The indirect e¤ect can be better illustrated by assuming that R and G are positioned at the extremes of the unit space, respectively at zR = 0 and zG = 1: Consequently, subject to the incentive compatibility constraint [equation (7)], the rebel leadership would like to hire …ghters from xf = 0 onwards (i.e. to the right of the distribution) so as to maximize the detection of shirkers. If it hires all available combatants from 0 up to xf = xR ; the number of combatants hired by the rebel group will be nR = F (xR ); where F ( ) is the cumulative distribution function associated with f (x): Likewise, the government prefers hiring combatants from type xf = 1 onwards (to the left of the distribution). The size of the government army is ultimately: nG = 1 F (xG ) [Figure 3]. Distance is then related to the size of the army and thus more hiring will increase the wage by making monitoring more di¢ cult.

3.2

Recruitment Process

Each leader chooses the number of recruits that maximizes her expected utility, given by equation (1). For leader i this yields: @Ui @Si (ni ; nj ) = K @ni @ni

@wi @wi d jxf zi j + @ni @ jxf zi j dni

wi + ni

where the …rst term of the right hand side is the marginal bene…t and the second (in brackets) the marginal cost. This set-up is equivalent to a duopsony model: the marginal cost adds to the actual compensation the change in it arising from the fact that the leaders are not price-takers. Group leaders will hire combatants as long as the marginal bene…t exceeds the marginal cost, which we hereafter denote: M Ci (ni ; nj ; jxf zi j). The …rst order conditions of the above maximization problem are: @Ui @ni @Ui @ni

= =

@Si (ni ; nj ) K @ni @Si (ni ; nj ) K @ni

M Ci (ni ; nj ; jxf

zi j) = 0

if ni > 0

M Ci (ni ; nj ; jxf

zi j)

if ni = 0

0

Simultaneous maximization of the expected utility by both groups produces the following reaction functions, which we assume negative sloped throughout

9

their support:8 ni =

i (nj )

for i; j = fR; Gg

Further, we assume the reaction functions intersect only once. At the intersection point we have @nGG < @nRG : De…ne ni as the minimum ‘…ghting deterrent’number of combatants of group i: Facing such an army, group j …nds it not pro…table to recruit any combatant (nj = j (ni ) = 0), and group i is quite likely to win the war. Assuming a 1 logistic CSF of the form: Si (ni ; nj ) = 1+exp(n ; this would happen with j ni ) + 1 probability S(n+ ni . i ; 0) = 1+exp( n+ ) , where ni i Critically, we assume that deterrence is only possible if group i hires more than half the total number of potential …ghters: ni > 12 F (1) = 12 : That is, if the leadership of i can hire beyond the median of the distribution. Let xf be the position in the unit space of the last combatant hired to achieve the minimum deterrence. Given the above assumption and the distribution of agents along the unit space f (x):

Proposition 2 i) For a symmetric distribution, jxf zi j > 12 ii) For an asymmetric distribution, jxf zi j can be

3.3 3.3.1

1 2

Distribution Shape and the Outcome of War Symmetric distribution and unique outcome

We …rst consider a case in which the population of potential combatants is distributed symmetrically along the unit space. We use this setting to investigate the conditions for a unique outcome, namely there is no clear winner in the short run. In such case both groups hire combatants but none …nds it optimum to recruit up to the deterrent point, so complete dominance is not possible. Thus, at ni : @Si K < M Ci (ni = ni ; nj = 0; jxf zi j) for i 2 fR:Gg @ni This case can arise, for instance, when there is a rough geography or low ethnic cohesiveness, characteristics that curb the ability to monitor the performance of …ghters. In this case, even if more combatants mean greater …ghting capacity and thus a higher probability of wining, they also imply less monitoring ability. If the indirect e¤ect –as de…ned by equation (8)– o¤sets the direct e¤ect then neither group will …nd it worthwhile to hire the deterrent number of combatants. There are two potential reasons why such outcome can prevail: Case 1 Neither group leadership can e¤ ectively monitor more than half of the total number of …ghters. 8 If we were to assume a standard logistic Contest Success Function (CSF, Hirshleifer, 1 1989) of the form 1+exp(n ; as the functionl form of the probability of defeating the rival, n ) j

i

Si (ni ; nj ); then the reaction funtions can be shown to be negative sloped.

10

Case 2 Even if monitoring is possible, it may not be worth hiring a …ghter. Consider Case 1. When monitoring technology is insu¢ cient to hire …ghters beyond the median, both groups have to be satis…ed only with agents closer to them.9 That is, for group i: jxf zi j 12 for i 2 fR; Gg and all f: Under symmetric distribution this implies, jxf

1 < jxf 2

zi j

zi j;

(9)

were the right hand side inequality follows from the …rst part of Proposition 2. Combatants beyond the median of the distribution cannot be pro…tably employed. This implies that deserters from one group cannot be monitored by the enemy, and hence q = 0: Thus (6) reduces to: V i (1; 1) = wi + pi u and the ICC becomes: i wi

1

wi

max

1

i

pi

; wi + p i u

Here, desertion is avoided altogether (i.e., V i (1; 1) is not binding) whenever wi 1

pi

> wi + pi u

Note that this is equivalent to assuming that the payo¤ from shirking is higher than the outside option, V i (1; 0) > u: For simplicity we make this assumption in this speci…c case and thus rule out desertion as an equilibrium outcome. Note that all we need for this to hold is that the outside option be su¢ ciently small (close to zero, to which we normalize the value of death).10 This is generally the case in civil wars where non-combatants are military objectives of every group that does not acknowledge them as their supporters, which constraints civilians to join either one army or the other (see Vargas, 2009). This assumption implies that the incentive compatible compensation has to o¤set only the value of a non-deserting shirker, or V i (0; 0) V i (1; 0): Rearranging from the ICC, this implies: 1

1 (1

i

pi )

(10) i

9 Employing more …ghters by o¤ering a higher compensation scheme would not be a good strategy. Given the scarce monitoring capacity, the new …ghters (who are farther away from zi ) will have an incentive to shirk. 1 0 This assumption is very likely to hold in civil wars in which armed groups take advantage of negative income shocks to recruit from the a¤ected population. For instance this appears to be the case of the main co¤ee areas in Colombia during the late 1990s’ co¤ee crisis, when the commodity lost 70% of its value in international markets (Dube and Vargas, 2007).

11

However, this does not guarantee that all …ghters lying between the group’s core and the median will be hired. A …ghter f located at xf such that condition (10) is not met, is not employable. Let ni and xf be respectively the number of recruits and the position of the last recruit such that: 1 i 1= 1 pi i where i = i (ni = ni ; nj ) and pi = pi xf zi : Note that beyond xf , group i cannot recruit further since it is not incentive compatible as de…ned by inequality (10). Hence, compared to inequality (9), a stronger condition for a unique outcome under a symmetric distribution, when monitoring is costly is: jxf

zi j

1 < jxf 2

zi j

In short, defection and desertion are not possible if the distribution of …ghters along the unit space is symmetric and there is no recruitment beyond xf : The lack of monitoring capacity imposes an exogenous limit on the number of combatants that the groups can hire. Thus in this case the reaction functions are e¤ectively kinked at a point below the …ghting deterrent level, ni (Figure 4.b). Consider now Case 2. The monitoring technology may well be such that the leadership of group i can hire …ghters beyond the median such that 21 < jxf zi j for i 2 fR; Gg: However, even in this case, group i may not want to hire up to xf if the marginal payo¤ of hiring is lower than the marginal cost, or: @Si K < M Ci (ni = ni ; nj = 0; jxf @ni

zi j)

In this case the reaction curves are no longer kinked, however they intersect at a point where the …ghting deterrent number of …ghters is not achieved by any group: ni < ni (Figure 4.a). Proposition 3 When potential …ghters are distributed symmetrically along the relevant con‡ict dimension such that 12 < jxf zi j; i) If monitoring beyond the median is not feasible, a su¢ cient condition for the unique outcome of the absence of a clear winner in the short run is: jxf

zi j

1 < jxf 2

zi j

ii) A necessary condition is that the marginal payo¤ of hiring the minimum deterrent number of …ghters does not o¤ set the marginal cost (which can happen even if monitoring beyond the median is feasible): @Si K < M Ci (ni = ni ; nj = 0; jxf @ni 12

zi j)

The unique outcome is more likely to occur when distributions are bimodal. That is, this situation arises when the population is divided into sharp clusters, where geographic distance (or ethnic heterogeneity, or political ideology, etc.) is small within clusters but large between them. When tails are thick, it is costlier to attain the minimum force necessary to overcome the rival, ni ; since principals have to recruit farther away from their epicenter (Figure 5). The Role of External Help The distinction between case 1 and case 2 above is subtle but in practice it has very relevant policy implications. Exogenous …nancial support to one group such as foreign aid can lead to very di¤erent conclusions. Consider for example external support in the form of a wage subsidy: 2 (0; 1): Suppose without loss of generality that the subsidy goes to the government, whose expected utility will be: UG = SG (nG ; nR )K

nG wG (nG ; nR ; jxf

zG j)

Note that given this utility, the marginal cost becomes M CG < M CG which shifts G’s reaction function upwards allowing the government to potentially hire more combatants. However, under case 1 additional hiring will not be possible given the limited monitoring capacity, which prevents the number of combatant from reaching the deterrent level (Figure 4d) In contrast, case 2 does give some leverage to external assistance as more resources will allow the government to recruit more …ghters without the constraint imposed by the monitoring technology. With su¢ cient aid, G can eventually deter the rebels from keep …ghting (Figure 4c). Discussion Civil wars featuring relative strong opponents who can conscript su¢ cient forces to sustain intense con‡ict but where armies are not large enough to overwhelm the enemy are common in (ethnically, religiously or politically) polarized societies. It is indeed polarization as opposed to fragmentation what increases the risk of con‡ict (Esteban and Ray, 1994; Montalvo and ReynalQuerol, 2007). In contrast, in homogeneous or more diverse nations it is more di¢ cult for armed groups to build relatively large armies. Polarization creates grievances and secessionist demands which make con‡icts more likely to break. Hence, binomial distributions both in terms of space and some relevant grievance dimension constitute a driving force for sustained con‡ict. Sudan is a classical example of polarization and civil war. The country is polarized along a number of traits including ethnicity, religion and language, and these di¤erences are in fact sharper between the (black, Christian) South and the (Arab, Muslim) North, which constitutes 75% of the population. Public goods provision and development policies were traditionally absent in the South where grievances accumulated for decades, leading to the outbreak of two civil wars: 1962-1972 and 1983-2005 (Ali et al., 2005). 13

In contrast to Sudan and many other African nations Kenya is an ethnically highly diverse country. Kikuyu, the largest tribe, constitutes about a …fth of the population and no other of the many tribes makes up for more than 15% of the population. Such diversity makes it di¢ cult for a single group to organize armed opposition against the central government, even in the existence of grievances. There have been periods in which land issues have led to violence outbreaks, but none of these regional episodes ever escalated into full civil war (Kimenyi and Ndung’u, 2005). Political polarization plays also a role, as illustrated by the case of Colombia. The civil war started in the early 1960s with the formation of largely rural peasant-based guerrillas in peripheral areas where the government had been traditionally absent. In the 1980s military-backed paramilitaries became de facto counterinsurgency units and the con‡ict escalated. Fighting occurs mainly in rural areas where the rebels dispute the control of strategic strongholds with the paramilitary. By 2002 the latter had gained control of over 30% of Colombia’s territory. The polarization of the rural population in terms of compliance to one group or the other (often secured by coercion) has perpetuated the con‡ict and to date no group has secured nation-wide the numbers to shift the balance in their favor and trigger the termination of war (either after some period of asymmetric …ghting or by forcing a political negotiation). Finally, the key role of the geographical concentration of polarized factions is illustrated by the di¤erent political objectives of Chechnya and the Tatar Republic in the Russian Federation. While the two territories are both resource rich and have strong leaderships, the Chechens want to secede and the Tatars do not. According to Toft (2003) what sets them apart is the geography concentration of ethnic groups. Indeed, while only 32% of Tatars live in Tatarstan and most of them are intermingled with ethnic Russians through marriage and other social networks; most Chechens (up to 82%) live in their home region and keep a strong independent identity. This enables rebel leaders to draw su¢ cient recruits to challenge the central power from an adjacent pool of loyal individuals. 3.3.2

Symmetric distribution and multiple equilibria

The unique outcome of unresolved con‡ict is not the only situation that can take place when the distribution of potential combatants is symmetric. We now look at the multiple equilibria case when desertion takes place to an extent that one group secures enough manpower to defeat its adversary. In this case whether R or G is the winner is decided by expectations. Recall that the e¤ect of an increase in the number of …ghters on the wage paid to the army is ambiguous. On the one hand, the probability that a …ghter located at xf survives combat with the enemy increases with the size of her own army (this is the direct e¤ ect). On the other hand, more …ghters can only be hired farther away from the leadership’s core and this induces higher wages due to lower monitoring ability (indirect e¤ ect).

14

If the direct e¤ect dominates so that: @wi d jxf zi j @wi > @ni @ jxf zi j dni then a bigger army translates into lower wages. If this is the case, given the symmetry of the game, multiple equilibria can take place. This happens because there are increasing returns from recruitment. In this situation, if potential (as well as actual) …ghters believe group i will win the war they will align with i even if this implies deserting from group j: Unlike the previous case where both groups fail to recruit enough manpower to defeat the enemy, here in principle both armed groups should be able to recruit beyond the median of the distribution because they have the monitoring ability to do so. Whether R or G will end up enlisting the deterrent number of …ghters and winning the war is contingent on expectations. Formally, Lemma

A necessary condition for multiple equilibria to exist is: jxf

zi j

xf

zi

To see this notice that if the contrary were true such that jxf zi j > xf zi ; group i would only be able to hire at best ni < ni : But, by de…nition ni is the minimum army size necessary to decimate the opponent. So with an army of ni group i can never win. On top of monitoring feasibility, …ghters have to be pro…tably hired at ni ; @Si which implies: @n K M Ci (ni = ni ; nj = 0; jxf zi j): i Proposition 4 When potential …ghters are distributed symmetrically along the xf zi , there relevant con‡ict dimension such that 12 < jxf zi j; If jxf zi j will be a multiplicity of equilibria if and only if: @Si K @ni

M Ci (ni = ni ; nj = 0; jxf

zi j)

The reaction functions in this case are still downward sloping but their slopes di¤er from the former set of diagrams in that @nGG > @nRG . Instead of ensuring stability at the unique intersection, this creates divergent paths up to a point in which either the government achieves n; or the other does (Figure 4e). For a given monitoring technology, this condition is more likely to be met for distributions which have more density around the median (Figure 6). With such a distribution, the recruitment cost of hiring up to the deterrent level becomes lower. This logic is similar to that of models of democratic politics with swing voters. In these models, undecided voters who can ultimately support one party or the other turn out to be decisive for the political outcome. Similarly, in our model combatants can desert their army and join the former enemy to create a decisive imbalance of power, allowing one group to secure n …ghters and hence win the war. Which of the two equilibria will prevail depends on the expectations of the combatants around the median. If they believe that 15

group i is likely to win, their expectations become self-ful…lling. In contrast, the multiple equilibria outcome is less likely for more polarized distributions as illustrated in the previous subsection. Note that we do not attempt here to model a dynamic process which allows for some transition between the two equilibria. Even if our set-up is one of an in…nitely repeated game, our results are static in the sense that wages are stationary (since they do not depend on the history of the game) and the distribution of the potential …ghters is …xed. But recruitment into armed groups is a dynamic phenomenon and from this perspective a more realistic model would be one that introduces a truly dynamic component. For instance, an unstable environment can be created by allowing the two principals to interact. We leave this extension for future work. Such model would be able to illustrate when the population can at all go back and forth between the two equilibria. Our present analysis only lays down the necessary conditions for the existence of such transition. Discussion Russell (1974) illustrates our point eloquently: "(...) [N]o mass rebellion can succeed without defection of some of the regime’s armed forces. (...) [R]evolutionaries (...) must devote a great deal of thought to how to encourage defections from the police and the army." The analysis in this subsection characterizes a fundamentally unstable state of a¤airs. Dominance by one party can be reversed quickly. To enable such massive swing, the majority of the society must constitute a sizeable population who is not ‘close’ to neither of the warring extremes, thus it is somewhat in the middle. Even though the existence of such cases of multiple equilibria are not uncommon, the very lack of irreversibility makes them less prone to make it into the highlights of history. Nevertheless, we discuss some examples where, arguably, the outcome of revolutions was in‡uenced by expectations-driven massive desertions. Tilly (1973) describes how in Sicily in the 19th century, after the closing of University in 1848, student protests led to small gatherings. This initiated further demonstrations that ended up with a few deaths. Soon, a full rebellion spread out and most of the island came to be under the control of the students. The end of the rule of the incumbent government was established when the liberal bourgeois and aristocrats joined the movement. The triumph was, however, short-lived as the revolutionary coalition failed to maintain its cohesiveness to run the state. By 1849, the bourgeois and aristocrats abandoned the revolutionary cause helping the old government return. The liberal bourgeois and aristocrats were the critical mass of ‘swingers’whose support determined the fate of the Sicilian Revolution.

16

In the early 1980s the Shining Path launched an insurrection in Peru with the support of thousands of discontent peasants.11 After an initial retreat, the army’s counterattack in 1984 was led by the deadly Rondas Campesinas militias. Widespread fear created by the Rondas led to massive desertions of insurgents from the Shining Path as well as informants and collaborators from the peasantry. This pattern soon became self-enforcing and the rebel group eventually lost the war to the government. Civil war in Peru lasted less than two decades and within that window it witnessed the sudden change from the rebels’relative success to their de…nite defeat. Something similar happened during the Zapatista Revolution in early 20th century Mexico. Wolf (1973) describes the appearance in 1910 of a coalition of diverse groups of Mexicans who collectively rebelled against Por…rio Diaz. At the time, Diaz’rule was increasingly despotic and the opposition was furiously quieten. It was the combination of the speed of the outbreak and the diversity of groups represented by the coalition of rebels that made the revolution a successful one. The Revolution was carried out by both the peasantry and disa¤ected intellectuals with urban ties. Led by Emilio Zapata, it started at Morelos, a sugar-growing area where pre-colonial customs remained fairly intact. Sugar requires a large number of workers on a seasonal basis. The interplay of this production structure and the little colonial in‡uence allowed the peasantry to remain cohesive and independent. A second hub of rebellion soon appeared in the north: much less integrated than the south to the prevailing socioeconomic structure, and where land inequality and banditry fed the discontent that made of the region one of the hottest spots of the Revolution. This was fueled by the ‡ow of arms and ammunition smuggled by the revolutionary leader Pancho Villa from the Unites States despite the existing embargo (Katz, 1998). However, these clusters had primarily regional in‡uence and that was not enough to overturn Diaz’ rule. Even if they could swiftly destroy the prevailing political structure, they could not establish a new order as easily. A third force …nally broke the deadlock: twenty six thousand men deserted from the constitutional army and joined the rebels, leading them to a …nal victory. This was the ‘swing middle’that made the decisive triumph possible. The Cuban Revolution of 1959 illustrates an interesting paradox as it was neither a peasant nor a feudal society, like those that characterize other societies where rebellions took place. Instead, Cuba was mainly composed by wage earners working for a large foreign-owned sugar plantation. There was no, however, a domestic entrepreneurial class or a middle class for that matter. The seasonal nature of the sugar cane demanded intense short-term activity together with prolonged periods of hunger. Such cycle fueled deep grievances against the government of Batista (Zeitlin, 1967). 1 1 The massive support was evident in 1982 with the attendance of up to 30,000 people to the funeral of guerrilla leader Edith Lagos, killed by the government’s forces (Huston, 1988).

17

While the pre-revolutionary government was a loose coalition serving the interest of the United States, the opposition was never coherent enough to truly challenge it either. This created a political deadlock that left the Batista regime e¤ectively unchallenged by any party that could address the growing social unrest. In the late 1950s Fidel Castro centralized the armed opposition and moved the center of the rebel activity to Sierra Maestra, a remote area distant from Havana where grievances against the government where widespread. When rebellion grew in strength it was gradually supported by the working class; and when it took momentum some loyals to the Batista regime deserted to support the insurgents. Indeed, the guerrilla army itself never constituted more than 2,000 combatants and so it could not have carried out the revolution without the support of others. This came in the form of …nancial aid as well as passivity towards the attempts by the government of suppressing the rebellion. 3.3.3

Asymmetric distribution

Consider the case in which potential …ghters are distributed asymmetrically along the unit space. Suppose recruitment is not pro…table beyond the median 1 such that xf zi 2 for i 2 fR; Gg: If the distribution was right-skewed and 1 1 hence F 2 < 2 ; the Rebel leadership (located at zR = 0) would have smaller pool of potential …ghters to hire from. Hence, even if the Government cannot 1 recruit from the other half of the distribution so that xf zG 2 , it may be able to reach enough manpower within its circle of (incentive-compatible) in‡uence to defeat the Rebel group. This will happen when: Z 1 1 f (x)dx > nG > 2 xG However, this is only a su¢ cient condition. It is necessary that the Govern@SG ment …nds it pro…table to hire nG : @n K M CG (nG = nG ; nR = 0; jxf zG j); G @SR and the Rebel …nds it not pro…table to hire nR : @n K < M CR (nR = nR ; nG = R 0; jxf zR j): So the only equilibrium under this case is when the government dominates. Thus, when the majority of potential …ghters is closer to the Government (and recall that this is not necessarily a geographical statement) a successful rebellion is unlikely. Naturally, if the distribution is left-skewed so that F 12 > 12 ; the same logic used above would make the Rebel much likely to win (Figure 7). Hence, Proposition 5 When the pool of potential …ghters is distributed asymmetrically so that jxf zi j can be less than or equal to 12 ; group i will win if: @Si K @ni

M Ci (ni = ni ; nj = 0; jxf

18

zi j)

while, @Sj K < M Cj (nj = nj ; ni = 0; jxf @nj

zj j)

Under asymmetric distributions the population on the left and the right to the median are no longer the mirror image of one another. This implies that armed groups do not have equal access to recruits so, in contrast to the previous two cases, here one party can obtain a dominant position. In sum, if the Government is ‘close’to the majority of the population, any attempt of revolution can easily be thwarted. If it maintains a su¢ cient distance, however, a successful revolution will become more imminent. Discussion Why some societies are prone to rebellions while others seem to be immune has been studied by Moore (1966): "A highly segmented society that depends on di¤use sanctions for its coherence and for extracting surplus from the underlying peasantry is nearly immune to peasant rebellion. On the other hand, an agrarian bureaucracy or a society that depends on central authority for extracting the surplus, is a type most vulnerable to such violent outbursts.” This quotation suggests that strong centralized governments generate distance from the peasantry, thereby enabling the rebels to recruit from the periphery. In contrast, maintaining close ties with the villagers makes it more di¢ cult to create a viable opposition. This dichotomy is evident in the divergent fate of 16th and 17th century England and France. Even though both nations had centralized administrations, their governments di¤ered with respect to the power of the landed elite. While the gentry, who owned 75% of the land in England, dominated local politics and constrained the power of the king, the French monarchy excluded the landlords from power. As a consequence peasants in France were largely free and able to organize in communes, but that was not the case of their British counterparts who remained tenants (Skocpol, 1979). This di¤erence shaped the nature of the monarchy in both nations. In France the peasants were able to mobilize themselves with relative ease and mount a rebellion. In England, however, the unrest of the peasants was easily contained due to the proximity of the landlords to the hubs of rebellion and their …rm grip on the local communities. Hence, while the French Revolution marked the eve of the French monarchy, in England the Glorious Revolution was a con‡ict between di¤erent factions of the landed class and its outcome was the creation of the Parliament. Similar di¤erences existed between Germany and Russia. While the Junker landlords kept German peasants under close watch, the 1861 agrarian reform gave peasants in Russia the opportunity to gather in communes (called ‘Mir’) and buy land from the nobility. Between 1877 and 1917, the share of land

19

owned by peasants rose from 32% to 47%. The nobility, who was allied with the state, lived mostly in the cities and was not in control of the rural periphery. The success of the 1917 Russian Revolution owes to some extent to such lack of control and the distance separating the peasants and the government (Skocpol, 1979). This contrast is also evident when we compare the history of China and Japan in the wake of the 20th century. Generally, the pre-revolutionary Chinese sociopolitical structure was one of a centralized authority with rural villagers under the command of the local gentry. An exception was northern China, where the power of the landed elite was weaker which helped the communist party to secure the support of local villagers by implementing land reform and progressive taxation. Indeed, the …rst front of the ‘Red Army’was constituted by northern peasants and rural proletariats. Even though imperial Japan had strong central administration and the advent of commerce withered the power of traditional landowners, the country was designed to serve the interest of the imperial rule. There, in sharp contrast to the case of China, villagers maintained a close link with the landowners: A Japanese village was also a community in symbiosis with the prevailing authority. In this sense, the ‘distance’between the peasants and potential rebels was larger than the distance between the peasants and the landlords. Indeed, despite numerous sporadic rebellions during the Tokugawa period, an epoch making revolution like the Chinese Communist Revolution failed to exist.

4

Conclusion

Many scholars have sought to explain why revolutions seem to have mostly taken place in peasant societies rather than industrial settings. According to Calhoun (1988), peasant societies retain the social capital that overcomes free rider problems and hence facilitate rebel movements. In contrast, urban workers in industrial clusters lack such ties and such movements become less likely. In contrast, Moore (1966) emphasizes the absence of the monopoly of violence inherent to primarily agrarian societies. To Wolf (1973), in turn, revolutions get momentum when capitalism has attenuated the power of rural landlords, weakening traditional elites. This paper brings forth a potentially complementary explanation. Here, what matters for a successful revolution is the relative support of the (exogenously distributed) population. This is so regardless on whether the con‡ict is driven by ethnic, religious, ideological, class, or political grounds. Relating our model to the discussion above, because industrial labor is primarily urban, it is close to both capitalists and the government. This proximity to the ‘incumbent’ leaves little room for a rebel leadership to form a critical mass of recruits without avoiding the wrath of the establishment. On the other hand, if the rebels can recruit successfully and monitor a large army, a successful rebellion is more likely and hence the transformation of society. As exempli…ed by the cases of Northern Mexico and China, geographical distance plays a crucial role. These

20

places became hot-spots for recruitment precisely because they are distant from the center. If the peasantry however remains in close association with the landed elite, as in Japan during Tokugawa period, rebellion becomes an unlikely event. In addition, when both the government and the rebel leadership can garner moderate support from di¤erent segments of the society, the con‡ict is less likely to be resolved in the short run. This is the case of the long-lasting, low intensity Colombian civil war. Yet in some other cases, massive expectationdriven shifts in loyalty from one principal to the other may be decisive for victory. Indeed, not all successful revolutions were carried-out entirely by the frontier residing peasantry. In the Mexican case, the …nal victory was achieved by a civilian-military coalition. Algeria followed a similar suite. Even though the anti-colonial movement started from village-level recruitment of rebels, it was the external support of the armies of Tunisia and Morocco that gave the decisive push to the revolution (Wolf, 1973). Such cases illustrate how a defecting group or an external power can strengthen the rebel movement. We only treat the case of external support tangentially in our model (section 3.3.1) but it is a natural extension that in future research should be considered in more detail. We motivate our analysis with the example of two parties …ghting over an indivisible good (e.g. ruling a country). However, the same framework can be extended to analyze the secessionist con‡icts. Spolaore (2008) argues that secessions are more likely if there are high heterogeneity costs, low economies of scale and the seceding region is larger. The latter condition relates to our emphasis on the necessity for the armed parties to garner enough support for their cause. There are a few other potential extensions to the theory presented here. Indeed, recruitment in civil war is to date largely understudied (with the exceptions of Gates, 2002 and Weinstein, 2006) and this paper can be considered part of a greater research agenda on the microfoundations of civil con‡ict. In section 3.3.2 we mention the possibility of a more dynamic model that would allow for explicit interactions between the two principals. Several other avenues for future research can be pointed out. First, in the present model the distance between principals and agents is exogenously given. It would be interesting to illustrate, in the case of a potential class-con‡ict, how the distribution of land and the presence of inequality can endogenize the distance to the principals. This will also explain the opportunity cost of joining the rebellion for each individual in terms of her land holdings. Relatedly, the position of the government and that of the rebel leader are exogenously …xed in this model, and the distance between the two groups is normalized to one. An interesting expansion would have the position of the principals as a decision variable. Second, in this model the population can only …ght. However, the outside option, u; could be explicitly modelled, for instance, by introducing a production economy and hence the opportunity for the citizens to decide whether to join one armed group or work productively (as in Grossman 1991). Further, in the current model the principals do not have a budget constraint. Resources are implicitly assumed to be unlimited and the only constraints are the no-shirking and no-desertions conditions. A budget constraint can be introduced, for instance, by having each 21

principal control some natural resource which provides an exogenous endowment. We abstract from this in order to emphasize the underlying moral hazard problem of recruitment. Indeed, introducing natural resources to the model can potentially bring interesting insights, especially if one allows for these to be predated by the other party. However, this would turn the focus of the paper from the substantive problem of moral hazard in recruitment of soldiers to that of the existence or not of some sort of "resource-curse". Likewise, the model abstracts from potential incentive compatibility problems of the principals. The promise to pay the incentive compatible wage, for instance, is assumed to be credible but in reality such promise may depend on, for example, whether the principal is winning or loosing the war.

5

References

Ali, Ali Abdel Gadir, Ibrahim A. Elbadawi and Atta El-Batahani (2005). “Sudan’s Civil War: Why Has it Prevailed So long?" in Collier, Paul and Nicholas Sambanis, Understanding Civil War Volume 1: Africa. The World Bank. Beber, Bernd and Christopher Blattman (2009). "The Industrial Organization of Rebellion: The Logic of Forced Recruitment and Child Soldiering" unpublished manuscript. Calhoun, Craig J. (1988). "The Radicalism of Tradition and the Question of Class Struggle", in Taylor, Michael (Ed.), Rationality and Revolution. Cambridge University Press. Collier, Paul and Anke Hoe- er (2004)."Greed and Grievance in Civil War" Oxford Economic Papers 56: 663-595 Collier, Paul, Anke Hoe- er and Måns Söderbom (2004). "On the Duration of Civil War" Journal of Peace Research 41(3): 253-273. Duclos, Jean-Yves, Joan M. Esteban and Debraj Ray (2004). "Polarization: Concepts, Measurement, Estimation" Econometrica 72: 1737-1772. Dube, Oeindrila and Juan F. Vargas (2007). "Are All Resources Cursed? Co¤ee, Oil, and Armed Con‡ict in Colombia" Working Paper 2007-1, Weatherhead Center for International A¤airs, Harvard University. Esteban, Joan M. and Debraj Ray (1994). “On the Measurement of Polarization” Econometrica 62: 819-852. Fearon, James (1995). "Rationalist Explanations for War" International Organization 49(3): 379-414. Fearon, James (2004). "Why Do Some Civil Wars Last So Much Longer Than Others?" Journal of Peace Research 41(3): 275-302. Fearon, James and David Laitin (2003) "Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War" American Political Science Review 97(1): 75-90. Gates, Scott (2002). "Recruitment and Alliance: The Microfoundations of Rebellion". Journal of Con‡ict Resolution, 46(1): 111-130. Grossman, Herschel (1991). "A General Equilibrium Model of Insurrections” American Economic Review 81(4): 912-921.

22

Gutierrez, Francisco (2004). "Recruitment in a Civil War: A Preliminary Discussion of the Colombian Case". Working Paper, Santa Fe Institute. Hirshleifer, Jack (1989). "Con‡ict, Rent Seeking and Success Functions: Ratio vs. Di¤erence Models of Relative Success" Public Choice 63 (3): 101-112. Horton, Lynn (1998), Peasants in Arms: War and Peace in the Mountains of Nicaragua, 1979-1994, Ohio Center for International Studies. Huston, James V. (1988). "Insurgency in Peru: The Shining Path" available at: http://www.globalsecurity.org/military/library/report/1988/HJV.htm (last access 10/24/09). Kalyvas, Stathis (2006). The Logic of Violence in Civil War. Cambridge University Press. Katz, Friedrich (1998). The Life and Times of Pancho Villa. Stanford University Press. Kimenyi, Mwangi S. and Njuguana S. Ndung’u (2005). “Sporadic Ethnic Violence: Why Has Kenya Not Experienced a Full-Blown Civil War?” in Collier, Paul and Nicholas Sambanis, Understanding Civil War Volume 1: Africa. The World Bank. MacLeod, W. Bentley and James M. Malcomson (1989). "Implicit Contracts, Incentive Compatibility, and Involuntary Unemployment" Econometrica 57(2): 447-480. Montalvo, Jose G. and Marta Reynal-Querol (2007) "Ethnic polarization and the duration of civil wars" Unpublished manuscript. Moore, Barrington (1966). Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Beacon Press, Boston. Polo, Michele (1995) "Internal Cohesion and Competition Among Criminal Organisations" in Gianluca Fiorentini and Sam Peltzman (Eds.) The Economics of Organised Crime, Cambridge University Press. Reagan, Patrick (2002). "Third Party Interventions and the Duration of Intrastate Con‡ict" Journal of Con‡ict Resolution 46: 55-73. Russell, Diana (1974). Rebellion, Revolution and Armed Force: A Comparative Study of Fifteen Countries with Special Emphasis on Cuba and South Africa. New York: Academic Press. Seidman, Michael (2002). Republic of Egos: A Social History of the Spanish Civil War, University of Winsconsin Press. Shapiro, Carl and Joseph Stiglitz (1984). "Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device" American Economic Review 74(3): 433-444. Skaperdas, Stegios (2008). "An Economic Approach to Analyzing Civil Wars" Economics of Governance 9(1): 25-44. Skocpol, Theda (1979). States and Social Revolution: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China. Cambridge University Press. Spolaore, Enrico (2008). "Civil Con‡ict and Secessions" Economics of Governance 9(1): 45-63. Tilly, Charles (1973). "Does Modernization Breed Revolution?" Comparative Politics 5(3): 425-447. Toft, Monica, D. (2003). The Geography of Ethnic Violence: Identity, Interests, and the Indivisibility of Territory, Princeton University Press. 23

Toft, Monica, D. (2006). "Peace through Security: Making Negotiated Settlements Stick" Unpublished manuscript. Tone, John L. (1994). The Fatal Knot: The Guerrilla War in Navarre and the Defeat of Napoleon in Spain, UNC Press. Vargas, Juan F. (2009). "Military Empowerment and Civilian Targeting in Civil War" Working Paper # 61, Economics Department, Universidad del Rosario. Weinstein, Jeremy (2005) "Resources and the Information Problem in Rebel Recruitment” Journal of Con‡ict Resolution 49(4): 598-624. Weinstein, Jeremy (2006) Inside Rebellion: The Political Economy of Rebel Organization. Cambridge University Press. Wolf, Eric (1973). Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century. Harper & Row Publishers. New York. Zeitlin, Maurice (1967). Revolutionary Politics and the Cuban Working Class. Princeton University Press.

24

Figure 1. Potential distributions of fighters a

b

1

0

c

0

1

0

d

1

0

1

Figure 2. Distance between group i and fighter f

0

zi

xf |xf – zi|

1

Figure 3. Size of Government and Rebel armies 

zR

xR

xG

zG

Figure 4. Reaction Functions a

b

nG

nG

nG

nG γR

γR nG*

nG*

γG

γG

c

nR nR

nR*

nR nR

nR*

d nG

nG

nG*=nG

nG γR

γR γ'G

γG’

nG*

γG

γG

nR

nR*=0

nR*

e nG nG

γG

γR nR

nR

nR nR

Figure 5. Polarization and unresolved conflict

< ZR

½

ZG

Figure 6. Expectations‐based outcome

ZR

½

ZG

Figure 7. Victory by one side only

ZR

½

ZG

Combatant Recruitment and the Outcome of War

Civil war in Colombia persists to date after over four decades. The average duration ...... Gates, Scott (2002). VRecruitment and Alliance: The Microfoundations of.

423KB Sizes 0 Downloads 171 Views

Recommend Documents

Combatant Recruitment and the Outcome of War
technology of recruitment of combatants determines the outcome of (an existing) war. Our model ..... surviving combat given compliance to the current group, π,.

The Impact of First Trimester Subchorionic Hematoma on the Outcome ...
The Impact of First Trimester Subchorionic Hematoma on the Outcome of Threatened Miscarriage.pdf. The Impact of First Trimester Subchorionic Hematoma on ...

The Morality of War and the Law of War - Rutgers Philosophy
to this proposal—for example, that it would require large-scale deceit, that the discovery of the deception would threaten the authority of the law and thus its ability to contain the violence of war, that the representation of the laws of war as o

Electrodermal predictors of functional outcome and ...
nal tones (78 db, 1.0 s duration, 25 ms controlled rise and fall times) presented binaurally through headphones at intervals varying between 20, 25, and 30 s. The first ... tion, Blunted Affect, and Disorientation (Guy, 1976). BPRS scores at the 1-ye

Short- and long-term outcome of inpatient pulmonary ...
Kaptein AA, Dekker FW, Dekhuijzen PNR, Wagenaar JPM, Janssen PJ. Patiënten met chronische luchtwegobstructie - Scores op NPV en SCL-90 en hun relaties met functionele capaciteit en belemmeringen in dagelijkse activiteiten. Gezondheid & Samenleving 1

Evaluation of COP18 outcome and impacts on Asia -
They are also incapable of coping with the climate disasters by their own ... Japan and Russia stuck to discussion on market trading structures using or ... change in the world According to world's risk report in 2012, 7 out of 10 natural disasters.

Nile Ltd-Outcome of the Board Meeting.PDF
Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Nile Ltd-Outcome of the Board Meeting.PDF. Nile Ltd-Outcome of the Board Meeting.PDF. Open.

Course Outcome - Web Programming and Networking Lab.pdf ...
Course Outcome - Web Programming and Networking Lab.pdf. Course Outcome - Web Programming and Networking Lab.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In.

A Synthesis of Outcome Research.pdf
all ages, and with couples and families across the life cycle. The second element of the credentialing process is preparation of a port- folio, supported by 10 ...

Outcome of the Board Meeting-14.08.2015.PDF
Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Outcome of the Board Meeting-14.08.2015.PDF. Outcome of the Board Meeting-14.08.2015.PDF.

Ancestral War and the Evolutionary Origins of - Institute of Cognitive ...
Two simulations explore the possibility that heroism (risking one's life fighting for the group) evolved as a .... neered into specialized mechanisms because there is no need to engineer a .... volunteers for the Peace Corps and Doctors of the World.

The Art of War - Wsimg.com
north he put fear into the States of Ch`i and Chin, and spread his fame abroad amongst the feudal princes. And Sun Tzu shared in the might of the King.

Investigating the stereochemical outcome of a tandem ... - Arkivoc
Feb 8, 2018 - Kanazawa, C.; Terada, M. Tetrahedron Lett. 2007, 48, 933-935. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tetlet.2006.12.015. 49. Terada, M.; Kanazawa, C.; Yamanaka, M. Heterocycles 2007, 74, 819-825. https://doi.org/10.3987/COM-07-S(W)73. 50. Lee, N. S.

Outcome of written procedures during the period 13 September 2017 ...
Dec 14, 2017 - (EMA/MB/353835/Rev.2), the Board shall be provided with a periodic overview of renewed memberships in the CHMP and CVMP. Renewed memberships include also those memberships where the member has been re-nominated as an alternate or vice

Outcome of written procedures finalised during the period from 14 ...
Jun 15, 2017 - Management Board meeting of 14-15 June 2017. Outcome of written ... Eudravigilance database, ended on 19 May 2017. The report was ...

Outcome of written procedures finalised during the period from 20 ...
Jun 16, 2016 - Telephone +44 (0)20 3660 6000 Facsimile +44 (0)20 3660 5555. Send a question via our website www.ema.europa.eu/contact. © European ...

Disturbance influences the outcome of plantsoil biota ...
Nov 13, 2009 - theoretical considerations uncover a need for empirical data on interactive effects of ..... Stats software (Statistics.com). Statistical ..... Recovery potential of dune ecosys- tems invaded by .... a review and synthesis. – For. Ec

The Study of War and the U.S Military.pdf
Page 1 of 30. North Plainfield School District. The Study of War and the U.S Military. Course Name: The Study of War and the U.S Military. Course NCES Code: Grade Level(s): 9-12. Date of Adoption by NPBOE: September 20, 2017. Unlocking​ ​Potentia

Cancer phenotype as the outcome of an evolutionary ...
Departamento de Matemática da Universidade Nova de Lisboa and Centro de ... This analysis also illustrates how complex biochemical signals can be ...

Outcome of written procedures during the period 13 September 2017 ...
Dec 14, 2017 - In accordance with the Board's decision of 18 March 2010 relating to the Procedure for the consultation of the Management Board on new ...