Competitive Pressure and the Decline of the Rust Belt Simeon Alder1

David Lagakos2 1 Notre

Dame

2 UCSD

and NBER

3 UCLA

and NBER

January 19, 2017

Lee Ohanian3

The Rust Belt

. . . or, as of November 8, 2016 . . .

Four Facts About Rust Belt Since WW II 1. Rust Belt share of economic activity declined slowly & persistently

2. Rust Belt wages substantially higher than average after end of WW II

3. Weak productivity growth in Rust Belt industries

4. In 1980s, Rust Belt decline slowed, wage premia declined & productivity growth increased

Our Theory ◮

Theory explores two channels of Rust Belt’s decline: 1. lack of competition and inefficient rent sharing in labor markets (where unions have ability to hold up firms) 2. effect of foreign competition in product markets on aggregate innovation

Our Theory ◮

Theory explores two channels of Rust Belt’s decline: 1. lack of competition and inefficient rent sharing in labor markets (where unions have ability to hold up firms) 2. effect of foreign competition in product markets on aggregate innovation



Lack of competition in labor markets + pro-growth effect of international trade ⇒ depresses innovation in Rust Belt compared to “Rest of Country”

Our Theory ◮

Theory explores two channels of Rust Belt’s decline: 1. lack of competition and inefficient rent sharing in labor markets (where unions have ability to hold up firms) 2. effect of foreign competition in product markets on aggregate innovation



Lack of competition in labor markets + pro-growth effect of international trade ⇒ depresses innovation in Rust Belt compared to “Rest of Country”



Economic activity shifts to region with faster productivity growth

Related Literature



Competition and productivity: Acemoglu & Akcigit (2011), Bloom, Draca and Van Reenan (2011), Cole & Ohanian (2004), Aghion et al (2005), Holmes (1998), Holmes & Schmitz (2010), Herrendorf & Texeira (2011), Schmitz (2005), Parente & Prescott (1999), Pavcnik (2002), . . .



Unions and economic performance: Holmes (1998), Taschereau-Dumouchel (2012), Bridgman (2011), Dinlersoz and Greenwood (2012), Acikgoz and Kaymak (2012)



Rust Belt; Blanchard & Katz (1992), Feyrer, Sacerdote and Stern (2007), Glaeser and Ponzetto (2007), Yoon (2012)

This Talk

1. Four facts + evidence for lack of competition 2. Model 3. Quantitative analysis

1. Four facts + evidence for lack of competition 2. Model 3. Quantitative analysis

.25

Rust Belt Employment Share .3 .35 .4 .45 .5

.55

Rust Belt Employment Share Declined

1950

1960

1970

1980

Aggregate Aggregate, excluding Sun Belt

1990

2000

Manufacturing

1.00

1.05

Relative Wage 1.10

1.15

1.20

Rust Belt Wages High

1950

1960

1970 Simple Ratio

1980

1990 With Controls

2000

Rust Belt Productivity Growth Low Labor Productivity Growth in Rust Belt Industries Annualized Growth Rate, % 1958-1985

1985-1997

1958-1997

Blast furnaces, steelworks, mills

0.9

7.6

2.8

Engines turbines

2.3

2.9

2.5

Iron and steel foundries

1.5

2.3

1.7

Metal forgings/stampings

1.5

2.8

1.9

Metalworking machinery

0.9

3.5

1.6

Motor vehicles/equipment

2.5

3.8

2.9

Photographic equipment/supplies

4.7

5.1

4.9

Railroad locomotives/equipment

1.6

3.1

2.0

Screw machine products

1.2

1.1

1.2

Rust Belt weighted average

2.0

4.2

2.6

Manufacturing weighted average

2.6

3.2

2.8

Rust Belt was Technological Laggard





Autos, steel, rubber did not adopt latest technologies: ◮

National Academy of Sciences: producers did not adopt long-available technologies



McKinsey productivity studies: lagging technologies



Literature comparing productivity to other countries: US producers were behind others

Frequently cite bad labor relations as important factor

Lack of Competition in Labor Markets



Many Rust Belt industries had powerful unions (UAW, USW,...)



Industry studies: earned rents through hold up/strikes





steel strikes of 1950s



GM strike of 1970, Caterpillar strikes



Bridgestone/Firestone recalls

Broad agreement that union power declined in 1980s Work Stoppages

Conflicted Labor Relations and Inefficient Rent Sharing



Big literature concludes inefficient rent sharing in Rust Belt



Producers and unions agree with this conclusion, in colorful language, on occasion:

Conflicted Labor Relations and Inefficient Rent Sharing



Big literature concludes inefficient rent sharing in Rust Belt



Producers and unions agree with this conclusion, in colorful language, on occasion: ◮

”We are tired of fighting with these bast****.”



”UAW did not trust employers, they were our adversaries.”



”Management refuses to show us the books.”



”When profitable, we accept union demands & recoup with higher prices. Strikes risk ruining the company.”



”We went on strike because we didn’t trust what they told us.”

Inefficient Rent Sharing and Low Productivity Growth Literature emphasizes that labor conflicts contribute to low investment and productivity: ◮

National Academy of Sciences: collective bargaining contracts that grew from adversarial and bitter relationships negatively affected technology and innovation



Census Bureau: Bad labor relations negatively affect productivity and costs



Literature comparing US to Japan: High U.S. costs reflect bad labor relations



President of Germany’s auto union: German workers don’t strike. American unions are destructive because of a hostile environment. American unions can’t be constructive if their as*** are always getting kicked.

(Lack of ?) Competition in Output Markets International Trade



Low import-to-GDP ratios until 1980s, followed by gradual rise



Rust Belt industries (marginally) less “exposed” in 1950 than manufacturing elsewhere, but imports rise more rapidly

(Lack of ?) Competition in Output Markets International Trade & FDI



Low import-to-GDP ratios until 1980s, followed by gradual rise



Rust Belt industries (marginally) less “exposed” in 1950 than manufacturing elsewhere, but imports rise more rapidly



Limited FDI pre-1980s, followed by uptick in traditional Rust Belt industries outside Great Lakes region: ◮

Japanese, German, Korean auto manufacturers in SC, TN, AL, KY, TX,. . .



Minimills in GA, FL, AL, TN,. . .

(Lack of ?) Competition in Output Markets International Trade & FDI



Low import-to-GDP ratios until 1980s, followed by gradual rise



Rust Belt industries (marginally) less “exposed” in 1950 than manufacturing elsewhere, but imports rise more rapidly



Limited FDI pre-1980s, followed by uptick in traditional Rust Belt industries outside Great Lakes region:





Japanese, German, Korean auto manufacturers in SC, TN, AL, KY, TX,. . .



Minimills in GA, FL, AL, TN,. . .

Is rise of imports/FDI cause or consequence of decline?

1. Four facts + evidence for lack of competition 2. Model 3. Quantitative analysis

Households



Economy populated by unit measure of individuals



Labor supply inelastic



Individuals have linear preferences and discount future consumption: ∞ X δ t Ct t=0

Final Good ◮

Final good produced from continuum of intermediates indexed by i (industry), j (variety), and origin: Yt =

Z

1

yt (i)

σ−1 σ

0

yt (i) =

Z

0

where



1

yt (i, j)

σ  σ−1 di

ρ−1 ρ

dj +

Z

0

1

yt∗ (i, ˜)

ρ−1 ρ

ρ  ρ−1 d˜  ,

denotes varieties produced abroad



Final output consumed or used for investment



Intermediates are gross substitutes in production and ρ>σ>1

Intermediate Goods



Industries i ∈ [0, λ) located in Rust Belt (R)



Industries i ∈ [λ, 1] located in Rest-of-Country (S)



Competition in labor markets varies by region (captured by time-varying union bargaining power βt )

Intermediate Goods

Each intermediate firm (producing variety j in industry i) has access to production and innovation technologies. 1. Production is linear in labor: yt = zt · ℓt  2. By investing C x, z, Z units of the final good, firm can enhance idiosyncratic productivity by 100 · x percent next period: zt+1 = zt (1 + xt )

International Trade



Intermediate varieties are tradable between US and Rest-of-World



International trade in intermediates is subject to time-varying (symmetric) iceberg costs τt ≥ 1



Final goods and labor are non-tradable internationally



Trade is balanced period-by-period

Labor Markets



Labor market competitive in Rest-of-Country



Rust Belt labor market governed by union



Individual worker’s union status denoted by υ ∈ {0, 1} and unionization rate in economy denoted by U ∈ [0, 1]



Workers retire with probability ζ each period (regardless of union status)



Access to Rust Belt jobs restricted to union members



Non-members can apply for vacant Rust Belt jobs and new union members are selected randomly from applicant pool

Union



Union bargains with (individual) Rust Belt producers over profits



Protocol is Nash with time-varying bargaining weight βt



Results robust to alternative protocols (e.g. micro-founded take-it-or-leave-it bargaining) TIOLI

Dynamic Model Exogenous State Variables



Two exogenous state variables: 1. union bargaining power β ≥ 0 2. iceberg trade cost τ ≥ 1



Exogenous state follows a Markov process:

(βH , τH ) (βL , τL )



(βH , τH )

(βL , τL )

1−ǫ 0

ǫ 1

βH > βL and τH > τL , by assumption

Dynamic Model Aggregate Endogenous State Variables



Aggregate unionization rate U with law of motion:   U ′ = (1 − ζ) U + M F (1 − U )



 1  1 Set of productivities Z ≡ z(i, j) i,j=0 ∪ z ∗ (i, j) i,j=0 with law of motion: Z ′ = Z × (1 + X)

Dynamic Model Idiosyncratic Endogenous State Variables



Intermediate firm’s productivity z(i, j) with law of motion:  z ′ (i, j) = z(i, j) 1 + x(i, j)



Worker’s union status υ with following law of motion: ◮



If υ = 1, then

If υ = 0, then

υ′ =

(

υ′ =

(

1 with probability 1 − ζ, 0 otherwise 1 with probability f (1 − ζ) if R, 0 with probability 1 − f if R or if S

Intermediate Firms’ Static Problem (Production) ◮

Individual producer indexed by i (industry) and j (variety): n o  Π Z, U, z(i, j); β, τ = max p(i, j)·y(i, j)−n(i, j) , p(i,j), n(i,j), y(i,j)

subject to

y(i, j) = z(i, j) · n(i, j) y(i, j) = P (Z, U ; β, τ )σ−1 P (i; Z, U ; β, τ ) ρ−σ {z } | {z } | agg. price index

ind. price index

· X(Z, U ; β, τ ) p(i, j)−ρ {z } | agg. expenditures



Profit-maximizing price is Dixit-Stiglitz markup: p(i, j) =

ρ −1 ρ−1 z(i, j)

Intermediate Firms’ Dynamic Problem (Innovation) In the Rest-of-Country: V S (Z, U, zS ; β, τ ) = maxxS >0

In the Rust Belt:

n

ΠS (Z, U, zS ; β, τ )

−P (Z, U ; β, τ ) · C(xS , zS , Z) h io +δE V S (Z ′ , U ′ , zS′ ; β ′ , τ ′ ) ,

V R (Z, U, zR ; β, τ ) = maxxR >0 {(1 − β)ΠR (Z, U, zR ; β, τ ) −P (Z, U ; β, τ ) · C(xR , zR , Z) io h ′ ′ R ′ ′ ′ +δE V (Z , U , zR ; β , τ ) ,

Worker’s Problem

 W (Z, U, M, υ; β, τ ) = max W R (Z, U, M, υ; β, τ ), W S (Z, U, υ; β, τ )

Value of non-union worker in Rust Belt:

n W R (Z, U, M, 0; β, τ ) = f (Z, U, M ; β, τ ) w + R(Z, U ; β, τ )    +δ (1 − ζ)E W (Z ′ , U ′ , M ′ , 1; β, τ )  o +ζE W (Z ′ , U ′ , M ′ , 0; β, τ )  + 1 − f (Z, U, M ; β ′ , τ ′ ) n  o × w−u ¯ + δζE W (Z ′ , U ′ , M ′ , 0; β ′ , τ ′ ) , where u ¯ ≥ 0.

Worker’s Problem (cont’d)

Value of union worker in Rust Belt: W R (Z, U, ·, 1; β, τ ) = w + R(Z, U ; β, τ ) n   +δ (1 − ζ)E W (Z ′ , U ′ , M ′ , 1; β ′ , τ ′ )  o ζE W (Z ′ , U ′ , M ′ , 0; β ′ , τ ′ )

Value of any worker in the Sun Belt:

  W S (Z, U, υ; β, τ ) = w + δE W (Z ′ , U ′ , υ ′ ; β ′ , τ ′ )

Balanced Trade



Domestic labor is num´eraire



Trade balance requirement pins down foreign wage w∗ (τ, Z)

1. Four facts + evidence for lack of competition 2. Model 3. Quantitative analysis

Quantitative Analysis



How big is model’s decline in Rust Belt employment share?

Quantitative Analysis



How big is model’s decline in Rust Belt employment share?



Discipline quantitative exercise by extent of competition 1. from foreign producers (regional trade shares, 1950-2000) and 2. in labor markets (estimated wage premiums, 1950-2000)



Import shares are low and wage premiums high initially, then move in opposite directions starting in 1980s

Calibration



Calibrate to manufacturing sector



Model and data period = 5 years



Set δ = 0.965 to match 4% annual interest rate



Set σ = 2.7 (Broda and Weinstein, 2006) and ρ = 4



Normalize initial domestic productivities to 1

State of Competition

◮ ◮

State of competition denoted by θt ≡ (βt , τt ) Ex post path {θ1950+5t }Tt=0 evolves deterministically with transition from H to L in 1985

Cost of Innovation

Cost function in units of domestic final good for i ∈ {R, S}:  C x(i, j), z(i, j), Z = α · x(i, j)γ · where α > 0, γ > 1,

z(i, j) ρ−1 ρ 2−ρ D(Z) ρ−1

,

2−ρ  h i 1−σ i 1−σ  1−σ h ρ−1 ρ−1 ∗ ρ−1 1−ρ ∗ ρ−1 1−ρ D(Z) = λ ZR + ZR + (1 − λ) ZS + ZS

Calibration Parameters and Target Moments



(τH , τL ) – iceberg trade costs



∗ zR,1950 – foreign Rust Belt productivity in 1950



(βH , βL ) – union’s bargaining weight



λ – share of varieties produced by Rust Belt



α – linear (scale) parameter of cost function



γ – curvature parameter of cost function

Calibration Parameters and Target Moments



aggregate import shares: 4% (pre-1985) and 9% (post-1985)



∗ zR,1950 – foreign Rust Belt productivity in 1950



(βH , βL ) – union’s bargaining weight



λ – share of varieties produced by Rust Belt



α – linear (scale) parameter of cost function



γ – curvature parameter of cost function

Calibration Parameters and Target Moments



aggregate import shares: 4% (pre-1985) and 9% (post-1985)



Rust Belt import share: 8% (pre-1985)



(βH , βL ) – union’s bargaining weight



λ – share of varieties produced by Rust Belt



α – linear (scale) parameter of cost function



γ – curvature parameter of cost function

Calibration Parameters and Target Moments



aggregate import shares: 4% (pre-1985) and 9% (post-1985)



Rust Belt import share: 8% (pre-1985)



Wage premium: 12% (pre-1985), 4% (post-1985)



λ – share of varieties produced by Rust Belt



α – linear (scale) parameter of cost function



γ – curvature parameter of cost function

Calibration Parameters and Target Moments



aggregate import shares: 4% (pre-1985) and 9% (post-1985)



Rust Belt import share: 8% (pre-1985)



Wage premium: 12% (pre-1985), 4% (post-1985)



Initial Rust Belt employment share of 51.3%



α – linear (scale) parameter of cost function



γ – curvature parameter of cost function

Calibration Parameters and Target Moments



aggregate import shares: 4% (pre-1985) and 9% (post-1985)



Rust Belt import share: 8% (pre-1985)



Wage premium: 12% (pre-1985), 4% (post-1985)



Initial Rust Belt employment share of 51.3%



1.8% TFP growth (1950-2000)



γ – curvature parameter of cost function

Calibration Parameters and Target Moments



aggregate import shares: 4% (pre-1985) and 9% (post-1985)



Rust Belt import share: 8% (pre-1985)



Wage premium: 12% (pre-1985), 4% (post-1985)



Initial Rust Belt employment share of 51.3%



1.8% TFP growth (1950-2000)



8.5% Investment-to-GDP ratio (1950-2000) (value added share of R&D, advertising, and intangible expenditures)

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

MSA-Level Evidence

2000

Conclusion

30

40

Import Shares in Model and Data

Import Share 20

Steel & Autos

Rust Belt, model

10

Aggregate, model

0

Aggregate, data

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

year

Conclusion

Robustness Checks & Counterfactuals Robustness Checks σ = 2.7, ρ = 3.5

σ = 3, ρ = 4.5

σ = 2, ρ = 4

σ = 3, ρ = 4

Counterfactuals high trade costs: τH = τL = 3.5

low trade costs: τH = τL = 2.7

free trade: τH = τL = 1

autarky: τH = τL → ∞

strong unions: βH = βL = .24

weak unions: βH = βL = .04

no unions: βH = βL = 0

I/GDP = 9%

I/GDP = 8%

Additional Evidence



Estimates of R&D intensity by industry from 1970s



TFP growth: Rust Belt vs. Japan



Adoption rates for key technologies

Post-1980 Growth

Conclusion

TFP

Adoption

R&D

R&D by Industry: Evidence ◮

Report of U.S. Office of Technology Assessment (1980)



Average manufacturing industry: R&D to Sales of 2.5%



Industries with highest ratio:





Communications equipment: 15.2%



Aircraft and parts: 12.4%



Office and computing equipment: 11.6%

Rust Belt industries: ◮

Autos: 2.1%



Rubber and Plastics: 1.2%



Steel: 0.4% Additional Evidence

Productivity Growth: United States versus Japan



Steel (Lieberman and Johnson, 1999) US: TFP growth < 1 percent per year 1950 to 1970 Japan: TFP doubled over same period



Autos (Fuss and Waverman, 1991) US: 1.6 percent per year in 1970s Japan: 4.3 percent per year in 1970s Additional Evidence

Technology Adoption: Evidence



Industry studies find that Rust Belt producers were slow adopters (compared to producers elsewhere)



Two new technologies in steel of 1950s and 1960s: ◮

Basic oxygen furnace



Continuous casting methods

0

10

Percent 20 30

40

50

Fraction of Steel Made Using Continuous Casting Process

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

year US

Japan

Germany

Italy

France

Additional Evidence

Post-1980 Growth

Conclusion

Signed Confession

From 1980 Annual Report of American Iron and Steel Institute: “Inadequate capital formation in any industry produces meager gains in productivity, upward pressure on prices, sluggish job creation, and faltering economic growth. These effects have been magnified in the steel industry. Inadequate capital formation ... has prevented adequate replacement and modernization of steelmaking facilities, thus hobbling the industry’s productivity and efficiency.”

Did Productivity Growth Pick up After 1980s? ◮



Steel: ◮

US vertically integrated mills (mostly in Rust Belt)



11 percent TFP growth from 1982 to 1987; 16 percent 1992 to 1997



Source: Collard-Wexler and De Loecker (2012), Lieberman and Johnson (1999)

Autos: ◮

Pick up seen in cars per worker at GM, Ford and Chrysler



From annual reports; most operations in Rust Belt



Working on TFP numbers Other Predictions

Conclusion

Conclusion



Relative to the rest of the US, Rust Belt declined in economic terms (employment, value added) from 1950 to 2000



Theory emphasizes lack of competition as force of Rust Belt’s decline



Quantitative model can generate sizeable share of employment loss



Consistent with historical evidence

Union with TIOLI Offers ◮

Union makes take-it-or-leave-it offer b ∈ [0, 1]



If firm accepts, unionized workers receive w plus per capita share of b · ΠR



If firm rejects, union calls a strike and ◮

succeeds with probability β (i.e. production is halted for one period and ΠR = 0)



fails with probability 1 − β (i.e. production resumes, workers get w, firm receives ΠR )



Union offers b ∈ [0, β] since firm rejects any b > β



In practice, β = b for empirically relevant parameterizations

Return to Nash bargaining

Work Stoppages Affecting 1,000+ Workers

Labor Markets

#!!"

!"#$%&'()'*(&+',-(../0%1''

'#!" '!!" &#!" &!!" %#!" %!!" $#!" $!!" #!" !" $(')" $(#%" $(#)" $(*%" $(*)" $()%" $())" $(+%" $(+)" $((%" $(()" %!!%" %!!)" %!$%"

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data σ = 2.7, ρ = 3.5

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Robustness Checks

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data σ = 2.7, ρ = 4.5

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Robustness Checks

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data σ = 2, ρ = 4

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Robustness Checks

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data σ = 3, ρ = 4

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Robustness Checks

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data τH = τL = 3.5

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data τH = τL = 2.7

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data Free Trade (τH = τL = 1) 0.55

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

0.3

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data Autarky (τH = τL → ∞)

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data βH = βL = 0.24

Data Model

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data βH = βL = 0.04

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

Data Model 0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data βH = βL = 0

Rust Belt Employment Share

0.5

0.45

0.4

Data Model 0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data = 9%

Data Model

0.5

Rust Belt Employment Share

I/GDP

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Rust Belt Employment Share in Model and Data = 8%

Data Model

0.5

Rust Belt Employment Share

I/GDP

0.45

0.4

0.35

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Counterfactuals

Measures of “Wage Premia”



Run Mincer-type regression for 1950 log wi,m = α · SCHi,m +

4 X

βj ·

j=1



Wage premium for MSA m: πm



Crude but useful proxy

j EXPi,m +

M X

m=1

Dm · πm + εi,m

6.0

Employment Growth Low Where Premiums High ORL PHX

Employment Growth 1950 to 2000 0.0 2.0 4.0

AUS

RAL

GRB SJO ATL SDG SLC SAC DAL ABQ HOU DEN NSV COM WAS CHR NOR LTL SAT MIA BAT KAL SEA GRR TAC JCK JSV MAD STO FRE SCR MININD AUG MOB TUL PTV CLB CHO SAG LUB ELP OKC RCM ATC GRN HAR WIC MNT FTW LNG WAC ASHYOR SHV SYR LAN KNX LIN LIN WLM CDR RCF SPO KAN GALLOS RCH MEMCOR OMA SXF DES BRK AMR LUI HAM DAY SAV POR NOL ROA REA ALT EVABEA JCS ALL BAL TER STL CIN CLM AKR PEO MIL TOP BIR TOL PRO JOH MUN ALBPHI CAN RAC CLE DET UTI ERE DEC TRE CHI BNG BOS WIF SPH SOB SIXDAV DUL HRT PIT SPR PUE SFR WAR BUF MAN BRG NHANYO FLI WOR TAM

CHT

GNA

−0.4

−0.2

0.0 Wage Premium in 1950

0.2

0.4

Employment: Model and Data

Industry Employment Growth and Unionization

1 0 −1 −2 −3 −4 −5

Employment Growth Rate: Rust Belt − Rest of US

2

Employment Growth and Unionization Rates: Rust Belt − Rest of US

−0.1

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

Unionization Rate: Rust Belt − Rest of US

Employment: Model and Data

Competitive Pressure and the Decline of the Rust Belt

Jan 19, 2017 - Signed Confession. From 1980 Annual Report of American Iron and Steel Institute: “Inadequate capital formation in any industry produces meager gains in productivity, upward pressure on prices, sluggish job creation, and faltering economic growth. These efiects have been magnified in the steel industry.

1MB Sizes 0 Downloads 124 Views

Recommend Documents

The Decline of the Rust Belt - University of Notre Dame
Feb 4, 2017 - view of unions is that of an organization that bargains over industry rents in the form of wage premia ...... Urban Economics, 46, 360–376. 45 ...

The Silver Lining of Rust Belt Manufacturing Decline
Agency is the source of my air pollution data.9 The EPA chooses monitor- ing locations to identify ..... Data Source: Printed Records of the. Census of ... When the steel mill was open, the area averaged 12.6 violations of the 24 ... tenants, Journal

Labor Market Conflict and the Decline of the Rust Belt
Mar 25, 2017 - Historical studies claim Rust Belt workers rationed jobs and .... and costly queuing for union job .... Office and computing equipment: 11.6%.

Competitive pressure: the effects on investments in ...
With this definition of competitive pressure it is straightforward to identify ... (1996) is more in line with the analysis here, as they measure competitive pressure.

The Rise and Decline of the American Ghetto ... - Stanford University
Data on house prices and atti- tudes toward ...... the white neighborhood, and house prices in the black area will rise relative to house ...... Chapel Hill: Univ.

The Decline of the Empire
Page 1. The Decline of the Empire. 12. Page 2. Page 3.

Productivity Dynamics, R&D, and Competitive Pressure
6Using Taiwanese plant-level data, they find that (i) self-selection of high productive plants is the dominant channel driving participation in the export market and ...

The Rise and Decline of European Parliaments, 1188 ...
First, however, we have to deal with the question: What is a Parliament? ..... of the cities was often crucial: they had access to (cheap) capital, or could raise taxes ... It also clarified (to a certain extent) the 'social contract' between a king

Detroit and the Decline of Urban America - Inverse Condemnation
Sep 23, 2013 - was the post-World War II tide of generous government home financing ... that I was thus de facto the beneficiary of free housing. .... For reasons that have not been judicially explained, in ..... http://www.library.unt.edu/gpo/acir/R

Detroit and the Decline of Urban America - Inverse Condemnation
Sep 23, 2013 - years. He was one of the lawyers who represented the Sisters of Mercy ... touched; it made no real effort to fix its abysmal schools, to nurture new ..... pensation” include damage to business stock in trade, for moving expenses,.

The Rise and Decline of European Parliaments, 1188 ...
this deal was necessary every seven years; therefore, the meeting of 1188 was .... was by simply not convening it again, leading to the virtual impotence of the ...

Technological Specialization and the Decline of ...
Mar 10, 2017 - i can occur in regions 1, 2, 5, or 6; the location of the project generated by j .... The root with the plus sign before the square root term cannot be a solution, since it would ..... Table A.5: Model Outputs and Data: Steady-State vs

Mortgage Loans, the Decline of the Household Saving ...
Jan 30, 2011 - enced: (i) a sharp decline in the personal saving rate, which was associated ... ownership rate rose by 6 percentage points, while household ...

Discovery and characteristics of the Kuiper belt binary ...
and dynamically cold primordial disk (Goldreich et al., 2002;. Weidenschilling, 2002 ... as part of the MIT recovery program for DES objects. Images under 0.5 ...

collapse pressure estimates and the application of a partial safety ...
Aug 4, 2010 - 1 Korea Atomic Energy Research Institute. 1045 Daedeok Street, Yuseong-gu, Daejeon 305-353, Republic of Korea. 2 School of Mechanical ...

collapse pressure estimates and the application of a partial safety ...
Aug 4, 2010 - Based on the present FE results, the analytical yield locus, considering the ... This paper presents a collapse pressure estimation model.