Constant Best-Response Functions: Interpreting Cournot Zivan Forshner University of Haifa and Oz Shy∗ University of Haifa Revised: November 2, 2002

Abstract Following Amir and Grilo (1999), we characterize a class of demand functions that generate constant quantity best-response functions. Then, we draw the implications of constant best-response functions for the invariance of equilibrium outcomes with respect to the assumed market structure of quantity games. We then argue that, unlike the class of linear demand functions, this class of demand functions supports the pure interpretation Cournot’s conjectures.

Keywords: Constant best-response functions, Cournot equilibrium, Cournot conjectures Stackelberg equilibrium. JEL Classification Numbers: C72, D43 (Draft = BR6.tex



2002/11/02 15:26)

Corresponding Author: E-mail: [email protected]

Department of Economics, University of Haifa, 31905 Haifa, Israel.

1.

Introduction

Perhaps the major problem in applying theoretical research on oligopoly theory is that equilibrium market outcomes tend to be highly sensitive to changing the order of decision makings of the firms in an industry, or the equilibrium concept. A natural question to ask is whether there exist demand functions in which the resulting market equilibrium outcomes are invariant with respect to the assumed market structure. Amir and Grilo (1999, p.9) demonstrated the existence of a class of demand functions for which the resulting best-response functions are constant in quantity oligopoly games. The desired result in which the order of decisions in quantity oligopoly games does not alter the market outcome immediately follows. From a theoretical point of view, the Cournot market structure may have two interpretations associated with two different assumptions concerning firms’ expectations.1 The widely-used (weak) interpretation is that a Cournot equilibrium is a Nash equilibrium, Nash (1950), in the sense that each firm expects the other firm to maintain a constant output level. Clearly, these expectations are consistent only in equilibrium, at least for the class of linear demand functions. However, a stronger interpretation of Cournot equilibrium is to assume that firms expect rival firms to have constant best-response functions. Thus, unlike the class of linear demand function, the class of demand functions identified in this paper is consistent with the strong interpretation of Cournot’s conjectures. This note is organized as follows. Section 2 identifies the class of demand functions yielding constant best-response functions. Section 3 demonstrates that the realization of output levels are invariant with respect Cournot and Stackelberg quantity setting market structures. Section 4 concludes with a general discussion and a demonstrating how in contrast to linear demand functions, this class of demand functions supports the pure interpretation of Cournot’s conjectures. 1

In fact, strategic games by themselves may have several interpretations; see for example Osborne and Rubinstein (1994, Section 2.1.2).

1

2.

Demand Functions Yielding Constant Best-Response Functions

Consider a market for a homogeneous product with an aggregate downward sloping inverse demand function denoted by p(Q), where Q denotes aggregate quantity demanded, and p the market price. We assume that p(Q) is twice continuously differentiable with respect to Q. There are N firms indexed by i = 1, . . . , N (N ≥ 2) which can costlessly produce this  product. Let qi (qi ≥ 0) denote the output of firm i, so Q = N i=1 qi . Also, define q = (q1 , . . . , qN ) and def

q¬i = (q1 , . . . , qi−1 , qi+1 , . . . , qN ). def

Thus, the N -dimensional vector q is the list of the firms’ output levels, whereas the (N − 1)dimensional vector q¬i is the list of output levels of all firms except firm i. Finally, let  def πi (q) = p( N j=1 qj )qi denote the profit function of firm i, i = 1, . . . , N . For given a q¬i , the set of maximizers is given by           q j qi ≥ p x + qj x, ψ(q¬i ) = qi ∈ R + p qi +  j=i

 for all x ∈ [0, ∞) .

j=i

N −1 We assume that ψ(q¬i ) = ∅ for all qi ∈ R+ . We call ψ the best-response correspondence. N −1 −→ ψ(q¬i ). A best-response function, Ri (q¬i ) is a selection out of ψ(q¬i ); i.e., Ri (q¬i ) : R+

A best-response function is said to be constant if there exists a constant ki ≥ 0 for which Ri (q¬i ) = ki for all q¬i . Following Amir and Grilo (1999, p.9), we state Proposition 1 There exists a class of downward-sloping market demand functions for which the corresponding best-response functions are constant. Formally, this class of demand functions is given by Q

p(Q) = e− β = e− Proof.

N i=1 qi β

,

for any β > 0.

We derive the best-response function of firm i, which chooses qi that solves −

max πi (qi , q¬i ) = qi e qi

2

qi +



j=i qj β

.

(1)

The first-order condition is given by (β − qi ) − ∂πi (qi , q¬i ) = 0= e ∂qi β

N j=1 qj β

.

Hence, qi = β is an extremum point. Since the second-order condition (evaluated at the extremum) is

 N qj (β − 2β) − j=1 ∂ 2 πi (qi , q¬i )  β = e < 0, ∂(qi )2 qi =β β2

it follows that πi attains a global maximum over (0, ∞) at qi = β. Observe that −

πi (q1 , . . . , qi−1 , β, qi+1 , . . . , qN ) = βe

β+



j=i qj β

> 0.

Finally, since πi (0, q¬i ) = 0, πi attains a global maximum over [0, ∞) at qi = β. It follows that ψ(q¬i ) = ∅, and in fact ψ(q¬i ) = {β}. Therefore, the best-response correspondence is a function.

3.

Equilibrium Oligopoly Market Outcomes

We now solve for the equilibrium market outcomes under Cournot and Stackelberg market structures. c A Cournot-Nash equilibrium, Cournot (1838), is an outcome q c ∈ R N + such that Ri (q¬i ) =

qic for all i = 1, . . . , N . Clearly, in this environment, the unique Nash-Cournot equilibrium is qic = β and the aggregate output level is Q = N β. A Stackelberg equilibrium (in which firm 1 is a leader), Stackelberg (1934), is the outcome qs ∈ R N + which is obtained by solving max q1

π1 (q1 , q¬1 )

(2)

s.t. qj = Rj (q¬j ) for all j ≥ 2. That is, the leader solves for the followers’ best-response functions, and chooses its output level accordingly. Followers behave in a Cournot fashion. We deliberately refrained from defining Stackelberg market structure that employs a specific extensive-form game for the following reasons: 3

(a) Every extensive-form game has unique normal-form representation, however the converse does not hold. (b) Using normal-form games is aligned with the equilibrium notion, that is the Nash equilibrium. In contrast, the mere specification of an extensive-form game suggests that the additional structure is meaningful and therefore calls for a refinement of the equilibrium notion, and this may yield different solutions. (c) The set of Nash equilibria of a given extensive-form game coincides with the set of Nash equilibria of the associated reduced normal-form game. (d) Most importantly, from the empirical point of view, applied economists do not observe decision processes. Proposition 2 The realization of output levels are invariant with respect to the choice of Cournot and Stackelberg market structures. It is interesting to point out that for this particular inverse-demand function, each firm can consider itself to be a Stackelberg leader in the sense that it solve the maximization problem (2), while firms’ conjectures maintain mutual consistency. This invalidates a common perception that in a Stackelberg market structure when there are two firms, there is no equilibrium when both firms view themselves as leaders [e.g., Kreps, p.330]. Moreover, our result here is related to the endogenous-timing papers such as Hamilton and Slutsky (1990) and Amir and Grilo (1999) which obtain in more general setting the possibility that both firms will choose their output level at the same time (simultaneous game). Here we demonstrate the possibility of having a complete invariance with respect to the order of moves in the absence of production costs is not mentioned in this literature.2 2

The issue of production cost turns out to be important since it is clear that for sufficiently-high production costs at least one firm will not produce thereby making the market outcome invariant with respect to the order of moves.

4

4.

Interpreting Cournot: A Discussion

From a theoretical point of view, we would like to point out the following. (a) Cournot (1927) has never suggested the widely-used class of linear demand functions as an example for his model. The class of linear demand functions belongs to a modern interpretation of his model. In fact, it seems as if Cournot left it vague which class of demand functions are consistent with his model. (b) Unlike the class of linear demand functions, the class of demand functions identified in this note is consistent with the strong interpretation of Cournot conjectures in the sense that firms’ correctly believe that rival firms will not deviate from their output level regardless of their actions. This interpretation does not hold for the class of linear demand functions. (c) One cannot argue that the widely-used class linear demand functions is more general than the class identified in this note. In fact, as we argue below, we believe that the present class of demand functions better suits econometric fitting. (d) It is indeed possible, that Cournot himself thought about constant-best response functions. Our interpretation of Cournot is based on Cournot’s system of two equations given in Cournot (1927, Ch.7, p.66), which can be written using our notation and for N = 2 as: ∂π1 (q1 , q2 ) = 0 =⇒ p(β + q2 ) + ∂q1 ∂π2 (q1 , q2 ) = 0 =⇒ p(q1 + β) + ∂q2

dp(Q) ∂Q β ≡ 0, dQ ∂q1 dp(Q) ∂Q β ≡ 0, dQ ∂q2

∀q2

(3)

∀q1 .

(4)

Equation (3) reflects what firm 2 conjectures about firm 1, namely that firm 1’s optimization always yields q1 = β regardless of the level of output set by firm 2. Similarly, equation (4) reflects what firm 1 conjectures about firm 2, namely that firm 2’s optimization always yields q2 = β regardless of the level of output set by firm 1.

5

Therefore, our interpretation of Cournot’s conjecture is that equations (3) and (4) holds as identities independently of each other. In contrast, the common interpretation is to require that this system of equations holds in equilibrium in which case the Cournot conjecture about rival firms holding their output constant is inconsistent with firms’ having downward sloping best-response functions. Finally, various authors [e.g., Bergstrom and Varian (1985)] have attempted to facilitate empirical research in oligopoly markets using simple Cournot market structures. The class of demand functions characterized in this note has significant implications for empirical research. The reason for this is that models in which econometricians can fit the data into a demand function in the class identified by (1) can have strong prediction power because the market outcome is invariant with respect to the assumed market structure. This means that in these markets, the applied economists does not have to search in the class of sequential dynamic games in order to find a particular ad-hoc order of moves which would fit the data best.

6

References Bergstrom, T., and H. Varian, 1985, “When Are Nash Equilibria Independent of the Distribution of Agents’ Characteristics?” Review of Economics Studies 52: 715–718. Amir, R., and I. Grilo, 1999, “Stackelberg versus Cournot Equilibrium,” Games and Economic Behavior, 26: 1–21. Cournot, A. 1927 [1838]. Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth. Translated by Nathaniel Bacon. New York: Macmillan. Hamilton, J., and S. Slutsky, 1990, “Endogenous Timing in Duopoly Games: Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria, Games and Economic Behavior, 2: 29–46. Kreps, D., 1990, A Course in Microeconomic Theory, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Nash, J., 1950, “Equilibrium in N -Person Games,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 36: 48–49. Osborne, M., and A. Rubinstein, 1994, A Course in Game Theory, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. von Stackelberg, H., 1934, Marktform und Gleichgewicht Vienna: Springer-Verlag. English Translation:The Theory of the Market Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

7

Constant Best-Response Functions: Interpreting Cournot

Nov 2, 2002 - desired result in which the order of decisions in quantity oligopoly ..... 1990, A Course in Microeconomic Theory, Princeton: Princeton University.

98KB Sizes 2 Downloads 147 Views

Recommend Documents

Cournot Duopoly - Calculations.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Cournot ...

Ramsey Meets Cournot
the market are decreasing in the discount factor and in the labor produc& ... APreviously circulated under the title VReal Business Cycles with Cournot Competition ... Floetotto (2008) have extended this class of models to strategic interactions ...

Ramanujan's Constant
Jan 14, 2005 - important result is that j(q) is an algebraic number of degree n, where n is the class number of d. ... number 2, so j(q) would be an algebraic integer of degree 2, or a root of a quadratic. And so on for ...... Verlag, 2 nd. Ed., 1989

Interpreting focus
... instance of what in the presupposition literature has come to be known as the 'binding problem'. ...... Linguistics and Philosophy 19: 259-294. Geurts, B. 1997: ...

Information disadvantage in linear Cournot duopolies with ...
measures the cross-effect, the change in firm i's demand caused by a change in firm j's action. Therefore, for bi N0(bi b0) products are substitutes (complements).

Interpreting Utility Patent Claims
Jul 11, 2016 - other patents within the invention's technology field. An Example of ..... consulting information such as dictionaries, technical trea- tises, other ...

Imitation in Cournot Oligopolies with Multiple Markets
An extension of the benchmark model reveals that sophisticated firms imitating across asymmetric ... Email: [email protected]%heidelberg.de. Phone: +49 ...

Interpreting focus
c is asserted): the speaker claims M (in c), and for every alternative M ∈ ... the focus-semantic value of VP, i.e. the set of alternatives to the interpretation.

Interpreting Utility Patent Claims
Jul 11, 2016 - The diagram below depicts the scope that may be available ... oppositions, trademark cancellations and domain name disputes; and preparing.

Profit sharing and strike activity in Cournot oligopoly - Springer Link
Feb 27, 1998 - employment level or other forms of pay like workers' participation schemes. .... a Call to strike concerns only one establishment b Monthly ...... bosch, Center for Operations Research and Econometrics, Catholic University.

Profit sharing and strike activity in Cournot oligopoly - Springer Link
Feb 27, 1998 - to increase its market share, its profits, and its workers' pay (see Bensa'id et al., 1990; Bensa'/d and Gary-Bobo, ... to substitute the profit share for the base wage. Also, empirical inves- tigations made ..... our bargaining proble

Embossing With Markers - Constant Contact
Layer 2: 5 1/8” x 3 7/8” Tangerine Tango Card. Stock. Layer 3: 5 x 3 ¾” Very Vanilla Card Stock. Inside Layer: 5 x 3 ¾”, stamped with crumb cake. “road grime” stamp. Instructions: Step 1: Using the road grime stamp, stamp the image mult

Cournot-Walras Equilibrium as A Subgame Perfect ... - CiteSeerX
introduced a Cournot-Walras equilibrium concept for exchange economies ...... (1x2(t,y(t),p),...,1xl(t,y(t),p)) is, under Assumption 2, the unique solution.

Pace Chart (Constant Pace).pdf
Pace Chart (Constant Pace).pdf. Pace Chart (Constant Pace).pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Pace Chart (Constant Pace).pdf.

Constant Current Source for Coulometry
Various readings displayed on Mobile Application. Android App Displays: 1. Interval X Voltage, 2. Interval X Current, 3. Interval ... Page 10. BJT Switch On. 10 ...

QUASI-CONSTANT CHARACTERS: MOTIVATION ...
Aug 24, 2017 - quasi-constant cocharacters in the setting of our program outlined in loc. cit. Contents. 1. Introduction. 2 ... E-mail address: [email protected], ...

Interpreting Curves Workings.pdf
Sign in. Page. 1. /. 3. Loading… Page 1 of 3. Page 1 of 3. Page 2 of 3. Page 2 of 3. Page 3 of 3. Page 3 of 3. Interpreting Curves Workings.pdf. Interpreting Curves Workings.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Interpreting

Interpreting the Upanishads
Apr 5, 2015 - tronically on the internet, but only free of cost and without any alteration. The rights to publishing and sale in paper-printed form are vested.

Practice Interpreting Graphs.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Practice Inte ... ng Graphs.pdf. Practice Inte ... ng Graphs.pdf. Open.

Equilibrium Constant Worksheet Blank Warren.pdf
There was a problem loading more pages. Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the ...

Backyard Cuckoo Hashing: Constant Worst-Case ... - CiteSeerX
Aug 4, 2010 - dictionary. Cuckoo hashing uses two tables T1 and T2, each consisting of r = (1 + δ)ℓ entries ...... Internet Mathematics, 1(4), 2003. [CFG+78].

Planck's Constant Measurement for Dummies
A 50 MHz bandwidth oscilloscope is used. The X-axis is set to 100 µs and the Y-axis is at 500 mV. The step between the markers with height of 360 mV and length of 60 µs corresponds to a single quantum conductance unit. Planck's constant evaluated a

Functions and Equations in Two Variables Functions ...
z = f(x, y). Example:ааEvaluate the function for f(4,ан3). f(x, y) = x. 2. + 4y or ... necessary to solve an equation for a variable. ... Pg 486аа585 x 5, 100, 101, 103.

Firebird/InterBase - Date functions
Number of days in month ... get Day of Week by ISO standard, use: .... Because IB5 does not support EXTRACT function, we can just test whether February 29th ...