An Informed Approach to Substance Abuse

Mark A. R. Kleiman

Drugs and Drug Policy: The Case for a Slow Fix The main policy goal should be to minimize the aggregate societal damage associated with drug use. "Fanaticism," says Santayana, "consists of redo ub ling your efforts when you have lost sight of your aim." An old Alcohol ics Anonymous adage defines insanity as "cont inuing to do the same thi ng and expecting to get a different res ult." Between them, these two aphorisms define the condition of U.S. drug po licy and the pub lic de bate about it. Our current polic ies, largely misconceived, are doing much more The discussion of harm than they shou ld and much less good than they might. Part drug policy remains of the problem is simply the formidable complex ity of the unproductively phenomena we are trying to manage . The heterogeneity of drugs polarized between and drug users defies s imple categorization. As a resu lt, the "drug warriors" and serious pol icy questions refuse to line up a long the easily "Iegalizers." com prehended polarity that fits two-party po litics and point/coun terpoint journa lism. Yet the discuss ion of drug policy remains unproductively polarized between the "drug warriors" who advocate stricter controls and harsher punishments and the "Iegalizers" who favor more re laxed contro ls. As a resu lt, a w ide variety of sensi ble pol icy mod ifications that fa il to fit the ideological predilections of either extreme simply do not get discussed. The only way to cl ose the gap between what we know how to do and what we are actually doing is to deve lop a "third way" of thinking about drug poli cy. Usi ng only ex isting knowledge and reso urces, the nation could have a much smaller drug problem five years from now than it has today. Repairing our broken pol ic ies, however, will requ ire a c learer vision of w hat the drug problem is and more moderate expectations about what public policy in thi s area can actually accompl ish.

Push ing enforcement Current policies, wh ich reflect the drug warrior philosophy , aim to reduce drug use through stricter controls, increased enforcement, harsher pu nishment, and schoo l-based and mass media efforts to stigmatize the use of illic it drugs. Treatment is very much an afterthought, both rhetorica lly and budgetari ly. At least three-quarters of the roughly $40 bi ll ion spent by governments at a ll leve ls on the contro l of ill icit drug use now goes into enforcement; the size of that effort and the number of people incarcerated for drug law vio lations have grown approximate ly 10-fo ld du ring the past 20 years. Yet hard drug prices are currently near their all-time lows. By contrast, critics of current policies focus not on use reduction but "harm reduction" -that is, maki ng the consumption of ill icit drugs less harmfu l to those who consume them and to nonusers. The most w idely debated example is need le exchange, which aims to reduce the transmission of HIV and other infectious organi sms that can oCCur w hen intravenous drug users share needles. Some advocates of harm redu ct ion also asse rt that dim inution or elim ination of legal penalt ies fo r drug use and distribution wo uld decrease addicts' need to stea l to buy drugs and the violence assoc iated with the drug trade.

The question always is whether and to what extent such reductions in risk wou ld be offset or more than offset by increases in the extent of illicit drug tak ing. Redu cing the risk of harm associated with any given pattern of drug-taking is not the same thing as reducing the aggregate level of harm. By reducing the risks associated with drug use, policies aimed at harm reduct ion may actually increase the number of users and/or the intensity of drug use, which could result in increas ing the total leve l of drug-re lated dam age to users and others .. Thus, whether a given harm reducti on po licy increases or decreases to tal damage depends on the detail s of the program and the circumstances. So far, the advocates of use reduction have had very much the better of the political confrontation . Harm reduction approaches have consistently fa iled to capture the public's imagination. Even methadone maintenance for op iate addicts, despite its am ply demonstrated success, remains politically controversial , as illustrated by New York C ity Mayor Rudolph Giuliani's recent proposal to abolish it. And legalization remain s the great bogeyman of the drug policy debate. The dominance of the use-reduction viewpoint is illustrated and reinforced by the extent to which measures of prevalence-the total number of drug users-dom inate public discussion of the effectiveness of current drug policies. The two big nationa l surveys paid for the federal government, the Monitoring the Future study of high schoo l students done by the University of Michigan and the National Ho useho ld Survey on Drug Abuse don e by the Research Triangle Inst itute, each ask people to volunteer information about their own drug use . The res ults of the surveys are often the subject of partisan commentary, and they have dominated the quantitative policy goals set by the White House's Office of National Drug Control Pol icy. But prevalence is only one measure, and probab ly not even a very im portant one, of the size of the problem or the success of our control efforts. Prevalence in the use of any drug is a poor proxy measure for aggregate damage. Most users of most drugs (cigarettes and heroin are the prominent exceptions) are occasional users, suffe ring little damage, doing little damage to others, and contributing little-even in the aggregate-to the revenues of the illicit markets. Moreover, no one would argue that an occasional marijuana smoker (by far the most common variety of illicit drug user) faces personal risks or creates problems for others that are comparable to the personal risks and social problems created by freq uent high-dose crack use. But by taking the total user count as the measure of success, we imp licitly give the two cases equal weight. Although publi c opinion is strongly on the drug warrior side of the debate, public concern about drug ab use does not in fact track data abou t drug use prevalence. In the late 1970s, when the total number of illicit drug users reached its peak, drug abu se was bare ly on the national radar screen. A decade later, when the total number of drug users was on ly half as high, but the crack epidem ic was devastating city after city , opinion surveys rated drug abuse the most serious threat to the nation's we ll-being. The goal of drug policy ought to be to minimize the aggregate damage created by drug taking, drug trafficking, and the enforcement effort. That is, we ought to judge drug contro l efforts as we judge other public policies: by their results in producing benefits or avoiding harm to individuals or institutions. The major barrier to more effective drug-control policies is that effectiveness, measured in terms of damage control, has not been at the center of po licymaking in this arena. Us ing this "third way" of evaluating drug policies and programs would have two key consequences. First, applying a damage standard wou ld expand our foc us to include licit drugs such as a lcohol and tobacco, which, precisely because they are more w idely used , cause much more aggregate damage than any illicit drug. Second, within the realm of the illicit drugs, a damage standard wou ld prompt us to concentrate our efforts on frequent highdose users, especially those whose addiction to expens ive drugs leads them into criminal activity, rather than occas iona l marijuana smokers and other casual users. A damage standard would also require us to pay as much attention to the side effects of drug traffick ing, especially violence and the enticement of juveni les into illicit activity , as to the damage done by the actual consumption of illega l drugs , and to count the financial and social costs of enforcement and imprisonment.

Protecting juveniles Thinking about juvenile drug abuse whi le ignoring alcoho l and nicotine is like studying oceans while ignoring the Atlantic and the Pacific. If our goal is to protect children from the damage they can do to themselves by abusing psychoactive chemicals, we need to concentrate on the licit drugs , wh ich are by far the greatest threats. Relatively few adolescents are heavy smokers; the hab it takes time to develop. But about a quarter of high-school sen iors do smoke, and most of them wi ll go on to months, ifnot years, of heavy daily smoking. Heavy smok ing, in turn , roughly doubles th e mortality rate at any given age. As for alcohol , its prevalence among high-school sen iors approaches universality (87 percent). According to the most recent Monitoring the Future study , more high school seniors had gone on a drinking binge (defined as more than five drinks at a sitting) in the previous two weeks (31 percent) than had used any illicit drug in the previou s month (23 percent). In this context, the political fixation on marijuana use among children seems bizarre. Of course, marijuana can pose a significant threat to children but not primarily because it leads to hard drugs, as the so-called gateway hypothesis holds . (The vast majority of juveniles who use marijuana do not go on to use other illicit drugs, as both national surveys demonstrate, and the causal significance, if any, of the statistical association between early marijuana use and subsequent use of cocaine and heroin remains open to debate.) Instead, the major risk is that marijuana use itself wi ll turn into a hard-to-break habit. This happens far more often than many people believe. James Anthony, Lynn Warner, and Ronald Kessler, ana lyzing data from the National Comorbid ity Survey, found that 9. 1 percent of those who had ever used marijuana eventua lly became c linically dependent on it. That "capture rate" is lower than the comparable figures for tobacco (31 .9 percent), cocaine ( 16.7 percent) or alcoho l (15.4 percent), but I chance in II represents a substantial risk. Even so, the total damage done to adolescents by marijuana doesn't approach that done by alcoho l and nicotine-nicotine because of its very high addiction risk and the grave health consequences from years of heavy smoking; alcohol because of its very w idespread use, the risks associated with drunken behavior (even if ep isodes are infrequent), and the substantial probability and devastating consequences of chronic alcoholism . Near ly 40 million Americans are addicted to tobacco and about 22 million people suffer from either alcohol dependency or its less severe form , alcohol abuse . Drinking and drunken behavior exact a terrible toll. Surveys of offenders under criminal justice supervision show that 40 percent of them had been drinking at the time they committed the offense that led to their convictions; and a lcoho l invo lvement in some categories of violent offenses, including murder and, especially domestic violence and hate crime, is even higher. (A lcohol is also a substantial risk factor for being a victim of a violent crime.) Alcohol also contributes to risky sexual behavior. In the furor over the use of the drug flunitrazepam (Rohypno l) in date rapes, almost no one mentioned the much larger role of alcohol in creating the conditions not only for date rape but for unplanned and unprotected intercourse and the unwanted pregnancy and sexually transmitted disease that results from it. (Although there is no carefu l scientific backup for the assertion that alcohol has been associated w ith more cases of HIV transmiss ion than has heroin, it is almost ce11ainly true .)

Licit drugs such as alcohol and tobacco cause far more aggregate damage to society than do illicit ones.

The death toll from tobacco consumption is about 400,000 per year; from alcohol consumption , about 100,000 per year. Whether a lcohol or tobacco should be considered the bigger threat depends on how one weighs chronic health damage against accidents , crimes, suicides, and irresponsible sexual behavior. Fortunate ly, we know exactly how to reduce smok ing and drinking amongjuveniles: Make

them more expensive. The $1.10 cigarette tax increase rejected by Congress this year would have reduced the prevalence of juvenile smoking by about a third; further disincentives aimed at the tobacco industry might lead to even larger reductions. Among feasible public actions to reduce adolescent substance abuse, only a similarly massive increase in alcohol taxation could conceivably create comparable benefits. The path to reducing il licit drug use among schoolchi ldren is less clear. We know a lot more than we used to about education to prevent drug abuse, and most of it is discouraging. A few high-quality programs have been shown to be significantly but not spectacularly effective, reducing the prevalence of drug use among those exposed to them by about 10 percent as compared to those who haven't been in a program. Most programs do much worse than that, and so far there is on ly scanty evidence that the most popular one of a ll , Drug Abuse Resistance Education (DARE), has had any measurable effect whatsoever on drug use. (Its benefits in terms of police-community relations are a separate issue.) Media-based prevention campaigns, such as the one recently launched with great fanfare by the federal government and the Partnership for a Drug-Free America, have proven much more successful at hardening antidrug attitudes among those uninterested in drugs in the first place than at changing the behavior of those actually at risk. A case could be made for replacing much of the explicit antidrug persuasion effort with a truly educational effort aimed more broadly at achieving self-control and at recognizing and avoiding health risk behaviors, if only we knew how .

Addressing illicit drugs According to the National Household Survey, fewer than 6 million people in the United States use illicit drugs other than marijuana. Because this survey does not include the homeless and prisoners and because illicit drug users are probably undercounted because of sample bias and response bias, the actual number is probably substantially higher, though there is no carefully developed published estimate. Moreover, even for the hardest drugsheroin, cocaine, and methamphetamine-long-term addiction is far from universal among users. Estimates combining survey results with the drug tests performed on a sampling of arrestees under the National Institute of Justice Arrestee Drug Abuse Monitoring program put the total number of hard drug addicts at anyone time at fewer than 4 million. This small group of hard-core hard-drug users, which accounts for about 80 percent of total consumption, creates a set of problems out of any proportion to their numbers. They suffer enormously and cause suffering around themselves. Their health problems are extensive, their behavior frequently obnoxious. Few of them can hold down steady jobs, though many work off and on. Most of their money goes to pay for drugs; a heavy heroin or cocaine habit costs $10,000 to $15 ,000 per year. In addition to legal work, which is rarely the major source, this money comes from drug dealing, from theft, from prostitution, from relatives or lovers, and from income-support payments of various kinds. (Compared to addicts in Europe, where income-support payments are much more generous, U.S. addicts are much more likely both to work and to steal.) Of the conventional tools of drug policy-prevention , enforcement, and treatment-only treatment has much relevance to controlling the problem s of this group. Prevention is obviously too late for those who are already addicted . Enforcement al so appears to have little to offer. Policymakers have long believed that the demand for hard drugs is inelastic; that is, it is not sensitive to changes in price. Recent research (as well as common sense) contradicts this notion, suggesting that enforcement could curtail drug use if it succeeded in driving up prices. This encouraging finding, however, is offset by the discouraging fact that hard drug prices have proven remarkably insensitive to the massive increase in enforcement and punishment directed at drug dealing over the past two decades. Cocaine prices are at about one-quarter of their late-I 970s values, and heroin prices have fallen even further, to levels not recorded since the mid-I960s. But treatment matters. The benefits oftreating a hard-core addict, even if with only partial success, are enormous. The National Research Council report Treating Drug Problems summarized a mountain of data showing the correlation between treatment participation and large decreases in drug use and criminal activity . Although long-term cessation is a highly desirable goal and for most former drug abusers probably represents the only stable, healthy state, even imperfectly successful attempts to quit have benefits in the form of greatly reduced drug consumption and drug-related harm during the attempt, and lesser but still

worthwhile reductions for some time after it. When Barry McCaffrey , director of the Office of National Drug Contro l Policy, says, as he often does , "If you hate crime, you love drug treatment," he is reciting an obvious truth . Evaluated as a crim e-control measure a lone, providing drug treatment for criminally active add icts is strikingly cost-effective, reducing crim inal activity by about two-thirds at about 10 percent of the cost of a prison cell , according to a study conducted by the Ca lifornia Department of Alcohol and Drug Programs and the National Opinion Research Center. Yet here again the focus on prevalence as the single measure of drug-contro l success distorts our efforts. Consistent with the misleading notion that the best measure of the drug problem is the number of people using any quantity of any illicit drug, the goal of treatment is w idely understood as producing imm ed iate, total , and lasting abstinence. Any other outcome is scored as a failure in computing a program's success rate, and the very high rate of eventual relapse is taken as evidence that treatment is ineffective. Because addicts represent a minority of drug users and because most treatment episodes reduce drug use rather than e liminating it entirely, treatment has little impact on the total number of drug users even when it dramatically reduces the total damage. Partly because of these factors , publicly funded drug treatment remains scarce and is frequent ly of poor quality . PaJt of the reason is that treatment has become more politically unpalatable as public hostility toward drug users has intensified. The benefits to crime victim s, usually a sure winner politically, have been largely ignored , in PaJt because victims' advocacy groups, with their strong ties to law enforcement and hosti Iity to anything that might benefit offenders, have been largely silent on the matter. Even if money were no obstacle, getting hard-core hard drug users into treatment and keeping them there would remain a major problem. Unfortu nate ly, this is the group that is least likely to enter treatment vo luntarily, most expensive to treat, and least likely to succeed by the standard of total abstinence. The hard truth is that most of them would rather have drugs than treatment, as long as they can get the drugs. This gives treatment providers a strong incentive to serve other kinds of clients for whom the apparent success rate will be higher, even though the damage prevented per person treated is much lower.

Rethinking drug treatment The choice, however, does need not be left entirely up to the addicts. Sooner or later, most hard drug addicts wind up under the jurisdiction of the criminal justice system. (Although there is a small population of legitimately prosperous addicts , most find it hard to finance a heavy habit without doing something they eventually get arrested for.) About three-quarters of all heavy cocaine users , for example, are arrested in the course of a year. The criminal j ustice system can become a powerful tool for imposing treatment on those who are unwilling or unable to quit. That is the idea underlying drug diversion, drug courts, and coerced abstinence programs. Together, these three programs offer the best prospects for actua lly shrinking the hard-drug markets, reducing the criminal activity of hard-core users, and improving addicts' lives by keeping them out of prison and reducing, if not ending, their drug abuse. Drug diversion offers treatment as an alternative to prison to offenders facing criminal charges who also have substance-abuse problems. Those who fa il to appear for treatment or to comply with treatment programs may be referred back to court for sentencing on the original charge. Drug courts are a variation on the diversion theme. Instead of leaving the supervision of the addict/offender entirely up to the treatment program , drug courts use the ir own staff to monitor compliance. Drug court participants meet frequently with the judge, who hands out pra ise, censure, and , if necessary , sanctions , sometimes including time in jail. There is good evidence that diversion programs and drug courts save substantial amounts of money compared to incarceration and that they are successful in recruiting offenders into treatment and keeping them there. But both kinds of programs face serious limitations on their abi lity to expand to include a large proportion of the truly hard-core population. First, because the programs involve diversion from incarceration, the offenders involved

must be ones whom judges and prosecutors are prepared to spare from prison as long as they agree to drug treatment. This tends to exclude those with long criminal histories or records of committing violence. The ironic resu lt is that the worse an addict/offender's behav ior (and the greater the damage he or she causes), the less likely the add ict is to be pressured into change. Second, since drug courts and diversion programs re ly on vo luntary participation, some offenders simply opt out of them and take their chances with the cOUl1 system. Third, divers ion programs and drug courts req uire treatment capacity. In most places, there are already people waiting for treatment who can't get in. As a resu lt, diversion programs and drug courts may in effect transfer treatment capac ity from those who want it to those who do not. Whether this is a good idea or not depends on how good the courts are at singling out for mandatory treatment those who would do the greatest amount of social damage if untreated. A ll of th is raises a question: When offenders are subject to coercion , why coerce them into treatment rather than focus directly on the desired outcome-that they simply stop using drugs? That's the idea behind "coerced abstinence," a concept endorsed by the Clinton administration and recently adopted in Maryland and Connecticut. Probationers and parolees identified as having hard drug habits (about half of all probat ioners and parolees) are to be subjected to twice-weekly drug testing, with immediate and automatic sanctions such as community service, day reporting, or a few days beh ind bars or in a halfway house for each missed or "d irty" test. Those who cannot or wi ll not abstain under this sort of pressure can then be referred to treatment programs. Various pi lot programs and one true clinical trial , wh ich is be ing conducted at the District of Co lumb ia Drug Court and evaluated by Adele Herrell of the Urban Institute, strongly suggest that this approach will work for a large fraction of use r/offenders. One objection to the idea of coerced abstinence comes from the Much of our effort widely held but m istaken belief that addicts have no capacity to should be focused control their drug consumption without partic ipating in treatment. on frequent high Complete lack of control is often taken to be the defining dose users , characteristic of addiction. But although addiction implies espec ially those diminished control over drug-taking, it does not imply that drugwhose add iction taking has become entirely involuntary, the way a reflex action or leads t hem into the tremor of Park inson's disease is invo luntary. As Herbet1 Kleber criminal activity . of the National Center on Addiction and Substance Abuse at Columbia University is fond of saying, "Alcoholism is not a disease of the elbow." Addictive behavior is subject to manipulation by consequences, but the consequences have to be immediate and certa in, not deferred and random. The management problems of running coerced-abstinence programs are daunting, but the potential rewards are enormous. By my calcu lations, a national program could reduce the quantity of cocaine bought and so ld in this country by about 40 percent. The cost, roughly $7 bill ion per year, would be more than covered by reduced incarceration , both for the offenders under coerced-abstinence supervision and for the drug dealers they wo ul d no longer be keeping in business.

Reframing the debate Anyone expressing real optimism about the prospects for significant drug policy improvements in the short run m ight reasonably be asked what he or she has been smoking (or drinking). The most vocal critics of current po lic ies, the legalizers, have played into the hands of their drug warrior opponents by asserting that the fundamental problem is drug prohibit ion and that the only real drug policy debate is between those who support prohibition and those who oppose it. This assertion , and their subsequent backtracking into a variety of harm reduction measures and such side issues as the medica l use of marijuana, have created a political c li mate in which anyone who challenges any aspect of current pol icies can be charged with a iding and abetting the cause of drug legalization, which is supported by no more than a quarter of the voters. Nonetheless, there is an emerging consensus for change within the research community that studies drugs and drug policy. In the fall of 1997, a group of leading drug policy thinkers and law enforcement and treatment practitioners released a statement entitled "Principles for Practical Drug Policies," emphasizing the need to adopt a damage standard, address licit as

well as illicit drugs, and shift the focus of illicit drug policy away from enforcement measures and school -based and media-based drug prevention efforts and toward a new emphasis on treatment for heavy hard drug users and hard-core addicts . The College on the Problems of Drug Dependency, the largest professional organization of drug abuse researchers, and a new group of medical school deans and other high-profile medical doctors called Physician Leadership on National Drug Policy, have issued similar calls for a rethinking of current policies, again with an eye to making prohibition work better rather than repealing it. Some of the organizers of the "Princ iples for Practical Drug Policies" effort have created a project called Analysis and Dialog ue on Anti-Drug Policies and Tactics (ADAPT) under the auspices of the Federation of American Scientists . They are now assembling working groups to address specific drug policy topics , such as sentencing, retail-level law enforcement, treatment, and alcohol regulation . Some key policy reforms could include: · Using a mix of coercion and treatment to reduce drug-taking among hard-core hard-drug addicts under criminal justice supervision . · Greatly increasing alcohol and tobacco taxes and creating a media-based antidrunkenness campaign on the model of the current antismoking effort. · Changing sentencing practices and enforcement tactics to concentrate on the dealers who employ juveniles, use violence, and greatly disrupt neighborhood life, and designing retail enforcement to break up flagrant drug markets rather than simply arresting dealers. The result would be safer communities and a substantial reduction in the current level of drug law imprisonment. (Of the 1. 7 million persons now in U.S. prisons , about haifa million are confined for drug law viol ation s.) · increasing funding for publicly paid drug treatment and improving the performance of health care providers in recognizing substance abuse and undertaking interventions to deal with it. That improvement would require changes in medical education and in health care finance. Special efforts should be made to resolve the problems that currently limit opiate maintenance therapy to a small fraction of heroin addicts. These include the laws restricting methadone to specialized clinics; regulations encouraging the use of inadequate methadone dosages ; and the whole web of regulations and customs that have slowed the use of two other promising agents, LAAM (a longer-acting form of methadone) and buprenorphine. · Developing school- and media-based programs to make children more capable of selfcontrol and more aware of the need to avoid health-risk behaviors. This would require a substantial R&D effort. · Learning how to use persuasion to prevent drug dealing by youngsters. Changes in enforcement and sentencing can do part of the job, but someone ought to be talking to the kids . No one has designed such a program yet, but inaction can hardly be the right policy. With the political forces that support the current unsati sfactory set of policies and outcomes likely to remain in place for the foreseeable future , the prospects for better policies seem dim. But because no quick fix is available, we can hope that some elected officials , given adequate cover against the dreaded charge of being "soft on drugs," might be willing to accept a slow fix in the form ofa more realistic set of policies aimed at reducing the total social damage associated with drug use, drug trafficking, and drug control efforts. Even when optimism is unjustified, hope remains a virtue.

Recommended reading Avram Goldstein, Addiction: From Biology to Drug Policy. New York: W.H Freeman & Co. , 1993 . Mark Kleiman, Against Excess: Drug Policy for Results. New York: Basic Books, 1992. Robert MacCoun and Peter Reuter, Beyond the Drug War: Learning From Other Places, Other Times, and Other Vices. Cambridge University Press, forthcoming.

Peter Reuter, "Why Can't We Make Prohibition Work Better?" Proceedings ofthe American Philosophical Society, Vol. 14 1. No.3. September. 1997 . Peter Reuter, "After the Borders are Sealed: Can Domestic Sources Substitut~ for Imported Drugs')." Drug Policy in the Americas. Santa Monica, Calif: The RAND Corporation. 1992. Peter C. Rydell and Susan S. Everingham, Controlling Cocaine: Supply Versus Demand Programs. Santa Monica, Cal if.: The RAND Corporation, 1994.

Relevant Web sites College on the Problems of Drug Dependence (CPDD) "Statement on National Drug Policy" (http ://views.vcu.edu/cpdd/ policy/drugpol.html). CPDD (http ://views .vcu.edu/cpdd/).

Drug Policy Analysis Bulletin (http ://www.fas.orgldrugs/ issue4.htm). The Federation of American Scientists Drug Policy Project (http://www.fas .org/drugs) . .loin Together (a national resource center for community antidrug efforts). (http ://www.jointogether.org). Physician Leadership on National Drug Po licy (http ://www.caas.brown.edu/ plndp/ ). "Principles for Practical Drug Policies" (http: //www.fas.org/drugs/ Principles .htm).

Mark A. R. Kleiman is a professor of policy studies at UCLA, a lecturer on public policy at Harvard Medical School, and editor of the Drug Policy Analysis Bulletin. From 1979 to 1983, he was deputy director for Drug Control Programs and then director of the Office of Policy and Management Analysis of the Justice Department's Criminal Division .

;Iss

8 Contents

wlous IBXl

lIP

Drugs and Drug Policy.The Case for a Slow Fix_The University of TX ...

enforcement and imprisonment. Page 3 of 9. Drugs and Drug Policy.The Case for a Slow Fix_The U ... n Science and Technology_Mark Kleiman_Fall 1998.pdf.

4MB Sizes 3 Downloads 108 Views

Recommend Documents

Eight Questions for Drug Policy Research_The University of TX at ...
Page 2 of 11. MARK A. R. KLEIMAN. JONATHAN P. CAUL KINS. ANGELA HAWKEN. BEAU KILMER. Eight Questions for. Drug Policy Research. The current research agenda has only limited capacity to. shrink the damage caused by drug abuse. Some promising. alternat

Drug-Drug Interactions of Common OTC Drugs
diazepam, lorazepam (brand name: Ativan), temazepam. (brand name: Restoril) and others. These antihistamines increase the depressant effects (for example, sleepiness) of sleeping pills, sedatives, muscle relaxants or anti-anxiety drugs on the central

Opportunities and Barriers in Probation Reform.A Case Study of Drug ...
Opportunities and Barriers in Probation Reform.A Ca ... . Fishbein_M. Magula_W. Allen_G. Lacy_June 2002.pdf. Opportunities and Barriers in Probation Reform.

Public-health-and-international-drug- policy-thelancet-drugs-2016.pdf ...
Mar 24, 2016 - Ministry of Health, Lisbon,. Portugal (J Goulão MD);. University of British Columbia,. Center of Excellence in HIV/. AIDS, Vancouver, BC, Canada. (Prof T Kerr PhD); Centro de. Investigación y Docencia. Económicas, Mexico City,. Mexi

Violence and Drug Control Policy_ The Drugs-Violence ...
Violence and Drug Control Policy_ The Drugs-Violence Connection_07-2014.pdf. Violence and Drug Control Policy_ The Drugs-Violence Connection_07-2014.

University of Alabama Public Schools Case Study for Education
leader in computer science (CS) education. Since 2003, Gray has trained high school teachers to integrate computer science into technology courses. He also works on various aspects of piloting with the College .... He broadened his PD program in 2014

Texas Tech University, Lubbock, TX, USA ; Agrifood Solutions ...
Agrifood Solutions International, College Station, TX, USA ... Beef carcasses in a commercial facility (n = 3 per treatment) were randomly assigned to one of four ...

Case Study University of East Anglia.pages - HubSpot
Results. Talis Aspire Reading Lists and Digitised Content have now been in place for 12 months with a formal project running for the last nine months. There are.

case-study-university-of-buffalo.pdf
... apps below to open or edit this item. case-study-university-of-buffalo.pdf. case-study-university-of-buffalo.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu.

A Thesis Template for Huazhong University of Science and ... - UNL
Nov 17, 2016 - quirements for the Degree of .... 文件,其效果见hustthesis-zh-example.pdf。 1. \documentclass[degree=phd,language=chinese]{hustthesis}. 2. 3.

A Report Template for Huazhong University of Science and ... - GitHub
4 Basic Format . .... 文件,其效果见hustreport-zh-example.pdf。 1 .... \email. 4 Simple example. Below is a simple example of using this template. For a complete ...

A Thesis Template for Huazhong University of Science and ... - CTAN
November 17, 2016. Contents .... This is a thesis template for Huazhong University of Science & Tech- · nology. .... 文件,其效果见hustthesis-zh-example.pdf。 1.

A Beamer Template for Huazhong University of Science and ... - GitHub
Jun 18, 2016 - 如\email{[email protected]}会生成如下效果的地址: ... 文件,其效果见hustbeamer-example.pdf。 1 ...... \href{mailto:#1}{\texttt{#1}}. 447 }.

USF Researchers Discover Novel Drug Therapy to Slow Down ...
Sep 7, 2016 - The majority of persons over the age of 60 suffer from some degree of ARHL. ... associate director GCHSR; Dr. Bo Ding, research assistant ...

Drugs and your child - a guide for parents.pdf
to say 'no' to cigarettes, alcohol or other. substances especially if the offer comes. from a friend. • Children may experience conflicting. emotions. Curiosity or fear ...

Anatomic and Functional Characteristics of a Slow ...
reflected by a jump in their AV nodal recovery curve. The jump reflects the .... along the PNE as well as from nearby transitional tissues. The ... resolution and a 0.47-ms precision with a computer algorithm.55. Stimulation ... Instruments) and anal