Free entry and regulatory competition in a global economy Kaz Miyagiwa∗

Yasuhiro Sato†

March 26, 2014

Abstract This paper examines the optimal entry policy towards oligopoly in a global economy. We show that free entry results in too much competition for the world, but each country’s corrective tax policy, unless internationally coordinated, proves suboptimal because of international policy spillovers. Thus, globalization prevents countries from pursuing the optimal entry policy. However, globalization also generates the gains from trade. When countries are small, the gains from trade dominate the losses from a suboptimal entry policy, but as markets grow the result is reversed, making trade inferior to autarky. Therefore, the need for tax harmonization grows as the world economy grows. This paper also contributes to the international tax competition literature through the discovery of the reverse home market effect.

JEL classification: F15, H21, H77, L13 Keywords: Entry Policy, Excessive entry, Globalization, Regulatory competition ∗ †

Florida International University and Osaka University, e-mail: [email protected] Osaka University, e-mail: [email protected]

1

1

Introduction

The idea that free entry leads to a social optimum has long been cherished as an irrefragable truth in economics. However, this shibboleth is not without criticism.1 In particular, Mankiw and Whinston (1986) demonstrate that free entry results in too much competition in oligopoly if entry reduces output per firm at the margin. This condition, dubbed the “business stealing effect,” holds in a wide variety of situations; in particular, in Cournot competition. The Mankiw-Whinston analysis pertains to a closed economy, but we now live in a globalized world. It is natural to wonder whether their result carries over intact to a global environment. In a globalized economy the question whether unrestricted entry results in too much competition – and, if so, what constitutes an optimal intervention policy – can be approached from the perspective of an individual country or the entire world. The added dimensionality gives rise to possible policy conflicts and dilemmas among individual countries. It is possible, for example, that entry is excessive for the whole world but too little from an individual country’s perspective. Even if all countries agree that entry is excessive, it is another matter whether they can correct the entry problem in a globalized environment. If they fail to institute a corrective tax policy, individual countries face yet another policy dilemma, which concerns the choice between free trade and autarky. As shown by Brander and Krugman (1983), an open economy enjoys the gains from trade under oligopoly with free entry. Thus, by retreating to autarky, a country can pursue the optimal entry policy but must forgo the gains from trade. If open to trade, a country faces the opposite tradeoff. The objective of the present paper is to address these policy issues brought about by globalization. To that end, we extend the Mankiw-Whinston model of Cournot oligopoly with free entry to a two-country setting.2 In doing so, we also make an important departure. While Mankiw and Whinston (1986) consider a governmental edict to directly determine the number of active firms, we explore the corrective role of corporate income tax as an indirect entry control instrument. The 1

See von Weizsacker (1980), Perry (1984), and in particular Suzumura and Kiyono (1987). In line with Mankiw-Whinston (1986) we use the partial-equilibrium model. Our model however can be recast in a general equilibrium setting by adding another tradable good, assuming that it is produced competitively and serves as num´eraire so as to balance each country’s trade account, and endowing consumers with quasilinear preferences over the two goods. 2

2

two approaches are equivalent as they yield the same results in a closed economy, provided that the tax revenues are rebated back to society in lump-sum fashion. However, our approach has the advantage in that it also contributes to the growing literature on international tax competition. Our main findings can be summarized as follows. Firstly, free entry results in excessive competition for individual countries and for the world in a globalized environment. Thus, each country has the unilateral incentive to tax domestic firms to curb entry. However, taxation of domestic firms promotes entry in the foreign country and undermines the efficacy of domestic tax policy. As a result, each country chooses too low a tax rate relative to when there are no such tax policy spillovers. Thus, even with the corrective corporate tax policy, competition remains excessive in each country. Our analysis implies that international tax policy harmonization is indispensable for the achievement of a social optimum in a global economy. As for the dilemma concerning the choice between free trade and autarky, the answer depends on market size. When markets are small, the gains from trade dominate the welfare losses from excessive entry, so globalization benefits open economies. However, when markets are sufficiently large, this result is reversed; autarky becomes welfare-dominant. Thus, as the world economy grows, the need for coordinated tax policy also grows. These results are obtained analytically under the assumptions that include symmetry, linearity and arbitrarily low transport costs. Relaxing these conditions makes the model analytically intractable, but numerical analysis yields similar results, demonstrating that the basic mechanism yielding our analytical results is also at work in more general settings. In addition, when we relax the symmetry assumption, we obtain two new results. First, we find that the larger country hosts a smaller number of national firms relative to its market size compared with the smaller country. This finding, which we call the reverse home market effect, contrasts sharply with the standard result in economic geography and trade (see e.g., Krugman 1980; Fujita et al. 1999). Second, we find that the larger country sets the tax rate lower than the smaller country. Moreover, this tax-rate difference widens as the counties becomes more asymmetric in size. These results also contrast sharply with those well known in the standard tax competition literature. We now mention the contributions of the present work to the international tax competition

3

literature. Our first contribution is to the strand of research that goes back to Wilson (1986) and Zodrow and Mieszkowski (1986). These authors examine unilateral taxation of internationally mobile factors and show that they are taxed below the optimal rates. This suboptimality is due to the fact that taxing internationally mobile factors causes factor flight and thereby erodes each country’s tax base for the provision of public goods. In the present study, factors are internationally immobile, but similar results emerge since unilateral corporate taxation curbs entry of domestic firms but promotes entry overseas. Our analysis also contributes to the new strand of literature investigating international capital tax competition under imperfect competition. For example, Ludema and Wooton (2000) and Haufler and Wooton (2010) examine how the market (population) size affects the tax rates and welfare under Cournot competition when the number of firms is fixed. In contrast, here the number of firms is determined endogenously through entry and exit. Thus, our model can be regarded as an extension of their works to a longer run in which the distribution of firms across countries changes endogenously. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the general model. Section 3 examines the case of symmetric demands and negligible trade costs. Section 4 considers symmetric linear demands and introduces non-negligible trade costs. Section 5 extends the analysis to the case of asymmetric markets. Section 6 discusses limitations of our analysis and suggests extensions for future research.

2

The model

In this section we describe the model. Suppose there are two countries (or regions) in the world. Call them East and West. Each country has a large number of potential firms capable of producing the homogeneous good. Firms are immobile across national borders, so there is no confusion in referring to a representative firm domiciled in country i as firm i (= e, w). Let pi (Qi ) denote (inverse) demand for the good in country i, where Qi is total quantity in country i. Assume continuous differentiability with first derivatives denoted by p0i < 0. (Primes denote derivatives.) On the production side, firms face constant marginal cost c and incur setup cost ki on entry. 4

In addition, firms pay transport cost t for each unit they export. (There is no transport cost for domestic sales.) Transport cost is low enough for firms to always export positive quantities, the condition to be made more precise below. If qij denotes the quantity sold by firm i in country j (i, j = e, w), industry supply in market i equals

Qi = mi qii + mj qji

(1)

where mi represents the number of firms in country i. Firms i pay the corporate income tax τi to their home country i, earning the net profit3

πi = (1 − τi ) [(pi (Qi ) − c)qii + (pj (Qj ) − c − t)qij ] − ki .

(2)

The entry cost ki in country i is assumed to increase with the number of active firms there, so we write ki = k(mi ) with ki0 > 0.4 This assumption implies that entry entails negative externalities or congestion. Such is the case, for example, if there is limited land supply so entry of new firms drives up the land rent, an important component of setup cost. Firms consider the two national markets segmented and choose home and foreign sales, qii and qij , separately to maximize total profits (2), given all other firms’ outputs. The first-order conditions for firm i are

pi (Qi ) + p0i (Qi )qii − c = 0

(3)

pj (Qj ) + p0j (Qj )qij − c − t = 0. 3

We consider tax on operating profits. Taxing the profit net of entry cost has no impact on our qualitative results. 4 This assumption is needed only for determination of the number of firms in each country when t = 0. For t > 0, the numbers of firms are determined uniquely when firms face constant entry cost. Thus, we could let t > 0 and constant entry cost at the outset, solve the model and then take the limit t → 0 to characterize the equilibrium when t is arbitrarily low. This alternative approach yields the same results, summarized as our propositions below, but is not pursued here because the proofs are longer. Note also that here we specifically preclude the possibility of positive externalities (i.e., ki0 < 0), since that would allow an infinite number of firms to be active under free entry.

5

The second-order conditions are assumed to hold; i. e.,

2p0i (Qi ) + p00i (Qi )qij < 0

(for all i and j).

The first-order conditions can be arranged to yield the equilibrium outputs: pi (Qi ) − c ≡ qii (Qi ) p0i (Qi ) pj (Qj ) − c − t qij∗ = − ≡ qij (Qj ). p0j (Qj ) qii∗ = −

(4)

On substitution, the equilibrium profit can be expressed as # (pi (Qi ) − c)2 (pj (Qj ) − c − t)2 − − ki . πi (Qi , Qj , τi ) = (1 − τi ) − p0i (Qi ) p0j (Qj ) "

(5)

If mi is treated as a continuous variable as is standard in the literature, free entry implies zero net profit for all active firms, and hence:

πi (Qi , Qj , mi , mj , τi ) = 0,

i, j = e, w.

(6)

Further, substituting from (4) into (1) yields the equilibrium total quantity supplied in each country: Qi = mi qii (Qi ) + mj qji (Qi )

(for all i and j, i 6= j).

(7)

Equations (6) and (7) form a four-equation system which can be solved for the equilibrium industry supplies, Qe , Qw , and the equilibrium numbers of active firms, me and mw . The equilibrium firm outputs qii and qij follow from (4). Governments impose tax τi and returns the tax revenues in lump-sum fashion to domestic consumers. We assume that country i’s national welfare Wi comprises the consumer surplus, the total domestic industry profit and the tax revenue: ˆ

Qi

pi (x)dx − pi (Qi )Qi + (pi (Qi ) − c)Qii + (pj (Qj ) − c − t)Qij − mi ki .

Wi = 0

6

(8)

where we write Qii ≡ mi qii and Qij ≡ mi qij . The first two terms on the right-hand side of (8) represent the consumer surplus, the next two measure the sum of firm profits and tax revenues, and the final term is the total entry cost. The tax revenues and rebates do not figure explicitly in (8) because they cancel each other out in aggregation. This implies the absence of fiscal externality, i.e., there is no externality due to changes in the tax base. However, tax policy entails an entirely new type of externality through changes in distribution of firms across countries and affects each country’s national welfare.

3

Entry and corporate income tax in a global economy

In autarky, free entry results in too much competition but it is easy to show that excessive entry can be corrected, and a social optimum achieved, with corporate income tax. Our objective is to revisit this policy prescription in a global economy. We begin our analysis with the question: is competition excessive in an open economy as in a closed economy? The answer to this question raises two new questions absent in the analysis of a closed economy. First, if there is too much competition, does each country have the unilateral incentive to tax its firms? Second, if each country has such an incentive, can two countries attain a social optimum without harmonizing their tax policies ? In this section we address these questions under the assumptions that market demands are symmetric and transport cost t are arbitrarily small (both assumptions are relaxed later). We first use (1) and (4) to write industry supply in each market as

Qi = −

mi (p(Qi ) − c) + mj (p(Qi ) − c − t) . p0 (Qi )

As t approaches zero, this expression simplifies to

Qi = −

M (p(Qi ) − c) p0 (Qi )

7

(9)

where M = me + mw denotes the total number of active firms in the world. Differentiation yields: ∂Qi ∂mi ∂Qj ∂mi ∂qii ∂mi ∂qij ∂mi

p(Qi ) − c >0 (1 + M )p0 (Qi ) + Qi p00 (Qi ) p(Qj ) − c =− >0 (1 + M )p0 (Qj ) + Qj p00 (Qj )   ∂qji p00 (Qi )(p(Qi ) − c) ∂Qi = = −1 + <0 ∂mi (p0 (Qi ))2 ∂mi   ∂qjj p00 (Qj )(p(Qj ) − c) ∂Qj = = −1 + < 0. ∂mi (p0 (Qj ))2 ∂mi =−

(10)

The last two inequalities confirm the presence of the business-stealing effect in a global economy; namely, entry reduces the existing firm’s outputs at home and abroad at the margin. The free-entry conditions are now given by

(p(Qi ) − c)qii + (p(Qj ) − c)qij =

k(mi ) . 1 − τi

(11)

Differentiating (11) and using the derivative results in (10) leads to our first result: Proposition 1 Suppose demands are symmetric and transport costs are negligible. When a country raises its tax, domestic firms exit by a greater number than foreign firms enter, causing the total number of active firms in the world to decline.

Proof: See Appendix A The presence of the business-stealing effect implies that entry is excessive in each country. The intuition is straightforward. The marginal entrant increases total supply which is good for society but causes other firms to contract output which is bad for society. However, the marginal entrant does not take the second effect into consideration when making the entry decision. Thus, free entry leads to too much competition. Given that entry is excessive in a global economy, we turn to our next question: does each country have the unilateral incentive to control entry by its domestic firms? We answer this question by evaluating ∂Wi /∂τi at τi = τj = 0. Our finding is given in 8

Proposition 2 Suppose that demands are symmetric and transport costs are negligible. When there are no initial taxes, each country has the unilateral incentive to introduce corporate income tax.

Proof: See Appendix B Each country has the unilateral incentive to intervene because by proposition 1 taxation in one country reduces the total number of firms in the world. Given such incentives for intervention, the next question we ask is: can countries attain a social optimum when acting unilaterally? In other words, what is the total effect of the two taxes when they are not harmonized? To answer this question, we set up a three-stage game, in which each country first chooses the tax rate unilaterally to maximize its welfare, given the other county’s tax rate, then firms decide whether to enter and finally active firms engage in Cournot competition in the manner described above. We look for the symmetric subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium of this game.5 To understand the welfare properties of the equilibrium of this game, consider the effect of an exogenous change in the tax rate in country i on world welfare, namely: ∂Wi ∂Wj ∂(Wi + Wj ) = + . ∂τi ∂τi ∂τi As each country chooses the tax rate to maximize its welfare, we set ∂Wi /∂τi = 0 in the above expression and observe that the following holds at a symmetric equilibrium: ∂(Wi + Wj ) ∂Wj = . ∂τi ∂τi symmetric equilibrium symmetric equilibrium The sign of ∂Wj /∂τi |symmetric equilibrium evaluated at the equilibrium tax rate indicates whether the equilibrium tax rate is too high or too low relative to a global optimum. We show that this derivative is positive, meaning that the equilibrium tax rate is too low, i.e., there is still too much 5

We assume existence of the symmetric Nash equilibrium and study it here. It should be noted however that in general existence and uniqueness of Nash equilibrium cannot be established without additional conditions; see Vives (1999) for a review of such conditions. We have nothing to contribute to this topic here, but in section 4 we prove the existence and uniqueness of the symmetric equilibrium under the assumptions of linear demand and entry cost.

9

entry after taxation. Proposition 3 In a global economy, countries set the tax rates below the socially optimal rates. As a result, entry remains excessive even under corrective tax policy. Proof: See Appendix C. Thus, uncoordinated tax policy fails to completely eliminate excessive entry. To understand the intuition, recall that by proposition 1 unilateral taxation decreases the number of domestic firms, reducing competition and benefiting the taxing country. However, also by proposition 1, tax in one country promotes entry in the foreign country. This tax policy spillover partially offsets the beneficial effect of taxation. Unable to fully appropriate the benefits of its tax policy, each country sets the tax rate too low relative to what it would choose in the absence of such tax policy spillovers. As mentioned in the introduction, the above result is similar to the one obtained in the tax competition literature in the presence of internationally mobile factors. This literature shows that each country taxes internationally mobile factors suboptimally for fear of factor flight that erodes the country’s tax base for the provision of public goods. Corporate tax in our analysis also generates policy spillovers that result in under-taxation. However, here the spillover effect occurs not through international factor movement, which is absent, but through entry and exit of firms in each country. In summary, free entry results in too much competition in a global economy, so that each country has the incentive to tax its domestic firms to regulate entry. However, due to the policy spillovers the optimal taxation in each country, when unilaterally implemented, proves insufficient, leaving entry still excessive. Thus, our analysis implies that international tax policy harmonization is indispensable for each country and for the world.

4

Symmetric linear demand and transport cost

The objective of this section is two fold. First, we sharpen our previous results by using the specific function forms, namely, linear demand and entry cost functions. Second, such specific function 10

forms allow us to consider the case of non-negligible transport cost. We first write the demand function as

pi = A −

Qi , n

where A is demand intercept and n is the number of consumers in each country (we maintain the symmetry assumption until the next section). The entry cost function is written

k(mi ) =

km . 2

where k > 0 is constant. This entry cost function is consistent with the simple land market model with fixed land supply.6 We choose the unit so that A − c = 1. Then, country-i welfare can be expressed as  (1 − pi )2 Wi = n + si + m i π i . 2 

(12)

where si is the tax revenue per resident. Cournot competition yields the following equilibrium outputs and prices

qww = npw ,

qwe = n(pe − t)

qee = npe ,

qew = n(pw − t)

pw =

1 + tme , 1+M

pe =

(13)

1 + tmw . 1+M

Trade occurs if and only if pi > t. This condition is written 1/(1 + mi ) > t. Also, Cournot competition makes sense only if there is at least one firm in each country, so mi ≥ 1.7 These two requirements combine to yield the following regularity condition, which we assume for the 6

This entry cost has another interpretation: Suppose there are M potential firms which are heterogeneous with respect to entry cost. M is assumed to be exogenous and sufficiently large. If the entry cost is represented by κ/h where h follows a Pareto distribution with a shape parameter equal to one and with support [κ, +∞), there is a threshold level h∗ such that firms with h > h∗ enter the market and firms with h < h∗ do not enter. The entry cost for a firm h∗ becomes a linear function of mi (more precisely, kmi /2, where k is now defined as k = 2κ/M ). Pareto distributions are often assumed in models of firm heterogeneity; see Helpman et al. (2004), for instance. 7 We continue to treat mi as continuous.

11

remainder of the analysis: 1 1 ≥ > t. 2 1 + mi Substituting (13) into the firm’s profit (2) yields these free entry conditions: kmw 2(1 − τw ) kme φe = , 2(1 − τe )

φw =

(14)

where φi is the equilibrium profit per firm i (gross of the entry cost and the tax) and is given by  φi ≡ n

1 + tmj 1+M

2



1 − t(1 + mj ) +n 1+M

2 ,

i 6= j.

Two equations in (14) determine the equilibrium numbers of firms me and mw for given tax rates τe and τw . Using these rates, we obtain the next proposition, which is a generalization of proposition 2 under non-negligible trade costs. Proposition 4 Assume symmetric linear demands and non-prohibitive transport cost t. If there are no initial taxes, each country has the unilateral incentive to introduce corporate income tax.

Proof: See Appendix D. As shown by Brander and Krugman (1983), there are gains from trade under Cournot competition with free entry when transport cost is positive. However, in a globalized world economy countries cannot completely redress excess in entry without tax policy harmonization, and hence the equilibrium outcome is suboptimal. In contrast, in autarky a country can attain a social optimum with respect to entry but forgoes the gains from trade. Because of this trade-off, it is not obvious whether free trade welfare-dominates autarky. We investigate this issue using the linear model of this section. First we present the results under the assumption that transport costs are negligible.8 8 Appendix E shows the existence and uniqueness of symmetric Nash equilibrium of the tax game, and Appendix F describes the case of autarky.

12

Proposition 5 Suppose demands are linear and identical across countries. Assume that transport costs are negligible. (A) When countries are sufficiently small, the gains from trade dominate the losses from excess entry, and hence trade welfare-dominates autarky. (B) When countries are sufficiently large, the result in (A) is reversed; autarky welfare-dominates trade.

Proof: See Appendix G. We only outline the proof of the proposition here (the complete proof is in appendix G). Let the superscripts a and o denote the equilibrium value in autarky and open economy, respectively. Key to the proof are the following two welfare expressions. First,

Wia =

N ma (2 + ma ) k(ma )2 − 4(1 + ma )2 2 {z } | {za } | ≡Sia

≡Ci

gives the optimal symmetric welfare under autarky, where each government can attain a social optimum while forgoing the gains from trade. Second,

Wio =

N mo (1 + mo ) k(mo )2 − . (1 + 2mo )2 2 } | {z {z } | o ≡Sio

≡Ci

measures the equilibrium symmetric welfare under free trade, in which each country captures the gains from trade but fails to eliminate excess entry. In these expressions, Sil represents the gross social surplus, i.e., the sum of consumer surplus and profits inclusive of entry costs, and Cil represents the total cost of entry. Let N denote the total number of consumers in the world. By symmetry N = 2n. A calculation shows that ma = 1 and mo ≈ 1.1571 at N = 16k; see (E2) and (F4) in Appendix G. Since there must be at least one active firm in each country, we assume N ≥ 16k for the remainder of the analysis. Then, computation yields Wio /Wia ≈ 1.186 at N = 16k, that is, when N takes on its minimum value, each country’s welfare is greater with trade than in autarky. However, this welfare 13

ranking is reversed when N is sufficiently large. To show that, consider the ratios 4(1 + 1/ma )2 (1 + 1/mo ) Sio = Sia (1 + 2/ma )(2 + 1/mo )2 2  Cio mo . = Cia ma (E2) and (F4) in Appendix G imply that limN →+∞ ma = +∞ and limN →+∞ mo = +∞ but limN →+∞ mo /ma = +∞. Therefore, as N goes to infinity the surplus ratio Sio /Sia converges to one, but the entry cost ratio Cio /Cia grows without bounds. These two results imply that Wio /Wia < 1 for N sufficiently large. That is, each country is better off in autarky than in an open economy when the markets are sufficiently large. In the next section we demonstrate these results by numerical analysis. Proposition 5 has the following intuition. In the absence of no transport cost, going from autarky to trade has no effect on the equilibrium price and firm profit in the Cournot model.9 Hence, the total number of active firms remains unchanged. This also means there are no gains from trade. These results do not hold in the presence of corrective corporate taxation. As we saw above, in autarky the corporate tax can keep the number of firms at the optimum. In contrast, under trade the corrective tax is insufficient, allowing new firms to enter. Thus, more firms are active under trade than in autarky. Trade-induced entry has two implications for our analysis. First, it implies that trade lowers the price and increases the consumer surplus. Second, however, trade also raises the social entry cost. The market size has differential impact on the magnitudes of those two effects from tradeinduced entry. First, firms face decreasing average cost in the presence of entry cost. Therefore, when markets are larger, firms realize more substantial scale economies to the effect that the prices are already lower without trade. With linear demand, that means that a larger country has less price-elastic demand in autarky. Therefore, trade-induced entry of new firms has less impact on the price and the consumer surplus. Thus, trade generates relatively less consumer surplus when markets are larger. On the other hand, larger markets have a greater number of active firms 9

This appears contradictory to the Brander-Krugman gains-from-trade proposition, but is not. Their result is predicated on the presence of transport cost, without which the gains from trade vanishes.

14

and hence suffers from higher total entry cost. Trade-induced entry raises total entry cost at the margin as much when markets are larger as when markets are smaller. Thus, when markets are sufficiently large, an increase in total entry cost can dominate an increase in consumer surplus at the margin.10 Hence, when two countries are sufficiently large, addressing the entry problem becomes more important than pursuing the gains from trade.11 Proposition 5 therefore implies that the need for international tax harmonization increases as the world economy grows. Proposition 5 is predicated on the assumption that trade cost is negligible. We now extend the above analysis to the case of non-negligible trade costs. Non-negligible trade costs make the model analytically intractable, so we resort to numerical analysis. The four panels of figure 1 presents our simulation results. The entry cost parameter k is set equal to k = 1 so that entry cost is written ki = mi /2.12 Each country’s consumer population is set equal to n = 20. In panel 1-(a), the ratio (M o /M ∗ ) on the vertical axis is the measure of excess entry, where M o denotes the number of the total firms in an open economy with uncoordinated tax policy and M ∗ the optimal number of firms that maximizes world welfare We + Ww . The panel shows that entry remains excessive even at non-negligible transport cost. This demonstrates proposition 3 in the presence of non-negligible transport cost. The panel also shows that the degree of excess in entry falls as transport cost rises. Intuitively speaking, this result holds because a higher trade cost makes countries less open so that the tax spillover effect is weaker, making domestic tax policy more effective in combating excessive entry. Therefore, the degree of excess in entry declines as transport cost rises.

[Figure 1 around here]

The next three panels concern the impact of trade on welfare under optimal tax policy. In each panel, the vertical axis measures the welfare effect of switching from autarky to trade. Panel 1-(b) illustrates the effect of changes in market size (population) on the welfare impact of trade at four different transport costs (t = 0, 0.001, 0.025, 0.05). The trade costs are differentiated 10

Note that this result holds even if the per-firm entry cost is constant. Thus, our result does not depend on the assumption of entry congestion. 11 This result is unaltered qualitatively if we focus on per capita welfare (i.e., Wi /n) because we can readily see that sgn[Wio /n − Wia /n] = sgn[Wio − Wia ]. See also Figure 1-(d). 12 The cases where k = 0.5 and1.5 yield similar results.

15

by the thickness of the curves; the thicker the curve, the higher the transport cost. Each curve first rises from one but eventually falls below zero. This indicates that at small populations trade welfare-dominates autarky while at larger populations the converse is true. Thus, our numerical analysis shows that proposition 5 holds at non-negligible transport costs. The underlying intuition is already discussed below proposition 5. Panel 1-(b) also shows that a rise in transport cost reduces the benefits of trade at any given population. The intuition is the same as above; the higher the trade cost, the weaker the spillover effect, and hence the more effective is the tax policy. Thus, at higher transport cost autarky is more attractive than trade. This result is more evident in panel 1-(c), where transport cost continuously changes while the population is fixed at three levels (n = 10, 15, 20, i.e., N = 20, 30, 40). Finally, panel 1-(d) evaluates the welfare effect of population changes in per capita terms. As with the corresponding aggregate measures in panel 1-(b), trade welfare-dominates autarky at small populations but the converse holds at larger populations. The only difference is that here, unlike in panel 1-(b), the benefits of trade per capita monotonically decline as the world population grows. To conclude, the numerical results replicate our analytical results in the presence of nonnegligible transport cost. We end this section with a slight digression.13 In the above analysis we examined the effect of market size as the world economy grew. In other words, growth of countries in question was synonymous with that of the world economy. We now separate these two elements. To that end, we suppose that the good in question is still produced only in the two countries under consideration, and examine the effect of changes in market size of these countries while holding the world population constant. In this setting, we find that the gains from trade still dominate the losses from excess entry when the countries have small populations, but this dominance is reversed when their populations are sufficiently large. The proof is similar to the one used to establish proposition 5. e represent the world population. Assume that the two countries are symmetric and have Let N e ,where 0 < ε < 1. The rest of the world has the population of the combined population of εN e . Now, by changing ε, we can examine the effects of different market sizes without size (1 − ε)N 13

We thank the editor for suggesting this possibility.

16

changing the world population. In this setting, the autarkic equilibrium is the same as in our basic model, but there are more to gain from trade as firms export to more than one country. To be more specific, let n e represent the threshold population at which the gains from trade between the two countries are balanced against the losses from excess entry in each country. Assume that 2e n e . Then we can show that the gains from trade dominates the losses is sufficiently smaller than N e . This from excess entry when the two countries are sufficiently small in the sense that ε < 2e n/N corresponds to result (A) of proposition 5. Even if the two countries total population grows slightly above the threshold 2e n, the gains from trade still dominates the welfare losses from excess entry because of trade with the rest of the world. Eventually, however, as ε → 1, the gains from trade with the rest of the world becomes minuscule and the welfare ranking is reversed as in result (B) of proposition 5. In conclusion, the presence of the rest of the world does not affect result (A) of proposition 5 but makes result (B) less likely when two countries remain small relative to the rest of the world.

5

Asymmetric countries

In this section we relax the symmetry assumption in market size. Assume without loss of generality that West has the fraction θ of the world population, where 1 > θ ≥ 1/2, i.e., West is the larger of the two countries. For simulation purposes the total (world) population is fixed at N = 30, the entry cost parameter at k = 1, and the transport cost at t = 0.025.14

[Figure 2 around here]

The first question we address concerns the relationship between the population distribution and the firm distribution across countries. To this end we construct the ratio (mw /me )/ [θ/(1 − θ)] in the absence of taxes. The numerator measures the number of domestic firms located in West relative to East. The denominator measures the relative population residing in West. In the standard literature this ratio exceeds one, implying that a large country has a proportionately 14

We checked the robustness of the results against different parameter values: N = 20, 40, k = 0.5, 1.5 and t = 0.001, 0.05. These alternative parameter values did not affect the qualitative results of this section.

17

greater number of domestic firms than a smaller country. This disproportional concentration of firms in a large country is known as the home country effect. In our model, however, this ratio stays less than one at all relevant values of θ as shown in figure 2.15 Thus, in our model a large country has a fewer domestic firms per capita compared with a small country. Since our result contrasts sharply with the standard result, we call ours the reverse home market effect. The reverse home market effect has a simple intuitive explanation. We already noted that in the presence of entry cost a larger market is served by a relatively fewer and more efficient firms than a smaller market due to decreasing average cost. The same intuition holds in a global economy. The reverse home market effect is also featured in the work of Sato and Thisse (2007). There, however, the reverse home market effect arises for an entirely different reason; competition among firms in the local labor market. Thus, their mechanism is distinct from the one highlighted here.16

[Figure 3 around here]

We next turn to the relationship between the market size asymmetry and the optimal tax rates. Figure 3 depicts how the equilibrium tax rates change as θ increases from 0.5 to 0.8 (the large country gets larger). The large country’s tax rate is represented by the solid line, and the small country’s tax rate by the dashed line. Figure 3 reveals two important results. First, the thick line lies below the dashed line in the figure. Thus, the tax rates are lower in the large country at all θ > 1/2. Second, as the large country gets larger, its tax falls monotonically in the large country while the tax in the smaller country rises monotonically. Thus, as countries become more asymmetric, the tax rates further diverge. These results have the following intuitive explanation. Due to the reverse home market effect, the large country has a fewer home firms relative to its population compared with the small country. 15

Our numerical analysis shows that the equilibrium is unique despite asymmetric market sizes. However, with asymmetry we cannot generally rule out the possibility of multiple equilibria. 16 Head et al. (2002) analyze the models involving increasing returns and trade to assess the robustness of the home market effect against alternative modeling assumptions. They find that, when the traded goods are differentiated between trading countries and not among firms, even a fairly standard trade model can exhibit the reverse home market effect.

18

This implies that entry is less excessive in the large country. Therefore, the large country has less need for corrective tax and hence sets the tax at a lower rate than does the smaller country. These results contrast sharply with the well-known result in the standard tax competition literature, which predicts that the tax rates are higher in the large country than in the small country.17 It is interesting to note however that this standard result is not always borne out empirically. For example, Devereux et al. (2002) find mixed results in their study of the effective corporate tax rates among OECD countries. According to their study, for instance, larger countries such as Germany, Japan, and the United States choose higher effective corporate taxes than their smaller counterparts, Austria, Finland and Sweden, in consonance with the standard literature, whereas smaller countries such as Belgium and Greece set higher taxes than their larger counterparts, France and the United Kingdom, contradicting the standard result in the literature; see figure 7 in Devereux et al. (2002). Moreover, Hines (2005) examine a change over time in the extent to which country size is correlated with tax rates and concluded that one cannot observe such correlation in recent years. It is noted that these rates are economy-wide tax rates. Since the corrective tax we consider is sector-specific, our results are not meant to predict what the economy-wide tax rates are. Still, our analysis may offer a clue as to why empirical findings are inconclusive.

[Figure 4 around here]

Finally, we examine the effect of market size asymmetry on the welfare impact of trade, both in aggregate and per capita terms. In figure 4, the benefits of trade are represented by the solid line for the large country and by the dashed line for the small country. As the large country gets larger, the benefits of trade decrease for the large country, but increase for the small country in both terms. The intuition is now familiar. The larger country can realize the substantial economies of 17

For earlier contributions, see Bucovetsky (1991) and Wilson (1991) on perfectly competitive product markets. More recent studies use models of imperfect competition. They find that in the presence of the home market effect the large country set a higher tax rate than the small country to capture the “agglomeration rent.” See Andersson and Forslid (2003), Baldwin et al. (2003), Baldwin and Krugman (2004), Borck and Pfl¨ uger (2006), Haufler and Wooton (2010), Kind et al. (2000), Ludema and Wooton (2000), and Ottaviano and van Ypersele (2005). Haufler and Pfl¨ uger (2004) examine commodity tax competition under monopolistic competition. Pfl¨ uger and Suedekum (2012) examine the relationship between trade costs and governments’ decisions to subsidize firm entry in the model of monopolistic competition with heterogeneous firms.

19

scale without the market-expanding effect of trade. Therefore, for the larger country, correcting the entry problem takes precedence over accessing a small foreign market. As the distribution becomes more lopsided, the benefits of trade further decline in the large country, while the converse holds in the small country.

6

Concluding remarks

In a close economy free entry leads to too much competition in oligopolistic industry. This paper considers this Mankiw-Whinston (1986) proposition in a global economy. We first show that without government interventions the problem of excessive entry inheres in a globalized world. More importantly, in a global economy corrective tax measures cannot completely eliminate excessive entry without international tax harmonization, because taxation in one country promotes entry in the other country, partially offsetting the effect of the tax and reducing the efficacy of the tax policy. For this reason, countries set tax rates too low relative to a global optimum, leading to a suboptimal equilibrium. However, globalization also generates the gains from trade as shown by Brander and Krugman (1983). Therefore, the overall welfare effect of globalization hinges on the balance between the gains from trade and the welfare loss from the inability to pursue the optimal entry policy in an open economy. We find that, when countries are small, the gains from trade dominate so trade raises aggregate welfare. When countries are large, however, the result reverses itself, implying that autarky is better than trade. Thus, our analysis indicates that coordinated tax policy is essential for a global optimum and that the need for tax harmonization increases as the world economy grows. These results are derived from the highly stylized model that omits several important tax policy issues from consideration. Several limitations of our analysis are now mentioned and suggestions are made for possible extensions. First, income distribution is an important element of any optimal tax policy. We however assume homogeneous households and abstract away from any income distributional consequences of tax policy. Second, we consider only lump-sum tax/transfer schemes. Therefore, many important second-best welfare analysis complexities arising when governments use 20

multiple distortionary policy instruments are left unexamined. Incorporating these complexities will make our model more realistic but is unlikely to reverse our main results. Third, we take pure profits as the tax base, but in most real-world tax systems some production costs are tax-deductible. In our model, even if part (or all) of the variable costs can be deducted from the tax base, taxation is still effective in reducing the number of firms but it also generates the policy spillover effect. Thus, our results still hold with tax deductibility.18 Fourth, if industries have different entry costs, industry-specific corrective tax policy is needed to achieve a social optimum in autarky. To that end, corporate tax may be too unwieldy as it sets a uniform rate in many sectors of the economy. If corporate tax cannot correct the entry problem in autarky, the case for autarky is weakened. However, in practice corporate income tax is not used solely to affect entry. Given that corporate tax exists for other purposes, the government can adjust its effective tax rates for specific industries with tax credit or deductibility. An interesting extension of our analysis is to investigate the second-best nature of the optimal entry policy when there are multiple sectors with independent or interrelated entry costs. Fifth, our analysis does not allow firms to move internationally. However, even if firms can move between countries, our results remain unaffected. The reason is that, here, free entry drives the firm profits to zero in both countries, so there is no scope for arbitrage across countries. A related but more serious limitation of our analysis is the absence of international capital flows and foreign direct investment. If we allow international factor movements, we also have to bring agglomeration into play. If agglomeration economies are strong enough, we may observe asymmetric equilibria even if we consider symmetric countries (see, e.g., Fujita, Krugman and Venables, 1999). Then, a country having a larger share of firms can impose higher corporate taxes than the other country without losing its firms so as to reap “agglomeration rents” (see Ottaviano and van Ypersele, 2005). If the agglomeration effect dominates the effect highlighted in this paper, the country with a larger share of firms could set the tax rate above the optimal rate. Finally, while we consider Cournot oligopoly, other types of imperfect competition such as Bertrand and monopolistic competition can be considered. While Bertrand models are expected to yield results similar to the ones we obtain here, monopolistic competition models may behave quite 18

Janeba (1995) discusses a model in which both corporate tax rates and deductibility rules are strategic variables.

21

differently because it is known that free entry results in too little competition under monopolistic competition (Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977). Relaxing these limitations requires separate treatment and are left for future research.

Appendix A:

Proof of Proposition 1.

The free entry condition (11) forms a two-equation system that is solvable for Qe and Qw in terms of me and mw for given τe and τw . Denote the derivative of the left-hand side of (11) with respect to mj by βij and define B by 



 β11 β12  B≡ , β21 β22 where ∂qii ∂Qj ∂qij k 0 (mi ) ∂Qi + (p(Qi ) − c) + qij p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) − ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi 1 − τi ∂Qi ∂qii ∂Qj ∂qij ≡ qii p0 (Qi ) + (p(Qi ) − c) + qij p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂Qi ∂qji ∂Qj ∂qjj ≡ qji p0 (Qi ) + (p(Qi ) − c) + qjj p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi ∂qji ∂Qj ∂qjj k 0 (mj ) ∂Qi + (p(Qi ) − c) + qjj p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) − . ≡ qji p0 (Qi ) ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj 1 − τj

β11 ≡ qii p0 (Qi ) β12 β21 β22

Differentiating the system (11), we obtain 







0

 2

1  β22 −β12   k (mi )/(1 − τi )   ∂mi /∂τi   =    det(B) ∂mj /∂τi −β21 β11 0   k 0 (mi )  β22  =  . 2 det(B)(1 − τi ) −β21 Note here that (10) implies that ∂Qi /∂mi = ∂Qi /∂mj , ∂Qj /∂mi = ∂Qj /∂mj , ∂qii /∂mi = ∂qii /∂mj , ∂qjj /∂mi = ∂qjj /∂mj , ∂qij /∂mi = ∂qij /∂mj and ∂qji /∂mi = ∂qji /∂mj , which lead to β22 < β21 < 0 and hence −∂mi /∂τi > ∂mj /∂τi > 0. By using these properties, we observe that 22

the determinant of B is positive since  ∂Qi ∂Qj k 0 (mi )(1 − τj ) + k 0 (mj )(1 − τi ) qii p0 (Qi ) + qjj p0 (Qj ) det(B) = − n(1 − τi )(1 − τj ) ∂mi ∂mj  0 0 ∂qjj k (mi )k (mj ) ∂qii + (p(Qj ) − c) + >0 +(p(Qi ) − c) ∂mi ∂mj (1 − τi )(1 − τj ) where the inequality comes from the assumptions on p(Qi ) and k(mi ), and (10). We also know that β21 < 0 and β22 < 0. Hence, ∂mi <0 ∂τi

and

∂mj > 0. ∂τi

Moreover, using the above properties, we have ∂mi ∂mj ∂τi > ∂τi .

Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 2. Differentiate (8) and evaluate the result at τi = τj = 0 to obtain   ∂Qi ∂qii ∂Qj ∂Qi ∂Wi 0 = −Qi p (Qi ) + mi qii p0 (Qi ) + (p(Qi ) − c) + qij p0 (Qj ) ∂τi τi =τj =0 ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi    ∂mi ∂Qi ∂qij ∂Qi − k 0 (mi ) + −Qi p0 (Qi ) + mi qii p0 (Qi ) +(p(Qj ) − c) ∂mi ∂τi ∂mj ∂mj  ∂qii ∂Qj ∂qij ∂mj +(p(Qi ) − c) + qij p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) . ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂τi By (9), Qi = Qj . This and (10), imply that qii = qjj = qij = qji , ∂Qj /∂mi = ∂Qi /∂mi and ∂Qj /∂mj = ∂Qi /∂mj . The free entry condition (11) at no tax (τi = τj = 0) implies mi = mj .

23

Using these results, we obtain   ∂Qi ∂Qi ∂qii ∂Wi ∂Qi 0 0 0 + mi qii p (Qi ) + mj qji p (Qi ) + mi (p(Qi ) − c) = −Qi p (Qi ) ∂τi τi =τj =0 ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi   ∂qij ∂mi ∂Qi ∂Qi +(p(Qj ) − c) − k 0 (mi ) + −Qi p0 (Qi ) + mi qii p0 (Qi ) ∂mi ∂τi ∂mj ∂mj   ∂Qi ∂qii ∂qij ∂mj +mj qji p0 (Qi ) + mi (p(Qi ) − c) + (p(Qj ) − c) ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂τi   ∂qij ∂mi ∂qii + (p(Qj ) − c) − k 0 (mi ) = mi (p(Qi ) − c) ∂mi ∂mi ∂τi   ∂qii ∂qij ∂mj + mi (p(Qi ) − c) + (p(Qj ) − c) . ∂mj ∂mj ∂τi Proposition 1 (−∂mi /∂τi > ∂mj /∂τi > 0) and the properties used in Appendix A (∂qii /∂mi = ∂qii /∂mj and ∂qij /∂mi = ∂qij /∂mj ) imply   ∂Wi ∂qii ∂mi ∂qij 0 > mi (p(Qi ) − c) + (p(Qj ) − c) − k (mi ) ∂τi τi =τj =0 ∂mi ∂mi ∂τi    ∂qij ∂mi ∂qii + mi (p(Qi ) − c) + (p(Qj ) − c) − ∂mj ∂mj ∂τi ∂mi = −k 0 (mi ) > 0. ∂τi

Appendix C: Proof of Proposition 3. Equations (9) and (10) imply that Qi = Qj , qii = qjj = qij = qji , mi = mj , ∂Qj /∂mi = ∂Qi /∂mi , ∂Qj /∂mj = ∂Qi /∂mj , ∂Qi /∂mi = ∂Qi /∂mj , ∂Qj /∂mi = ∂Qj /∂mj , ∂qii /∂mi = ∂qii /∂mj , ∂qjj /∂mi = ∂qjj /∂mj , ∂qij /∂mi = ∂qij /∂mj , ∂qji /∂mi = ∂qji /∂mj , and −∂mi /∂τi > ∂mj /∂τi > 0 (−∂mj /∂τj > ∂mi /∂τj > 0). When each government chooses the tax rate simulta-

24

neously, the first-order condition for country j is given by  ∂Qj ∂Qj ∂qjj ∂Qi −Qj p (Qj ) + mj qjj p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) + qji p0 (Qi ) ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi   ∂mi ∂Qj ∂qji + −Qj p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) +(p(Qi ) − c) ∂mi ∂τj ∂mj   ∂Qj ∂qjj ∂Qi ∂qji ∂mj 0 0 0 +mj qjj p (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) + qji p (Qi ) + (p(Qi ) − c) − k (mj ) ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂τj

∂Wj = ∂τj



0

= 0.

Using the properties given at the top of this appendix, we obtain ∂Wj ∂τj   ∂qjj ∂qji ∂mi = mj (p(Qj ) − c) + (p(Qi ) − c) ∂mi ∂mi ∂τj    ∂mj ∂qjj ∂qji 0 + (p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) + mj (p(Qj ) − c) + (p(Qi ) − c) − k (mj ) ∂mj ∂mj ∂τj    ∂qjj ∂qji ∂mj > mj (p(Qj ) − c) + (p(Qi ) − c) − ∂mi ∂mi ∂τj    ∂qji ∂mj ∂qjj 0 + (p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) + mj (p(Qj ) − c) + (p(Qi ) − c) − k (mj ) , ∂mj ∂mj ∂τj

0=

which simplifies to

0 > [(p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) − mj k 0 (mj )]

∂mj . ∂τj

Because ∂mj /∂τj < 0, we now have that 0 < (p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) − mj k 0 (mj ).

25

(C1)

In a symmetric equilibrium, ∂Wj ∂τi symmetric equilibrium   ∂Qj ∂qjj ∂Qi ∂Qj 0 + mj qjj p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c) + qji p0 (Qi ) = −Qj p (Qj ) ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi ∂mi   ∂qji ∂mi ∂Qj +(p(Qi ) − c) + −Qj p0 (Qj ) + (p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) ∂mi ∂τi ∂mj   ∂qjj ∂Qi ∂qji ∂mj ∂Qj 0 0 0 + (p(Qj ) − c) + qji p (Qi ) + (p(Qi ) − c) − k (mj ) . +mj qjj p (Qj ) ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂mj ∂τi Use symmetry to simplify the above as ∂Wj ∂τi symmetric equilibrium   ∂qji ∂mi ∂qjj > mj (p(Qj ) − c) + (p(Qi ) − c) ∂mi ∂mi ∂τi    ∂qjj ∂qji ∂mi + mj (p(Qj ) − c) + (p(Qi ) − c) − ∂mj ∂mj ∂τi ∂mj ∂τi ∂mj = [(p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) − mj k 0 (mj )] ∂τi

+ [(p(Qj ) − c)qjj + (p(Qi ) − c)qji − k(mj ) − mj k 0 (mj )]

> 0.

The last inequality comes from (C1) and ∂mj /∂τi > 0.

Appendix D: Proof of Proposition 4. We use (14) to derive 







kmi  −2φj /(1 + M ) − k/[2(1 − τj )]   ∂mi /∂τi   .  = 2 det(Φ)(1 − τi )2 2φj /(1 + M ) − Ψi ∂mj /∂τi

26

(D1)

Here, Φ and Ψi are defined by 



∂φw /∂me  ∂φw /∂mw − k/[2(1 − τw )]  Φ≡  ∂φe /∂mw ∂φe /∂me − k/[2(1 − τe )]   −2φw /(1 + M ) + Ψe  −2φw /(1 + M ) − k/[2(1 − τw )]  =  −2φe /(1 + M ) + Ψw −2φe /(1 + M ) − k/[2(1 − τe )] and Ψi ≡

2nt2 (1 + 2mi ) . (1 + M )2

In the first stage, each government chooses the tax rate, taking the other government’s tax rate as given and anticipating the responses of firms (described in (D1)). Maximization of national welfare n Wi = 2



M − tmj 1+M

2

(  )  2 2 1 + tmj 1 − t(1 + mj ) kmi + mi n +n − . 1+M 1+M 2

(D2)

gives the first-order condition for country i:     ∂Wi 2ξi1 ξi2 2ξi1 ξi3 ∂mi ∂mj 0= = − + − kmi + − + . 3 2 3 2 ∂τi (1 + M ) (1 + M ) ∂τi (1 + M ) (1 + M ) ∂τi

(D3)

where (M − tmj )2 ξi1 ≡ n + mi (1 + tmj )2 + mi [1 − t(1 + mj )]2 2  ξi2 ≡ n M − tmj + (1 + tmj )2 + [1 − t(1 + mj )]2   ξi3 ≡ n (1 − t)(M − tmj ) + 2t2 mi (1 + 2mj ) . 



The first-order condition (D3) simplifies to  −

2ξi1 ξi2 + − kmi 3 (1 + M ) (1 + M )2



2φj k + 1+M 2(1 − τj )

27



 = −

2ξi1 ξi3 + 3 (1 + M ) (1 + M )2



 2φj − Ψi . 1+M (D4)

Note that τe = τw = 0 leads to the symmetric number of firms mw = me = M/2. Now, evaluating ∂Wi /∂τi at τw = τe = 0, we obtain  ∂Ww sgn = sgn [Ξ] ∂τw τw =τe =0 

(D5)

where (

 2 Ξ ≡ k(1 + M ) (1 + 3M ) + n M (7 + 4M ) t −

3M − 1 M (7 + 4M )

2

25M 2 + 22M + 1 − M (7 + 4M )

) .

A calculation yields n (25M 2 + 22M + 1) M (7 + 4M ) 2 4n(1 + 3M ) n (25M + 22M + 1) > − M M (7 + 4M ) n(23M 2 + 78M + 27) = M (7 + 4M )

Ξ ≥ k(1 + M )2 (1 + 3M ) −

> 0.

The second inequality comes from k(1 + M )2 > 4n/M using the first-order condition (14).19 From (D5), we have ∂Ww > 0. ∂τw τw =τe =0

Appendix E: The existence and uniqueness of symmetric Nash equilibrium of the tax game. Assume no trade cost. Taking the limit of t → 0, we obtain Ψi = 0, ξi1 = nM 2 /2 + N mi , ξi2 = nM + N and ξi3 = nM . Then, by (14), (D4) can be written as  −

2ξi1 ξi2 + − kmi (1 + M )3 (1 + M )2



1 mj + 2 1+M

19



 = −

 2ξi1 ξi3 mj + (1 + M )3 (1 + M )2 1 + M

Summing up the zero profit conditions for two countries after substituting τw = τe = 0, we obtain that kM/2 = φw + φe > 2n/(1 + M )2 .

28

which simplifies to   2mj N (1 + 3mj − mi ) + nM . = kmi 1 + (1 + M )3 1+M

(E1)

First, we show that the first-order condition (E1) determines (τwo , τeo ) uniquely. Subtracting (E1) of West from that of East, we obtain 

 4N + k (mw − me ) = 0. (1 + M )3

Because the bracketed term is positive, mow = moe = M/2. Substituting me = mw into (E1), we obtain k=

N (1 + 3mw ) . mw (1 + 2mw )2 (1 + 4mw )

(E2)

The right hand side of (E2) is decreasing in mw . Hence, given k < 4N/45, it has the unique solution for mw > 0, which determines (mow , moe ) uniquely. Substituting t = 0 into (14), and using the fact that (mow , moe ) is unique and me = mw , we can determine (τwo , τeo ) uniquely and τwo = τeo . Next, we show that Ww |τe =τeo is quasi-concave in τw . The second derivative of Ww |τe =τeo with respect to τw at (τwo , τeo ) (and hence at (mow , moe )) is given by  d2  k 2 M (1 + M )2 [4k 2 M (1 + M )5 + σ1 + σ2 + σ3 ] Ww |τe =τeo = − dτw2 8(1 − τwo )[k(1 + M )3 + 8N (1 − τwo )]3

(E3)

where

σ1 ≡ k 2 M 2 (1 + M )5 (16 + 13M ), σ2 ≡ −8N 2 (1 − τwo )(4 + M )(1 + 3M ),  σ3 ≡ kN (1 + M )2 −4 + M (21 − 32τwo ) + M 2 [151 + 158M − 152τwo (1 + M )] . Here, use has been made of the fact that mow = moe = M/2. This fact allows the free entry condition

29

(14) and the first order condition (E1) to be rewritten

4N (1 − τwo ) = kM (1 + M )2 ,   3M 2 kM (1 + M ) (1 + 2M ) = 2N 1 + . 2 Substituting these into σ1 and σ2 yields 2N kM (1 + M )3 (16 + 13M )(1 + 3M/2) σ1 = 1 + 2M σ2 = −2N kM (1 + M )2 (4 + M )(1 + 3M ).

Hence, σ1 + σ2 =

2N kM (1 + M )2 {24 + M [64 + M (55 + 27M )]} > 0. 2 + 4M

(E4)

Moreover, since mow = moe > 1, the total number of firms M is larger than 2. Hence,   σ3 > kN (1 + M )2 −4 + M (21 − 32τwo ) + M 2 (6M − 1)

(E5)

> kN (1 + M )2 [−4 + M (21 − 32τwo + 11M )] > kN (1 + M )2 [−4 + 11M (M − 1)] > kN (1 + M )2 (11M − 4) > 0.

From (E3), (E4) and (E5), we have that  d2  Ww |τe =τeo < 0. dτw2 Because there exists a unique τwo that satisfies the first order condition dWw /dτw = 0 for τeo , Ww (τw , τeo ) is quasi-concave in τw . Similar arguments hold for East. Next, we check the behavior of dWw /dτw when τw → 1 or τw → −∞. For τeo given, it follows from (14) that limτw →1 mw = 0, limτw →−∞ mw = +∞, limτw →1 me = m b < +∞ and

30

limτw →−∞ me = 0 where m b is determined by 2N (1 − τeo ) = m(1 + m)2 .

Using (14), dWw /dτw |τe =τeo can be rearranged to yield    dWw N (1 + 3me − mw ) + nM kN 2me − = + kmw 1 + dτw τe =τeo (1 − τeo ) (1 + M )3 1+M   −1 2N 1+M k(1 + M ) × + mw + . 1+M 1 − τeo 2 From this, we obtain dWw dWw lim = lim τw →1 dτw (mw ,me )→(0,m) b dτw τe =τeo τe =τeo =−

kN 2 (2 + 7m) b < 0. (1 + m) b 2 [k(1 + m) b 3 + 4N (1 − τeo )]

and lim

τw →−∞

dWw dWw = lim = 0. dτw τe =τeo (mw ,me )→(+∞,0) dτw τe =τeo

These two conditions and quasi-concavity of Ww (τw , τeo ) imply that Ww (τw , τeo ) is maximized at τwo . In other words, (τwo , τeo ) is a Nash equilibrium of the tax game. It remains to consider the cases of corner solutions in which one country has no firms (mi = 0). Two cases can arise. In one, a country sets a tax rate so high that it loses all firms. Clearly, such a strategy is never optimal for this country. In the other, a country gives such a high subsidy that it gets all firms. Again, this cannot happen in equilibrium because the other government would reduce its tax rate. Thus, (τwo , τeo ) is the unique Nash equilibrium of the tax game.

Appendix F: Autarky with linear functions. In this appendix, we characterize the equilibrium allocation under autarky. Cournot competi-

31

tion leads to the following quantities of output and the price

q=

n , 1+m

mn , 1+m

Q=

p=

1 . 1+m

(F1)

The profit (2) of a firm then becomes as  π = n(1 − τ )

1 1+m

2 −

km . 2

The zero profit condition π = 0 in the second stage determines the number of firms for a given corporate tax: k=

2n(1 − τ ) . m(1 + m)2

(F2)

In the first stage, each government maximizes the welfare function (12) with respect to τ subject to the balanced-budget constraint sn = mnτ /(1 + m)2 . By (F2), corporate taxation reduces the number of firms (∂m/∂τ < 0). Substituting (F1) and sn = mnτ /(1 + m)2 into (12), we obtain 

  n m  km W =m − . 1+ (1 + m)2 2 2

(F3)

By (F2), the number of firms m is a function of tax rate τ , which makes welfare in (F3) a function of τ . Taking ∂m/∂τ < 0 into consideration, the first-order condition of welfare maximization yields τa = 1 −

1 2(1 + ma )

where ma is determined by k=

n . ma (1 + ma )3

(F4)

Since there are more than one firm in the equilibrium, (F4) implies that n ≥ k (i.e., N ≥ 2k), which in turn implies that the equilibrium tax rate is positive (τ a > 0). It is straightforward that this allocation is optimal.

Appendix G: Proof of Proposition 5. 32

Calculations show that mi ≥ 1 in the closed economy (resp. in the open economy) if and only if N ≥ λa k (resp. N ≥ λo k) where λa ≈ 16 (resp. λo ≈ 11.25). Therefore, we focus on N/k ∈ [16, +∞) so that the number of firms is larger than one in both economies. Equations (F3) and (D2) are rearranged as

Wia

N ma (2 + ma ) k(ma )2 − = 4(1 + ma )2 2

(G1)

N mo (1 + mo ) k(mo )2 . − (1 + 2mo )2 2

(G2)

and Wio =

In the followings, we show (A) that Wio > Wia when N is equal to 16k, but (B) that the result is reversed when N goes to infinity. When N is equal to 16k, (E2) and (F4) yield ma = 1 and mo ≈ 1.1571, respectively. Using these values we can calculate Wio ≈ 1.186. Wia which establishes claim A above. As for claim B, we first show how ma and mo diverge when N goes to infinity. Define δ a and δ o as 1 2m(1 + m)3 1 + 3m δo ≡ . m(1 + 2m)2 (1 + 4m)

δa ≡

Then, (E2) and (F4) are represented as k/N = δ a and k/N = δ o , respectively. Noting that both δ a and δ o are decreasing in m and that, δ o − δ a = {1 + 4m + 2m2 [2 + m(2 + 3m)]}/[2m(1 + m)3 (1 + 2m)2 (1 + 4m)] > 0 for all m > 0, we readily know that

mo > m a .

Let ma be the solution of k/N = 1/(2m4 ) (i.e., ma = [N/(2k)]1/4 ). From the fact that δ a −

33

1/(2m4 ) = [m3 − (1 + m)3 ]/[2m4 (1 + m)3 ] < 0 for all m > 0, we obtain.

ma < ma .

(G3)

Let mo be the solution of k/N = 1/(1 + 4m)3 (i.e., mo = (1/4)[(N/k)1/3 − 1]). Because δ o − 1/(1 + 4m)3 = {1 + 2m[5 + 2m(9 + 11m)]}/[m(1 + 2m)2 (1 + 4m)3 ] > 0 for all m > 0, we know that

mo > m o .

(G4)

Next form the ratio mo 21/4 = ma 4

"

N k

1/12

 −

k N

1/4 #

and note that mo = +∞. N →+∞ ma lim

(G5)

(G3) and (G4) imply that mo /ma > mo /ma . This and (G5) lead to mo lim = +∞ N →+∞ ma Now rearrange (G1) and (G2) as   a N m (2 + ma ) (ma )2 Wia = − k k 4(1 + ma )2 2   o o o N m (1 + m ) (mo )2 Wi = − , k k (1 + 2mo )2 2 and define the following functions of m.

a

ω (m) ≡

o

ω (m) ≡

N k



m(2 + m) m2 − 4(1 + m)2 2

N k



m(1 + m) m2 − . (1 + 2m)2 2





34

(G6)

For a given N/k, a change in the number of firms leads to changes in ω(m) as N/k + 2m − 6m2 − 6m3 − 2m4 ω (m) = 2(1 + m)3 N/k − m − 6m2 − 12m3 − 8m4 0 ω o (m) = . (1 + 2m)3 a0

Moreover, the second derivatives are given as 3N/k + 2 + 8m + 12m2 + 8m3 + 2m4 <0 2(1 + m)4 6N/k + 1 + 8m + 24m2 + 32m3 + 16m4 00 ω o (m) = − < 0. (1 + 2m)4 00

ω a (m) = −

(G7)

Evaluating the first derivative at equilibrium values of m, we obtain 0

ω a (ma ) = 0.

(G8)

Define Ωa as a



Ω ≡

N k



ma (2 + ma ) (ma )2 − . 4(1 + ma )2 2

Then, equations (G3), (G7) and (G8) imply that Wia − Ωa = ω a (ma ) − Ωa > 0. k

(G9)

We also obtain (mo )2 (1 + 6mo ) <0 1 + 5mo + 6(mo )2 1 + 11ma + 42(ma )2 + 52(ma )3 − 8(ma )4 0 ω o (ma ) = (1 + 2ma )3 0

ω o (mo ) = −

< 0 for a sufficiently large ma .

Define Ωo as 0

Ω ≡



N k



mo (1 + mo ) (mo )2 − . (1 + 2mo )2 2 35

(G10)

Note that limN →+∞ ma = +∞. Then, equations (G4), (G5), (G7) and (G10) yield Wio − Ωo = ω o (mo ) − Ωo < 0 k

(G11)

for a sufficiently large N . Equations (G9) and (G11) imply that Wio Wia − < Ωo − Ωa for a sufficiently large N. k k

(G12)

Substituting ma = [N/(2k)]1/4 and mo = (1/4)[(N/k)1/3 − 1] into Ωo − Ωa , we obtain  " #2 r     1/3  8(N/k) (N/k)1/3 − 1 (N/k)1/3 + 3 N 2N 1 o a − −1 +8 + Ω −Ω = 2 32  k k [(N/k)1/3 + 1]  ) 823/4 (N/k)5/4 23/4 (N/k)1/4 + 4 − . 2 [23/4 (N/k)1/4 + 2] A calculation show that lim (Ωo − Ωa ) = −∞.

N →+∞

Then (G12) implies that  lim

N →+∞

Wio Wia − k k

 = −∞

and hence lim (Wio − Wia ) = −∞.

N →+∞

Acknowledgments We thank Masahisa Fujita, Mutsumi Matsumoto, Keizo Mizuno, Hikaru Ogawa, Marcello Pagnini, Takatoshi Tabuchi, Dao-Zhi Zeng, and participants at NARSC, ARSC and the JSPS Kakenhi Kiban (A) seminar held at Kwansei Gakuin University for helpful discussions and comments. Special thanks go to Jacques-F. Thisse for stimulating conversations that set this project in motion when Miyagiwa was visiting the CORE. Sato acknowledges the financial support by the JSPS Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (S, A, B, and C) and the MEXT Grant-in-Aid for 36

Young Scientists (B).

References [1] Andersson, F. and R. Forslid, 2003, Tax competition and economic geography, Journal of Public Economic Theory 5, 279-303. [2] Baldwin, R., R. Forslid, P. Martin, G.I.P. Ottaviano and F. Robert-Nicoud, 2003, Economic Geography and Public Policy, Princeton University Press. [3] Baldwin, R.E. and P. Krugman, 2004, Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonization, European Economic Review 48, 1-23. [4] Borck, R. and M. Pfl¨ uger, 2006, Agglomeration and tax competition, European Economic Review 50, 647-668. [5] Brander, J. A., and P. Krugman, 1983, A ’reciprocal dumping’ model of international trade, Journal of International Economics 15, 313-321. [6] Brander, J. A., and B. J. Spencer, 1985, Export subsidies and international market share rivalry, Journal of International Economics 18, 83-100. [7] Bucovetsky, S., 1991, Asymmetric tax competition, Journal of Urban Economics 30, 167-181. [8] Devereux, M. P., R. Griffith and A. Klemm, 2002 Corporate income tax reforms and international tax competition, Economic Policy 35,451-495. [9] Dixit, A. K., and J.E. Stiglitz, 1977, Monopolistic competition and optimal product diversity, American Economic Review 67, 297-308. [10] Fujita, M., P. Krugman, and A.J. Venables, 1999, The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions, and International Trade, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. [11] Haufler, A and M. Pfl¨ uger, 2004, International commodity taxation under monopolistic competition, Journal of Public Economic Theory 6, 445-470. 37

[12] Haufler, A. and I. Wooton, 2010, Competition for firms in an oligopolistic industry: The impact of economic integration, Journal of International Economics 80, 239-248. [13] Head, K., T. Mayer, and J. Ries, 2002, On the pervasiveness of home market effects, Economica 69, 371-390. [14] Helpman, E., M. J. Melitz, and S. R. Yeaple, 2004, Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms, American Economic Review 94, 300-316. [15] Hines Jr., J.R., 2005, Corporate taxation and international competition, Ross School of Business Working Paper No. 1026, University of Michigan. [16] Janeba, E., 1995, Corporate income tax competition, double taxation treaties, and foreign direct investment, Journal of Public Economics 56, 311-325. [17] Kind, H.J., K.H.M. Knarvik, and G. Schjelderup, 2000, Competing for capital in a lumpy world, Journal of Public Economics 78, 253-274. [18] Krugman, P., 1980, Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade, American Economic Review 70, 950-959. [19] Ludema, R.D. and I. Wooton, 2000, Economic geography and the fiscal effects of integration, Journal of International Economics 52, 331-357. [20] Mankiw, G.N. and M.D. Whinston, 1986, Free Entry and Social Inefficiency, RAND Journal of Economics 17, 48-58. [21] Ottaviano, G. I. P. and T. van Ypersele, 2005, Market size and tax competition, Journal of International Economics 67, 25-46. [22] Perry, M.K., 1984, Scale economies, imperfect competition, and public policy, Journal of Industrial Economics 32, 313-333. [23] Pfl¨ uger, M. and J. Suedekum, 2013, Subsidizing firm entry in open economies, Journal of Public Economics 97, 258-271. 38

[24] Sato, Y. and J.-F. Thisse, 2007, Competing for capital when labor is heterogeneous, European Economic Review 51, 2054-2079. [25] Suzumura, K. and K. Kiyono, 1987, Entry barriers and economic welfare, Review of Economic Studies 54, 157-167. [26] von Weizsacker, C.C., 1980, A welfare analysis of barriers to entry, Bell Journal of Economics, 11, 399-420. [27] Wilson, J.D., 1986, A theory of inter-regional tax competition, Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 296-315. [28] Zodrow, R.G. and P. Mieszkowski, 1986, Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods, Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 356-370.

39

M o M ** 1.35 1.30 1.25 1.20 1.15 1.10 1.05 t 0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

(a)Trade cost and the degree of excess entry

Wio -Wia 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 t=0 0.1

t=0.001

t=0.025 0.0

n 20 t=0.05

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

-0.1

(b)Trade cost and the impact of trade on welfare-(I)

Wio -Wia n=30 t 0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

n=70 -1

-2 n=100 -3

-4

(c)Trade cost and the impact of trade on welfare-(II)

Wio - Wia n 0.06

0.04

0.02 t=0 0.00

n 20

40

60

80

100

120

140 160 t=0.001 t=0.025

-0.02

t=0.05

(d)Trade costs and the impact of trade on welfare per capita Figure 1. Eects of trade cost Notes: In all gures, we set k = 1 (i.e., ki = mi /2). In (a), we set n = 20.

mw  me Θ  H1 - ΘL 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5

0.55

0.60

0.65

0.70

0.75

Figure 2. The reverse home market eect

0.80

Θ

Τ 0.70

0.65

Dashed line: small country

0.60

0.55

0.50 0.50

Solid line: large country

0.55

0.60

0.65

0.70

0.75

0.80

Θ

Figure 3. Dierence in the tax rate between asymmetric countries

Wio -Wia

1.0 Dashed line: small country 0.5

Solid line: large country 0.55

0.60

0.65

0.70

0.75

0.80

Θ

-0.5

(a) Asymmetry and the impact of trade on welfare

Wio - Wia ni 0.20

0.15

0.10 Dashed line: small country 0.05 Solid line: large country 0.55

0.60

0.65

0.70

0.75

0.80

Θ

(b) Asymmetry and the impact of trade on welfare per capita

Figure 4. Dierence in the impact of trade on welfare between asymmetric countries

Free entry and regulatory competition in a global ...

Mar 26, 2014 - international tax competition literature through the discovery of the reverse home market effect. .... represent the consumer surplus, the next two measure the sum of firm profits and tax revenues, and the final term is the total .... forms allow us to consider the case of non-negligible transport cost. We first write ...

306KB Sizes 1 Downloads 168 Views

Recommend Documents

Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, ... our empirical analysis of competition in five retail and professional ..... When these practices had the same phone number, we treated them ... number

Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets
We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and .... A. Demand, Technology, Competition, and Entry .... Extending this logic to degrees of.

NRAI Competition Entry Form.pdf
Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. NRAI Competition Entry Form.pdf. NRAI Competition Entry Form.pdf. Open.

man-129\global-marketing-foreign-entry-local-marketing-and-global ...
... more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. man-129\global-marketing-foreign-entry-local-marketing-and-global-management-pdf.pdf.

Cournot Competition and Hit-and-Run Entry and Exit in ...
undergraduate classes on strategy and management as well as in master of busi- ness administration ... at different levels of formal detail. The experiment we ...

Christmas Card Competition entry form 2015.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Christmas Card Competition entry form 2015.pdf. Christmas Card Competition entry form 2015.pdf. Open. Extrac

Collusion and downstream entry in a vertically ...
Jan 26, 2012 - published by the European Commission (European Commission (2008)) point at a specificity of this ..... Ia, gets a utility of V minus the price paid to the firm. ...... able at: http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/2614.htm. 21.

Global Quality Competition, Offshoring and Wage ...
measured as the college/high school wage ratio, increased by approximately 20 .... before, an increase in the education premium increases the share of skilled .... measured as the ratio of wages of workers with a college or higher degree.

Competition and Custom in Economic Contracts: A ...
We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and ... Survey data suggest that cropsharing contracts exhibit a much higher degree of .... Figure 2, which shows the distribution of shares ...... Travels during the years 1787,.

Cues, constraints, and competition in sentence processing
sentence processing, significant controversies remain over the nature of the underlying ...... Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 16, 555-568. Fisher ...

Mate guarding, competition and variation in size in ...
depletion of energy stores during the mate-searching period, when males feed ..... Rubenstein (1987) proposed size-dependent alternative mating behaviour in ...

competition and regulation reforms in spain in 2013: the cnmc
institutional reform merged the competition authority with practically all sector regulators (except for the financial regulator). .... Exempting the competition agency from civil service salary limits in order to attract and retain the best ... A gr