Inflation Forecasts and Monetary Policy Author(s): Ben S. Bernanke and Michael Woodford Source: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 29, No. 4, Part 2: Dynamic Effects of Monetary Policy (Nov., 1997), pp. 653-684 Published by: Blackwell Publishing Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2953656 Accessed: 05/05/2010 16:07 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=black. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

Blackwell Publishing and Ohio State University Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.

http://www.jstor.org

BEN S. BERNANKE MICHAEL WOODFORD

InflationForecastsandMonetaryPolicy Proposals for "inflationtargeting"as a strategy for monetarypolicy leave open the importantquestion of how to determinewhethercurrentpolicies are consistent with the long-mn inflationtarget. An interestingpossibility is that the central bank might targetcurrentprivate-sectorforecastsof inflation,either those made explicitly by professional forecastersor those implicit in asset prices. We address the issue of existence and 1miquenessof rationalexpectations equilibriawhen the central bank uses private-sectorforecasts as a guide to policy actions. In a dynamic model which incorporatesboth sluggish price adjusttnentand shocks to aggregatedemandand aggregate supply, we show that strict targeting of inflation forecasts is typically inconsistent with the existence of rationalexpectationsequilibrium,and that policies approximating strictinflation-forecasttargetibgare likely to liave undesirableproperties.We also show that economies with more general forecast-basedpolicy rules are particularly susceptibleto indeterminacyof rationalexpectationsequilibria.We conclude that, although private-sectorforecasts may contain informationuseful to the central bank, ultimately the monetaryauthoritiesmust rely on an explicit structuralmodel of the economy to guide their policy decisions.

IN RECENT YEARSa number of major central banks have adopted, or at least actively considered, some form of "inflationtargeting'+as a frameworkfor monetarypolicy.1 In an inflation-targetingregime, the central bank (usually in conjunctionwith the government)establishesexplicit goals for the inflation rate at medium-termand long-term horizons. Although pursuitof an inflation targetdoes not precludeother objectives, such as short-runoutputor exchange-rate The authorsthank V. V. Chari, LarryChristiano,MarvinGoodfriend, Ed Nelson, Julio Rotemberg Lars Svensson, Alberto Trejos, and an anonymousreferee for helpful comments. Both authorsreceived financial supportfrom the NationalScience Foundation. 1. Central banks recently making highly publicized switches to an inflation-targetingapproachinclude New Zealand, Canada, the United Kingdom, Sweden, and Australia,many other countries have moved towardmakingprice stabilitythe primaryobjective of the centralbank, often in conjunctionwith institutionalreforms to increase central bank independence (Goodhartand Vinals 1994, Debelle and Fischer 1994; Leidermanand Svensson 1995; Haldane 1995- Bernankeand Mishkin, forthcoming). A few countries, notablyGermanyand Switzerland,have long used medium-terminflationobjectives as an importantcomponent of their monetary policy making (Bernanke and Mishkin 1992, Bernanke and Mihov, forthcoming).In the United States, the Fed has so far resisted the adoption of explicit inflation targets, althoughthe perceptionis that the relative importanceof price stability among the Fed's objectives has increased. Formallegislation introducedin the U.S. Senate by SenatorMack would amend the Humphrey-Hawkinsbill and requirethe Fed to pursuean inflationtarget.

BENS. BERNANKE and MICHAEL WOODFORD are bothprofessors of economics at Princeton Universityand research associates at the National Bureau of Economic Research. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 29, No. 4 (November 1997, Part2) Copyright 1997 by The Ohio State University Press

654

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

stabilization,it is understoodthattheseobjectivesare subsidiaryto achievingthe targetlevel of inflation. As a strategyfor conductingmonetarypolicy,inflationtargetinghasbothadvantages and disadvantages.One potentialadvantageis increased"transparency" of monetarypolicy,thatis, bettercommunication of policymakers' objectivesandintentionsto the publicandthe financialmarkets;see BernankeandMishkin(forthcoming).A seconddesirablefeatureis that,by settingtargetsfor its goal variable ratherthanfor an intermediate indicator(suchas moneygrowthor the exchange rate),the inflation-targeting centralbankmayavoidthe "velocityinstability" problem, whichariseswhenthereareunexpectedchangesin the relationship between the intermediate targetandtheultimateobjective. The maindisadvantages of the inflation-targeting approachfollow fromthe empiricalobservation thatinflationrespondsto changesin monetarypolicyonlywitha substantial lag, fromoneto twoyearsor more.Thelackof quickfeedbackfromthe economyto policyimpliestwo relatedproblems:First,the information the central bankrequiresin orderto implementinflationtargetingmay be muchgreaterthan thatneededto targetanintermediate variable,whoseresponseto policychangescan be observedwithless delay.Second,as it is difficultforthe inflation-targeting centralbankto tell whetherit is "ontrack,"it is equallydifficultforthepublicandthe financialmarketsto make thatjudgment,which has potentiallyadverseconsequencesforthecentralbank'saccountability andcredibility. Is theresomewayto overcometheproblemsassociatedwiththelonglag between changesin policyandchangesin the inflationrate?An interestingpossibilityis for the centralbankto targetcurrentforecasts of medium-term inflation,ratherthan inflationitself. Thecurrentforecastof inflation,unlikeactualfutureinflation,is (at leastin principle)a contemporaneously observablevariable;thus, in a regimethat targetsinflationforecasts, boththe centralbankandthe publicwouldbe able to monitorpolicycontinuously. Further,therationallyformedforecastof inflationincorporates,by definition,all information currentlyavailableaboutfutureinflation, so thattherecanneverbe anyconflictbetweenthe objectivesof targetingthe inflationforecastandtargetinginflationitself. Forbothof thesereasons,it hasbeenargued that the forecastof inflationis the "ideal"intermediatevariablefor an inflation-targeting regime(Svensson,forthcoming and1997). In practice,how couldthe centralbankgo abouttargetingthe forecastof inflation?At leastthreetypesof approaches havebeenproposed.First,thecentralbank couldtry to "target"the predictionsof private-sector forecasters,for example,by raisinginterestrateswhentheconsensusprivate-sector forecasthas inflationabove thecentralbank'sannounced targetandloweringrateswhentheinflationforecastis belowthetarget.HallandMankiw(1994)proposea strategyof thistype.2Second, the centralbankmightattemptto targetthe forecastof inflationimplicitin various assetprices;for example,as we discussin section4, therehavebeenproposalsto 2. Actually, Hall and Mankiw suggest that the centralbank target forecasts of nominal GDP growth ratherthaninflation;however, many of the criticismsmade here are independentof the particularvariable whose forecast is to be targeted.

BEN S. BERNANKEAND MICHAELWOODFORD : 655

adjustmonetarypolicy automaticallyin responseto movementsin commodity prices,to changesin long-termbondyieldsor in interest-rate spreads,to CPIfuture prices, and to changesin the spreadbetweennominaland indexedgovernment bonds,amongothers.Finally,the centralbankmighttryto targetits own internal forecastsof inflation(Svensson,forthcoming), in the senseof adjustingits instrumentto eliminateany discrepancybetweenits staff'sforecastof inflationandthe target.Examplesapproximating each of these proposalsmay be foundin central bankpractice:Forexample,in its quarterly InflationReport, the Bankof England reportsextensivelyon bothprivate-sector andits owninternalforecastsof inflation; and,thoughtheBankdoesnotfollowa mechanical rule,thereis a presumption that if a preponderance of forecastsareabovetheBank'sinflationtarget,a tighteningof policywill be recommended [seeBowen(1995)andKing(1994)fordiscussionsof the Bankof England'sstrategy].A similarapproachhas beenfollowedby the ReserveBankof New Zealand(MayesandRiches1996).Virtuallyall centralbanks pay close attentionto financial-market indicatorsof inflation,such as long-term bondyieldsandyieldspreads. Theobjectiveof thispaperis to studythebehaviorof theeconomywhenthecentralbankattemptsto "targettheforecast"of inflation,settingits instrument to eliminatedeviationsof some explicitor implicitinflationforecastfrom a prespecified target.Forconcreteness,formostof thepaperwe considerthecasein which(1) the inflationforecastbeingtargetedis theconsensusprivate-sector forecast,and(2) the privatesectorhas someinformation aboutthe economythatthe centralbankdoes nothave.3However,as we discussin thefinalsectionof thepaper,thoroughanalysis of thiscaseallowsus to drawconclusionsaboutothertypesof forecasttargeting, andaboutthe cases in whichthe centralbankhas equalor superiorinformation to theprivatesector. Unfortunately, we findthattargetingthe forecastof inflation,in the senseof allowingmonetarypolicyto respondstronglyto deviationsbetweentheinflationforecast andthe target,is not likelyto be a usefultacticfor monetarypolicy,for two broadsetsof reasons:First,somewhatparadoxically, to theextentthattargetingthe forecastis successful,the signal-to-noise ratioin the inflationforecastis likely to become(endogenously) small.In the limit, as perfectstabilization of the inflation forecastis approached, thereis no incentivefortheprivatesectorto gatherinformation, andthe inflationforecastbecomesuninformative. We showfurtherthatpolicies approximating stabilizationof the inflationforecast-arealso likely to have undesirable properties.Thesefindingsconfirmandextendthe analysisof Woodford (1994a);see alsoWest(1994). Second, we find that attemptsto targetthe inflationforecastlead, for broad classesof policies, to indeterminacy of the rationalexpectationsequilibrium.An implicationis thateven successfulattemptsto targetthe inflationforecastmaybe 3. Romer and Romer (1996) have presentedevidence that Fed forecasts are superiorto those of the privatesector. Even if this finding is correct, however, it does not lule out the possibility that the private sector has informationthat the Fed would like to infer (the reversemay also be true, of course). It is well known, for example, that the Fed attemptsto use private-sectorinformationimplicit in asset prices.

656

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

associatedwitharbitrary volatilityin inflationitself, as well as in outputandother goal variables.Thus, directtargetingof private-sector inflationforecastsis not a panaceafor the problemsraisedby the long lag betweenmonetarypolicy actions andtheresponseof inflation. Ona somewhatmorepositivenote,ouranalysisshowsthat,despitetheproblems withstrictforecasttargeting,a moresubtleapproachin whichforecastsaresimply usedas one of severalsourcesof information canbe helpful.In particular, the centralbankmaywell be ableto inferusefulinformation fromprivate-sector forecasts of macroeconomic variablesotherthaninyS!ation, suchas outputor interestrates.4 However,againcautionmustbe urged,as we show thatthe problemof indeterminacyof equilibrium canapplyto monetarypolicyrulesbasedon forecastsof outputandinterestrates,just as it can to policiesbasedon forecastsof inflation.The mostgeneralconclusionof ourpaperis thatcentralbanksshouldbe carefulnot to tie monetarypolicytoo closelyto anyvariablethatis too sensitiveto the expectationsof thepublic. Toavoidmisunderstanding, we shouldemphasizethatourresultshavelittleto say aboutthe desirability or feasibilityof inflationtargetingperse, as opposedto inflation-forecast targeting; indeed,thispolicystrategyhasmanyattractiveaspects.Our claim is only that, for successfulimplementation of inflationtargeting,thereappearsto be no substituteforexplicitstructural modelingof the economyandextensive informationgatheringby the centralbank. Private-sectorforecasts, and forecastsinferredfromfinancialmarkets,shouldbe partof theinformation gathered by the bank,buttheyshouldbe combinedwithotherinformation in the makingof policy. The rest of the paperproceedsas follows. Section 1 analyzesthe effects of inflation-forecast targetingin a simple, reduced-formmodel due to Woodford (1994a).WeconfirmWoodford's earlierresultthat,whenthe centralbankattempts to targetthe inflationforecastpreciselyat the target,no rationalexpectationsequilibriumexists.Moregenerally,we findthatattemptsby thecentralbankto keepthe inflationforecastclose to the target,whiletechnicallyfeasible,mayleadto excessive volatilityin actualinflationoutcomes. The modelof section1 is staticandthushas no role for private-sector expectationsaboutfuturepolicies.Toremedythis shortcoming,in section2 we analyzea dynamicmacroeconomicmodel which incorporatesprice stickinessand disturbancesto bothaggregatedemandandaggregatesupply.Wefindthattheresultsfrom thestaticmodelgeneralizeto thedynamiccase. Insection3 we showfurtherthat,in thedynamicmodel,forecast-based policyrulesin manycasesleadtypicallyto nonuniquenessof rationalexpectationsequilibrium; in particular, undersuchrulesthe economymaybe subjectto "sunspot" equilibriaandrelatedpathologies. As notedabove,ouranalysisfocusseson the case in whichthe centralbankattemptsto targetprivate-sector inflationforecasts,andin whichtheprivatesectorhas 4. More generally, our point is that the most useful informationvariable will not be the target variable. Thus inflationforecastsmight be useful to a centralbankthat seeks to stabilize nominalGDP rather than inflation.

BEN S. BERNANKEAND MICHAELWOODFORD : 657

someinformation abouttheeconomythatthecentralbankdoesnothave.Section4 discussestheapplication of ourresultsto alternative formsof forecasttargeting,and to alternative assumptions aboutinformation. Thebasicmessageof thispaper-that thereis no alternativeto structuralmodelingof the economyfor implementing forward-looking monetarypolicies- survivesthesegeneralizations. SectionS is a briefconclusion.

1. MACROECONOMICEQUILIBRIUMWHEN MONETARYPOLICYDEPENDS ON PRIVATE-SECTORFORECASTS:A SIMPLEMODEL

In this sectionwe extendthe exampleoriginallydue to Woodford(1994a),who used it to illustratethe potentialincompatibility of inflation-forecast targetingand the revelationof private-sector informationin rationalexpectationsequilibrium. Supposethatnextperiod'sinflationis givenby st+l

=

St +

Ut +

Et+l

(l)

wherest+ 1 iS realizedinflationin periodt + 1, St iS a statevariableindicatingunderlyinginflationpressures,utis the instrument of the centralbank(which,as the subscriptindicates,mustbe chosenone periodpriorto the realizationof the inflation rate),and Et+l iS an unforecastable disturbance thatalso affectsthe realized inflationrate.TherandomvariablesSt andEt+ l areassumedto be independent of the policyactionut;thedifferencebetweenthemis thatSt iS realizedpriorto thechoice of policyactionandEt+ 1 iS realizedsubsequent to thepolicyaction.Withoutloss of generalitywe mayalsoassumethatSt andEt+ l aremutuallyindependent. Wedenote thevariancesof s andE by cr2 andcr2, respectively,andwe normalizetheirmeansto zero. Finally, below we drop the time subscriptswhen there is no potential ambiguity. Fornow,assumethattheobjectiveof thecentralbankis to minimizeuncertainty aboutinflation,as measured by theconditional variance.(Implicitly,we assumethat thetargetedinflationlevel is zero;thisassumption is easilymodified.)If thecentral bankobservesthe underlyingstates, thenits taskis simple;it needonly set its instrumentu = -s. In thiscase, var(1r)= cr2, whichis evidentlythelowerboundthat canbe achieved. However,supposeinsteadthattheunderlyingstates is observedby privateforecastersbut not by the centralbank.The authoritymay thenseek to inferthe true statefromtheprivate-sector forecasts.If thecentralbanktakesthisapproach,will it be ableto achievethe sameminimalvarianceof inflationattainable whenit has directinformation of thestate?Clearlytheansweris no;if thecentralbankcouldinfer thestates fromtheprivate-sector forecasts,thenit wouldset u = -s, so thatir = e. Butthenthe rationalprivate-sector forecastsof inflationwouldhaveto be independentof s, so that(contrary to hypothesis)thecentralbankwouldnotbe ableto infer therealizationof s fromtheforecasts.

658

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

Moreformally,supposethattheloss functionof eachforecasteris givenby Lf =

Et{(rf-st+l)

(2)

}

whereTrfis theindividual's (publiclyannounced) forecastof inflation.Minimization of thisloss requiresthe announcement wf = Et{st+1|

St}

(3)

*

(Forthe momentwe assumethatforecastershavethe sameinformationandthus makethesameforecast.)Now supposethatthecentralbankobservesthe(common) forecastandchooses u = +rf.

(4)

Equations(1), (3), and(4) jointlyimplya uniquerationalexpectations equilibrium, so long as + 7&1, in which trf= ps,

with

(S)

1

+

(6)

1- +

Now as long as + 7&O,the valueof s canbe recoveredfromthe forecast[by using (5)]. So it mightseemthatthe centralbankcan achievethe minimumvariancefor inflationby usinga ruleof the form(4) forwhich (>

_ 1

(7)

However,it can be readilyseen thatthereexists no joint solutionfor (6) and(7): From(7), minimization of thevarianceof inflationrequires++ =-1, whichin turn implies,from(6), thatforecasters will rationallychoose+ = O.Butthen(7) hasno solution. Somemightarguethatthisexampleis of littlepracticalimport,sincethereexist well-behavedrationalexpectationsequilibriain whichthe centralbankachievesa level of inflationvariabilityarbitrarilyclose to the theoreticalminimum.Note that equations(1), (3), and(4) implya uniquesolutionforanyfinitechoiceof thepolicy reactioncoefficient+, so longas + 7&1. Intheassociatedequilibria,thevarianceof inflationis givenby (

)

(+

_

1)2

E

(8)

BEN S. BERNANKEAND MICHAELWOODFORD : 659

Thusit is possibleto makethevarianceof inflationarbitrarily close to its minimum valuecr£2 by choosinga sufficientlylargepositiveor negativevalueof + (although the lowerboundis attainedonly in the limitas + is madeunboundedly large,with eithersign). But the equilibriaof this simplemodelassociatedwith very large(in absolute value)+ areunappealing as a basisfor a policyrecommendation, eventhoughthey aretechnicallywell behaved.Oneproblemis thatthe modelassumesthatforecasterswill maketheeffortto observethetruestates precisely,eventhoughin equilibrium the forecaster'sloss will barelydependon whethershe knowss or not. To be specific,supposethatobservationof the realizedvalueof s costs the forecasteran amountc > 0, wherethiscostis measuredin thesameunitsas theloss in (2). Since eachforecastercan achievea loss of E{1r2}simplyby choosingtrf = O, thatis, by forecastinginflationto be at its unconditional mean,it will be worthwhilefor the forecasterto gatherinformation abouttherealizationof s if andonly if E{(rrf(s)--

X)2} + C < E{Tr2}

(9)

wherevrf(s)is theoptimalforecastconditional on knowledgeof thestates. Equation (9) represents anadditional constraint on theproblemof thecentralbank.Using(1), (3), and(4), one canshowthat(9) requiresvarfTr)2 CT£2+ C, or equivalently 2 (+_

1)2 C

s *

(10)

Equation(10) showsthatthereis a limitto howlarge+ canbe set, andthereforeto the degreeto whichthe variabilityof inflationcanbe reduced,withouteliminating the incentiveof the forecastersto gatherinformation. On the otherhand,it should be noted,as longas c < crS2, theconstraint (10) doespermitvaluesof + thatimplya varianceof inflationlowerthanthe centralbankcouldachievewithoutusingthe information in theprivate-sector forecasts(thatis, lowerthan(rS2 + (r2e).5 So thereis a sensein whichthecentralbankcanuse outsideforecaststo improveits policy,as we notedin the introduction. Butthisis not, strictlyspeaking,an inflation-forecast targetingpolicy,sincein equilibrium forecastsdiiTerent fromtheinflationtargetcan occurwithoutimplyingthatthe centralbank'spolicyis too "tight"or too "loose." Anotherpracticalconcernaboutrecommending a "large-+"policyto the central bank(thatis, one in whichthecentralbank'sactionsarehighlysensitiveto privatesectorforecasts)is that-even if thereis sufficientincentiveforforecasters to gather information-someforecastersmaybe "incompetent" at usingtheirinformation to produceoptimalforecasts.Toillustrate,supposethereis a randomcomponentin the averageforecastmadeby theprivatesector,conditionalon theunderlyingstate.For example,we mightreplace(3) with 1rf=

E{sls}

+ v

(11)

5. In this case, one can show that there are two constrained-optimalsolutions to the central bank's problem, correspondingto the two values of + one negative and one greater than 2 that satisfy (10) with equality.Under either of these policies, var(Tr)= (J2 + C < (J2 + (J2.

660

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

wherev is a randomvariablethatwe assume(forsimplicity)to be independent of s andE andto havemeanzeroandvarianceC2. Therearevariousinterpretations that maybe givento the noise termv in (11): As alreadysuggested,one possibilityis "incompetence"-thatis, systematicerrorsin thecomputation orcommunication of the forecast- or, perhaps,"herdbehavior," eventhoughovermanytrialsthe forecastersmakethecorrectinferenceon average.An alternative possibilityis strategic randomization by the forecasters,whichmayoccurif in fact theirloss functionis notgivenby (2). Forexample,Laster,Bennett,andGeoum(1996)showthatif forecastersobtainbenefitnot only fromthe accuracyof theirforecastsin an absolute sense,butalsofrombeingobservedto havemadetherelativelymostaccurateforecast, thenin equilibriumthey will distributetheirforecastsratherthanannounce theirconditionalexpectations,evenif all forecasters haveidenticalinformation.6 If we supposethattherearethreeor moreforecasters andtheforecastsareannounced simultaneously, thenthisgamecanhavea mixed-strategy equilibrium in whichthe averageforecastis random,evenconditionalon thetruestate5.7 In suchanequilibrium(11) will hold, whereXf refersnow to the averageprivate-sector forecast. If thecentralbankfollowsa ruleof theform(4), andtheaverageforecastis given by (11) ratherthan(3), thenequation(5) is replacedby Sf = +5 + V, where+ is determinedby (6). The analogueto equation(8), whichdescribesthe varianceof inflationattainable by the centralbank,is Val*(7r)

=

(+

1)2

+

+

¢V

+

¢E

'

(12)

Equation(12) showsthatthe varianceof inflationis now boundedaboveits minimumvalueunderperfectinformation (equalto C2), regardlessof the valueof the centralbank'sreactioncoefficient+. Furthermore, the varianceof inflationis no longerminimizedby choosing+ as largeas possible(eitherpositiveor negative); indeed,"targeting the forecast"by choosing+ largemayleadto a veryhighvarianceof inflationbecauseof thepresenceof thesecondtermon therightsideof (12). Analysisof (12) showsthatthe globalminimumfor the varianceof inflationis attainedfor a finitevalue+* < O, thoughthereis also a local minimumat a value +** > 1.8

Likethe problemof inducingforecastersto bearthe costsof gatheringinformation, the problemof eitherpotential"incompetence" or strategicbehaviordoes not imply thatthe centralbankcannotbenefitfromusing private-sector forecaswts in 6. For a related analysis of strategy regarding incentives for scattering of forecasts, see Lamont (1996). 7. Note that the strategicdispersionof forecastsrequiresthat the forecastersbe uncertainabout what the realized value of inflationwill be, which in this model is guaranteedby the presence of the shock e. 8. The proof proceeds as follows: Differentiationof (12) indicatesthat two local minimaexist, correspondingto the roots of the equationk = (+ - 1)-3, where k 8 2/ff2. The two roots are as described in the text. Furthermore,defining g 8 1/+, this equationmay equivalentlybe writtenk(l - ()3 = (4. Letting (* = 1/+*, (** - 1/+**, one observes that O < 1 - (** < 1 < 1 - (*, implying that |g* | > | (** | and hence | +* | < | +** 1. Finally, since at either of the local minima | + - 1 |-3 = k|+ |, one must have |+* - 1 > |+** - 1|. Thus each of the first two terms on the right side of (12) takes a smaller value at + = c)* than at + = +**, so that +* is the global minimum.

BEN S. BERNANKE AND MICHAELWOODFORD : 661

makingits policy:Afterall, the varianceof inflationis still lowerfor + = +* than for+ = O.However,againit is alsotruethatit is dangerous to literallytryto "target the forecast";althoughmonetarypolicyshouldreactto deviationsof privateforecastsfromthe inflationtarget,a policyof completelyeliminatingdeviationsof privateforecastsfromtheofficialinflationtargetis generallynotoptimal,andcanlead to an extremelyhighvarianceof inflation. "Targeting the forecast"is a misleadingdescriptionof the properuse of privatesectorforecastsin anothersenseas well:Thestrategyof targetingtheforecastseems to implythatthe private-sector forecastof thegoalvariable(forexample,inflation) is a sufficientstatisticfor the information thatthe centralbankcan usefullyobtain fromoutsideforecasters.In fact, in general,the centralbankmayfindit usefulto observeprivate-sector forecastsof variablesotherthanthegoalvariable,evenin the extremecase whenits objectivefunctiondependsonly on the stabilizationof the single goal variable.To illustratethis pointin the contextof our simpleredu.cedformmodel, supposethat,priorto the centralbank'schoiceof policy,it observes private-sector forecastsof bothinflationandalso the centralbank'spolicyvariable u. (Thinkof u as the short-term interestrate,for example;the choiceof u as the particular additionalvariableto be forecastis inessential,as we showlater.)With this assumption,we can now considerthe consequencesof monetarypolicyrule$ thatdependon the averageprivate-sector forecastuf of the centralbank'spolicy action,as well as on the forecastwrrf of subsequent inflation. Wewill wantto assumethattheprivate-sector forecasters careabouttheaccuracy of boththeirinflationforecastsandtheirforecastsof centralbankactions;forexample, theirclientsmay be interestedin the likely pathof short-terminterestrates. Generalizing (2), let us supposethatforecasters minimizea loss functionof theform Lf = E{(rrf-Orr)2}

+ alE{(uf-u)2}

(13)

wherea > Ois therelativeweightforecasters puton accuratepredictionof thecentralbank'spolicy variable.Becausethe loss functionis quadratic,the forecasters optimallychoose to announcethe conditionalexpectationsof Trand u as their forecasts: rrf= E{s js},

uf = E{UIs}*

(14)

Now supposethatthemonetarypolicyruleis of the form a

= +wsf ,+ U"S *

( 15)

Thecombination of (1), (14), and(15) impliesa uniquerationalexpectationsequilibrium,as long as + + u 7&1, in which orrf= +5,

+

- 1-

+

-

+

662

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

uf = 05, Tr = s+

0

-1 - +w- u

E

u = Os.

(16)

It may be observedthat,if in additionwe imposeu 7&1, the equilibriumdescribedby (16) is equivalentto the one resultingfromthe simplerpolicyrule (4), with+ = +w/(1 - a). Thusat firstglanceit mightappearthatimposingu = Oin (15) is innocuous,andthatthe inflationforecastof the privatesectoris all thatthe centralbankneedsto know.However,this conclusionis incorrect.Indeed,as we shownext, allowingfor u 7&0 canmitigatethe problemsassociatedwithrulesof theform(4) withverylargevaluesof +. First,we observedabovethatno ruleof theform(4) cancompletelyeliminatethe effectsof the statevariables on inflation,andtherebyreducethe varianceof inflationto its full-information lowerbound.Moreprecisely,we showedthatthereis no equilibrium in which(1) inflationis independent of thestatevariablein equilibrium and(2) the centralbankis ableto inferthe valueof the statevariablefromprivatesectorforecasts.However,this problemdisappearswhenthe centralbankuses a rule of the form(15), thatis, it respondsto forecastsbothof inflationandof an additionalvariable(in thisexample,the centralbank'spolicyvariable).In particular,if thecentralbanksetsu = 1, + 7&O,thenin equilibrium + = Oando = - 1, with the consequencesthatTris independent of s andvar(Tr)= cr£2, its theoretical minimum.It is interestingto note that,whenthe centralbankuses this rule, the private-sector inflationforecastneverdeviatesfromthe targetrateof inflationin equilibrium. (If it did, thecentralbankwouldchoosea valueof u differentfromits forecastedvalue, butin a rationalexpectationsequilibrium sucha deviationcould not predictablyoccur.)But the centralbankdoes not achievethis resultby the heavy-handed meansof movingthepolicyinstrument violentlyin responseto deviations of the forecastfromthe target;instead,it inducesthe privateforecastersto revealtheirinformation throughtheirforecastof the policyinstrument. Second,a ruleof the form(15) caneliminate,or at leastameliorate,the forceof the incentiveconstraintthatariseswhenforecastershavea cost of collectinginformation.In particular, if the forecasters' loss functionis givenby (13), plusthe cost c > Owhichis incurredif thetruestateis observed,thentheincentiveconstraint(9) becomes E{(sf(s)-s)2

+

al(uf(s)-u)2}+ c ' E{Tr2 + au2}.

(17)

Thatis, the improvement in forecastaccuracyfromobservingthe truestatemust exceedthe cost of gatheringthe information. Note that,if c < acrS2, thenthe constraint(17) is satisfiedin theequilibrium resultingfromthe (unconstrained) optimal policyrule,u = 1, + 7&O.Thusif information-gathering costs, thoughpositive,

BEN S. BERNANKE AND MICHAELWOODFORD : 663

arenot too large,it maystill be possibleto reducethe varianceof inflationaround its targetto thetheoreticalminimum. Finally,a ruleof the form(15) thateliminates(ornearlyso) the influenceof the statevariables on inflation(withu closeto 1) will in generalbe muchmorerobust to randomnoise in private-sector forecasts even thoughpolicynow respondsto two distinctforecasts,eachof whichmaybe noisy.Toillustrate,supposethat( 14)is replacedby Trf =E{s|S}+V,

Uf =

E{u|s}+ (1)

(18)

wherev andX aremean-zerorandomvariables,independent of s, , andeachother, andwithvariancesC2 andC2, respectively.If the policyruleis againof the form (15),in equilibrium theprivateforecastswillbe givenby Trf= s + v, uf = 05 + @, where+ ando areas definedin (16). Theresultinginflationrateis s

= +5 + +oV

+ uX

+ E

(19)

andthe varianceof inflationis ( 1

+

_

+

)

C s + + U2

+ + 2C 2 + a 2

(20)

In the benchmark case u = 1, + 7&0, whicheliminatesthe effectsof the state variableon inflation(butwhichis notnecessarilythe optimumin thisclassof policies), (20) implies var(s) =

d)cr2 + a2 + a2

(21)

Forecastnoisedoescauseadditional inflationvolatility,butoverallthispolicydominatespoliciesthatdo notconditionon theforecastof thepolicyinstrument (thatis, for whichu = 0) as long as the idiosyncratic noise in the forecastof the policy instrumentis not too large(specifically,we need crX,< crS2/(+* - 1)2 + +*2crV, where+* < 0 is theoptimalpolicyreactioncoefficientdescribedabove).Moregenerally,one can writethe first-order conditionsdefiningthe optimalreactioncoefficients+ andu for the case of noisyforecasts,verifyingthatu = 0 cannotbe a solution;hence,in generalit canneverbe optimalto ignorethe information in the forecastof thepolicyinstrument. The desirablepropertiesof the rule(15) withu = 1, + 7&0 showthatuse of private-sector forecasts,includingforecastsof inflation,can improvethe performance of monetarypolicy. We reiterate,however,that the ideal rules are not usefullydescribedas "targetingthe inflationforecast":First,the best policy rule doesnotusuallyinvolveresponding to forecastsonlyof inflation(eventhoughstabilizing inflationmaybe the centralbank'sonly objective);andsecond,the optimal policyrulewill typicallynotinvolvea highdegreeof sensitivityof thepolicyinstrumentto deviationsof private-sector inflationforecastsfromthe inflationtarget.

664

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

2. MONETARYPOLICYAND PRIVATE-SECTOR FORECASTSIN A DYNAMIC MODEL

The modelof section1 is staticandratherstylized.Wenow presenta moredetailedandexplicitlydynamicmodelwhichallowsforbothmonetaryandnonmonetarysollrcesof inflation.In thismorerealisticmodelthe inflationratedependsnot solelyupona monetarypolicyactiontakenata singlepointin timebutalsouponthe rule (orreactionfunction)thatis expectedto dictatemonetary policyin the future. Thismodification introduces important complications, in particular, thepossibleindeterminacy of rationalexpectations equilibrium undercertaintypesof rules.As we showin section3, thispotentialindeterminacy is a furtherproblemwithsimpleproposalsto "targetthe forecast." In section1 we werenot specificaboutthe centralbank'spolicyinstrument.In line withthe actualpracticeof mostof the world'scentralbanks,we now assume thatthe policyinstrument is the short-term nominalinterestrate,Rt, andask how private-sector forecastsmightbe usedin settingthisparticular instrument. Apartfromthe monetarypolicyruleitself, to be discussedbelow,ourdynamic modelconsistsof two structural equations,an"expectational IS equation" (Kerrand King 1996;Woodford1996;McCallumandNelson 1997)andan aggregatesupply or price determination equation.The expectationalIS equation,which relates spendingdecisionsto the interestrate,is givenby Yt-EtYt+l-cr[Rt-Etst+l-Pt]

(22)

whereYtis the log of realoutputin periodt, Trt+ 1 is the rateof inflationbetween periodst andt + 1, andPtis an exogenousdisturbance. Equation(22) is derivable as a log-linearapproximation foroptimalconsumption on thepartof therepresentative household,intowhichhasbeensubstituted the equilibrium conditionthatconsumptiondemandequalstheeconomy'soutput(thereis no investment,government spending,or netforeigndemandin themodel).In thisinterpretation, theparameter C > Ois the intertemporal elasticityof substitution of coonsumption, andthe exogenousdisturbance term{Pt}representsrandom(percentage) variationsin the intertemporalmarginalrateof substitution, arising,for example,fromvariationsin the rateof timepreferenceandevaluatedat a planinvolvingconstantconsumption over time.9 Theaggregatesupplyrelationship is assumedto be st-Et-

1st+1 + KEt-1(Yt-Ot)

(23)

whereOtis an exogenousstochasticprocessinterpretable as the log of the "natural rate"level of outputin periodt. Equation(23) can be obtainedas a log-linearapproximation to a first-order conditionforoptimalpricesettingin a discrete-time ver9. Otherinterpretationsof the randomdisturbanceterm p, are possible. For example, in a model with governmentspending, exogenous shifts in the share of resources consumed by the governmentwould give rise (by changing the relationshipbetween private consumptionand total output)to a disturbance term of the same form, in the log-linear approximation.

BEN S. BERNANKEAND MICHAELWOODFORD : 665

sion of the modelof staggeredpricechangesintroducedby Calvo(1983). Alternatively,(23)canbe derivedfroma modelwitha convexcostof changingprices,as in Cochrane(1995).The parameter ,B,O< ,B< 1, maybe interpreted as the discountfactorof the price-setterswhile K > O iS a measureof the speedof price adjustment. The modelunderlyingequation(23) is one in whichonly somesuppliersareallowedto choosea newpricefortheiroutputin anygivenperiod,these"lucky"suppliersbeing randomlyselectedin an independent drawingeach period.It is also assumedthatanypricechangechosenat datet takeseffectonlyoneperiodlater,in t + 1;hence,(23) differsfromtheformof theaggregatesupplyfunctionobtainedin severalrecentpapers(for example,Roberts1995;Yun 1996;King and Watson 1996;Woodford1996)whichassumethatpricechangestakeeffectwithinthe same period.In particular, whereasthe citedpapersobtaina first-order conditionof the formst = EtXt+l, we hereobtaininsteada relationship of theformxrt= Et_lXt+1* Thus,in ourspecification,theperiod-tinflationratedependsonlyon period-(t- 1) information, becauseall pricesin effectin periodt werechosenin t - 1 or earlier. Wechoosethisspecification to capturethenotionthatinflationis "inertial," in particular,thatit is affectedby monetarypolicyactionsonly witha lag.10 Forconcreteness,assumethe shocksto theIS equationandthe aggregatesupply equationarefirst-order autoregressive: Pt= Ap,_l + vt ot= 80t-l + Nt

(24)

whereAand8 haveabsolutevaluesless thanoneandtheinnovationsseries{Vt}, {Nt} areseriallyuncorrelated, mean-zerodisturbances, also mutuallyuncorrelated at all leadsandlags. Equations(22)-(24), togetherwiththemonetarypolicyrule,constitute a completemodelof the inflationprocess.In this model,bothaggregatedemandandaggregatesupplyshocks,if not offsetby monetarypolicy,may lead to changesin the inflationrate. Weturnnowto theanalysisof monetarypolicyin thismodel.Letus supposethat thecentralbank'sobjectiveis notonlyto stabilizetheinflationratebutalsoto minimize deviationsof outputYtfromthe naturalratelevel of output,Ot.Stabilizing outputis not only consistentwith the pursuitof stableinflationin this modelbut actuallyimpliesit, sincein anystationary equilibrium (23) implies 00

st=

K E

SEt_l(Yt+j- ot+j)*

(25)

j=o

10. For furtherdiscussion of aggregatesupply specificationswith time lags in price setting of the kind assumed here, see Rotembergand Woodford(forthcoming).

666

: MONEY, CRED1T,AND BANKING

In any case, as a practicalmatter,not even the most hawkishinflationtargeters among-centralbankshavenot demonstrated thatthey arewillingto ignoreoutput fluctuations entirely. It is easilyseenhowinterestratesmustvaryif theobjectivesof inflationstabilizationandoutputatthenaturalrateareto be fullyachieved.If we assumewithoutloss of generalitythatthe inflationtargetis zero, substitution of Trt= OandYt= Ot(for all t) into(22) yields Rt = Pt +

ff

(EtOt+l-Ot) = Pt-

ff

(26)

wherewe haveused (24) to substitutefor EtOt+l.Equation(26) showsthat,if the centralbankdirectlyobservesthecurrentrealizations of thetwo shocks,PtandOt,it will be ableto set the nominalinterestrateRtto stabilizebothinflationandoutput perfectly. Whatif the centralbankdoes not directlyobservethe two shocks,butonly the historyof outputandinflation?To be precise(andto makethe mostgenerousassumptionaboutthe timingof information receipt),supposethatat the time thatit mustchooseRtthe centralbankcanobserveYt-jand Trtjfor allj 2 0.ll Is it possiblein thiscase for the centralbankto implementthe first-bestoutcome?The answeris plainlyno: Equation(26) requiresthatRtrespondto the innovationsvt and at, or morespecifically- to thelinearcombination vt - (1 - b)t/cr. It is thereforenecessarythatthe centralbankbe ableto inferthisquantity.ButYtis the only variablein the centralbank'sinformation set thatis not determined at datet - 1 or earlier;andsinceYt= Otin the first-bestcase, observingoutputin periodt would permitthecentralbank(underthehypothetical first-bestpolicy)to inferonly,, the innovationto Ot.Thusif the centralbankobservesonly currentandpastvaluesof outputandinflation,it caMotimplementthe first-best. 12 Whatif, besidesobservingthe historiesof outputandinflation,the centralbank can also observea private-sector inflationforecast?To give privateforecastersan informationadvantageover the centralbank,let us assumethat(perhapsat some cost),theforecasters canmakedirectobservations in periodt of theshocksPtandOt, as wellas thehistoriesof outputandinflation (equivalently, thehistoriesof theshocks), uponwhichtheybasetheirforecastof inflationbetweenperiodst andt + 1. Let rrf denotetheforecastof Trt+ 1 announced by theprivateforecasters in periodt. Wecontinueto assumethatforecastersseekto minimizethe varianceof theirforecasterrorandhenceannouncerrf = E{Trt+ 1 |It}, wheretheinformation setIt consists 11. Strictlyspeaking, we have in mind thatthe centralbankcan conditionthe nominalinterestrate on the currentvalue of output, so that the interestrate and output are simultaneouslydetermined.It is not necessary to think of y, as being determinedstrictlybefore R, is chosen. 12. Nor is it possible, we may add, to approximatethis outcome arbitrarilyclosely. An informalargument is as follows: In any equilibrium, under the informationassumptionsof the last paragraph,the centralbank can infer only the linear combinationof v, and 1l, that is revealed by the observationof y For any equilibriumthat is near-optimal,innovationsin y, will be almost perfectly correlatedwith 1l, and so not a close approximationto the variablethatthe centralbankneeds to know. Thus the assumptionthat prices are determinedat least one period in advance implies that observing the history of output and inflation alone does not provide the centralbank enough informationto achieve complete stabilization.

BEN S. BERNANKEAND MICHAELWOODFORD : 667

of {Pt<, ot-J} Vj 2 O. Now, supposingthatthe centralbankobservesthe privatesectorforecasts,let us considerwhatcanbe achievedby a monetarypolicyruleof the form Rt-+w7rf + PyYt

(27)

Werestrictattention,fornow,to rationalexpectations equilibriaof the form Yt

= alPt + a20t

7rt+1 = blpt + b20t

(28)

Notethatthefirst-bestoutcome,Yt= Ot,Trt+ 1 = O,canbe expressedin theformof (28), so thatequilibriayieldingfull stabilization canbe considered. Usingequations(22) and(23), it is straightforward to showthat,given a policy ruleof the form(27), (28) can describea rationalexpectationsequilibrium if and only if thecoefficients{ai, b} satisfy bl = Abl

+ KAal

b2 = ,B8b2+ Kba2

(29)

Kb

(1 + crly)al + cr(+-l)bl

= Aal + cr

(1 + cry)a2 + cr(+ - l)b2 = ba2

(30)

Since,BA< 1 and,Bb< 1, it is possibleto solveconditions(29) for(al, a2)given (bl, b2), or vice versa.Thusequilibriaof the class characterized by (28) may be indexedby the coeiSficients (al, a2) describingthe behaviorof output,or alternativelyby the coeiSficients (bl, b2)describingthebehaviorof inflation.Letus considernowwhether,usinginformation fromprivate-sector forecasts,thecentralbank will be ableto achievestabilization of inflation.Forthispurpose,it is convenientto indexequilibriaby (bl, b2);the goalof inflationstabilization thenrequiresbl = b2 = O.Notethatthisalsoimpliesthatal - O,a2 = 1, so thatinflationstabilization is associatedwithoutputalwaysequalto the naturalrate.[Thisis becauseof ourrestrictionof attentionto the specialclassof candidateequilibriaof form(28).] Usingequations(29) to eliminateal anda2 fromequations(30), we obtain [(1-A+cr4>) [

1

A + cr(+lr-l)]bl

<, ) 1 - 8 + (+

= 1

- l)]b2 = -(1 - 8 + +y)@

(31)

Since therearetwo free policyparameters to be chosenin orderto determinethe valuesof bl andb2,it is clearthat"almost"anypatternof inflationresponsesto the

668

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

underlyingshocksis consistentwithsomepolicyof the form(27). In this respect, we haveverifiedthe usefulnessof allowingpolicyto makeuse of the information containedin theinflationforecast:Ingeneral,qrfwill notdependuponPtandOtwith the samerelativeweightsas doesYt,andso the centralbankwill be ableto extract information fromthe inflationforecastthatcanbe usedto reducethe centralbank's expectedloss. Nevertheless,it is thecasethat as in thesimplemodelof theprevioussectioncompletestabilization of inflationis not possibleby meansof policiesof the form (27). In particular, inspectionof equations(31) revealsthattheseequationscannot be solvedfor (+1r,y) whenwe imposebl = b2 = 0. As before,the problemis essentiallythatperfectstabilizationof inflationis inconsistentwith private-sector inflationforecastsbeing informativeaboutthe underlyingshocks.Specifically,in any equilibrium withbl = 0, inflationforecastscease to revealinformationabout the valueof Pt.(Thereis no problemin choosinga policythatinducesb2 = 0; this simplyrequiresy = - ( 1 - b)/(r,x + 1 ) As in section1, althoughperfectstabilization is impossible,thereexist rational expectationsequilibriain this modelin whichthe centralbankcomes arbitrarily close to full stabilization of bothinflationandoutput,thatis, equations(31) canbe solvedfor policyparameters thatachieveb2 = 0 andan arbitrarily smallvaluefor bl. This near-optimal policy involvesXy = -(1 - b)/(rand+ largein absolute value. Sucha policynot only makesuse of the private-sector inflationforecastbut comesarbitrarily close to a policyof "targeting theforecast." However,as in the exampleexploredin section 1, this policy has undesirable featuresthatwe believeshouldruleoutits application in practice.First,if policyis highlysensitiveto the forecast,the resultinglow variabilityof expectedinflation couldeliminatetheincentiveforforecasters to gatherinformation abouttheunderlying statevariables,as we saw earlier.Second,if forecastersare subjectto "tremblinghands,"so that due, for example,to systematicerrorsor strategicbehavior thereis additivenoise in the averageforecast,thenextremesensitivityof policy to the forecastwill induceexcessivevolatilityin bothinflationandoutput. However,theseconclusionsdo not ruleout the productiveuse of private-sector forecastsin policymaking.Onecanagainshowthat,if forecasters makepredictions of variablesotherthaninflation,thecentralbankmaybe ableto use theinformation impliedby theseadditionalforecasts even if the additionalvariablesbeingforecasteddo notenterthecentralbank'sloss function.Forexample,supposethatthere areavailableprivate-sector forecastsof the short-term nominalinterestrate,as well as of inflation.To be precise,supposethatin periodt the followingsequenceof eventsoccurs:First,the shocksPtandOtarerealizedandrevealedto theforecasters (as well as to the privateagentswhose decisionproblemsare affectedby these shocks).Next, the forecastersannouncetheirforecastsof qTt+ l andRt, denotedqrf andRf, respectively.Finally,the centralbankandprivatedecision-makers jointly act, determining qTt+ 1,Yt,andRt. Specifically,we assumethatthepolicymakers are ableto conditionthevalueof theirinstrument RtonYt(butnotqTt+ l ) andthatprivate decisionmakers observeRtwhenchoosingYtandqrt+1

BEN S. BERNANKEAND MICHAELWOODFORD : 669

Thecentralbank'spolicyruleis of the form Rt = +1rsf+ RRf + yYt

(32)

andwe againconsiderrationalexpectations equilibriaof the form(28). It is easily verifiedthatif R + 1, andtheparameters of thepolicymle aresuchthatanequilibriumof the form(28) exists,thenthe equilibrium is identicalto one arisingfroma policyruleof theform(27), withcoefficients(+1r,y) givenby +1r= +1r/(l-R)S y = y/(l-R). However,if R = 1, moreinterestingpossibilitiesarise:In particular,completeinflationandoutputstabilization (anequilibrium withbl = b2= °) is possibleif R = 1, y = O, and+ # O. Furthermore, this way of stabilizing inflationis superiorto the use of a ruleof the form(27), with | +1r| large,in that completestabilization maynot eliminatethe incentivefor forecastersto gatherinformationaboutthe statePt,andtheeffectsof forecastnoiseon outputandinflation will be bounded.Thusthe pointsdevelopedin the contextof the simplemodelof section1 carryoverto thismorecompletemodel. Weconcludethatthe monetaryauthorities shoulduse private-sector forecastsin theirdecisionmaking,if the privateforecastersarelikelyto haveinformation that the centralbankersdo not have. However,a regimeof stricttargetingof privatesector inflationforecastsis unlikelyto be desirable.Instead,the policymakers shoulddrawinformation froma varietyof privateforecasts. 3. DETERMINACYOF EQUILIBRIUMUNDER FORECASTTARGETING

We saw in sections1 and2 that,althoughprivate-sector forecastsmay provide usefulinformation to policymakers,targetingthe inflationforecastdirectlyis not likelyto be an effectivedevicefor stabilizingtheinflationrate;the problemis that, if inflationequalsthetargetin equilibrium, thentheinformation of theprivateforecastersis not revealed.In this sectionwe show that,in the contextof a dynamic modellikethatof section2, thereis anadditional potentialproblemwithnaiveforecasttargeting.Thisproblemis thatsucha policyruleneednotimplya determinate rationalexpectations equilibrium andso maypermitfluctuations arisingpurelyfrom self-fulfillingexpectations. Notonlymaytheresponseof theeconomyto exogenolls structural disturbances be indeterminate, but theremay also exist "sunspotequilibria,"in whichtheendogenousvariablesrespondto randomvariablesunrelated to the structure of themodelsimplybecausetheyareexpectedto. Indeterminacy of equilibrium is, of course,a generalproblemfor policyrulesin settingsin whichthe currentequilibrium dependson expectationsaboutthe indefinite future.l3However,rulesthatlink policyactionsto forecasts,therebymaking thecurrentequilibrium especiallysensitiveto expectations aboutthefuture,areparticularlyvulnerablein this regard,as we shall see. Thus, in analyzingforecastbasedpolicyrules,it is insufficientto demonstrate (as in section2) thatthe ruleis 13. For general discussion of the issue of determinacyof equilibriumas a criterion for choosing among policy rules, see Guesnerieand Woodford(1992, section 8) and Woodford(1994b).

670

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

consistent witha particular desirableequilibrium; we mustalso checkwhetherthe desirableequilibrium is the unique outcomeassociatedwiththatrule. Weshowin this sectionthat forecast-based policy rules often do not imply uniquerationalexpectations equilibria,whichprovidesanothercaveatto theuse of suchrules. Letus consideragainthe dynamicmodelof section2 andthe stationary rational expectationsequilibriaconsistentwitha policyruleof the form(27). However,we no longerrestrictattentionto equilibriaof theform(28) thoughwe knowthat,for almostall choicesof (+1r,y) thereis an equilibrium of thatform.Substitution of the policyrule(27) intothe "expectational IS curve"(22) yields

Etyt+1 = (r(+1r-l)st+ 1 + (1 + (ry)Yt-(rPt

(33)

wherewe haveusedthefactthatqrf= EtqTt+ 1 = qTt+ 1, becauseall pricesarefixedat leastone periodin advance.14 Next, advancingthe periodby one in the aggregate supplyrelationship (23) andusing(33) to substituteforEtyt+l, we obtain EtqTt+2 = t l[l +

+

KS(+s-

l)]t+l

-

s

lK(l

+

any)Yt

lK((rPt + EtOt+l)

(34)

Thesystem(33)-(34) canbe writtencompactlyin vectorformas Etxt+l = Mxt + zt wherext = [qTt+ 1Yt]t is a vectorof endogenousvariablesandzt is a vectorof exogenousdisturbances. Note thatbothelementsof xt aredetermined at datet (despite the factthat"qTt+ l" is writtenwitha t + 1 subscript,followingconventionalnotationfor the rateof inflation),andthateachis freeto respondto disturbances, news of futuredisturbances, or sunspotstatesrealizedat datet. Supposethatthe disturbance processes{Pt, Ot}are boundedrandomvariables. Then,fromBlanchard andKahn(1980),we knowthatthesystem(35) hasa unique boundedsolutionif andonly if botheigenvaluesof M lie outsidethe unitcircle. Whenthisconditionholds,(35) impliesthat k-1

Xt =-E

j=O

M-j-lEtzt+j

+ M-kEtxt+k

for all k 2 1. Becausein thiscaseM- l hasbotheigenvaluesinsidetheunitcircle, in anyboundedsolutionfor{xt}it mustbe that limk<,OOM

kEtXt+k

=

°

-

14. Although we wish now to allow for the possibility of sunspotequilibria,we assume that any sunspot state affecting pricing decisions made in period t (and taking effect in t + 1) is observed by the forecastersbefore they announcethe forecast 7,t>.

BENS. BERNANKE ANDMICHAEL WOODFORD: 671

Hencethe uniqueboundedsolutionto (35) is givenby 00

xt=-

E

M-j-lEtzt+j.

(36)

j=o

In the case in whichthe structural disturbances follow the processesdescribedin (24), it is possibleto writeEtzt+jfor arbitrary j 2 0 as a linearfunctionof thedisturbancevector[PtOJ'. It followsfrom(36) thatxt is a functionof theperiod-tdisturbancevectoras well. Then,in thiscase, theuniqueboundedsolutionis of the form (28), andis the stationary equilibrium characterized in section2. However,if M hasaneigenvalueinside theunitcircle,thereis no longera unique rationalexpectationsequilibrium,even if we restrictourattentionto boundedstationarysolutions.l5For example,supposethatM has one eigenvaluesatisfying IASI < 1 whilethe othersatisfiesIAUI > 1. (Thisturnsoutto be the case of greatest relevance,sinceit corresponds to a policyof attempting to "targettheinflationforecast"by choosinga largevalue for +1r;see below.)Then, letting(es, e") be the corresponding righteigenvectorsand(vs, v")the corresponding left eigenvectors, normalizedso thatvseS = vueU= 1, we knowthatanyprocessof the form xt= steU+ wteS

(37a)

is a boundedsolutionto (35), where(1) the scalarprocess{st}is definedby 00

st=-

2

j=o

A"-j-lvtEtzt+j;

(37b)

and(2) the scalarprocess{wt}evolvesaccordingto wt+l = ASWt + Et+lt

(37c)

where{et+1}is anyboundedrandomvariablesuchthatEtet+1 = ° The conditions(37a-c) admita wide varietyof solutions,dependingon the choiceof the unforecastable randomvariable{et+l}. One solutionarisesfromsettingwt = 0 for all t, so thatxt = ste";it is easilyverifiedthatthis solutionis of the form(28), so thatthisis thesolutioncharacterized in section2. However,if instead 15. We consider only bounded solutions because these solutions to our log-linear approximationsto the exact equilibriumconditions constitute approximatesolutions to the exact (nonlinear) conditions. Even in the case that there is a unique bounded solution to the log-linear equilibriumconditions, there may exist a multiplicityof solutions to the exact conditions;but one cannotdeterminethis from the form of the log-linearizedconditions alone. Further,even when the exact conditions have multiple solutions the bounded solution representsan approximatecharacterizationof a rationalexpectations equilibrium that is at least locally unique, in an appropriatetopology (Woodford1996). In the "indeterminate"case analyzed here, by contrast,the REE is not even locally unique-thus it is less plausible that the economy can be relied to settle into the particularstationaryequilibriumof the forrn(28), ratherthaninto one of the large multiplicityof nearbyequilibria.

while n oo. Then |+yn|/|+1nr| the quantity O Butinneither squarecondition bracketsin (39) thenor first condition equation (40) of (31) allows must |+n|become to grow unboundedly withoutbound large

672

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

we let {Et+ 1} be whitenoiseindependent of themodel'sstructural disturbances, then (37) describesa "sunspot" equilibrium. Foryet anotherdisturbingpossibility,suppose that{Et+l} dependson the innovationsto the model'sstructural disturbances, for example, Et+ 1 = Ntt+

1 + tant+

(38)

1 *

In this case it canbe shownthat,althoughoutputandinflationrespondonly to the structural disturbances of the model,in equilibrium the responsesof bothendogenousvariablesto the structural shocksareindeterminate. Evidently,the robustnessof rules thatrelatethe policy instrumentto privatesectorforecastsdependscriticallyon the magnitudesof the eigenvaluesof M. It turnsoutthatwhetherthe unique-or multiple-equilibrium case obtainsdependson the parameters of thepolicyrule,(27), itself. OnecanshowthatM hasbotheigenvaluesoutsidetheunitcircleif andonly if either py > - ( 1 - )(r

and - ( 1 - )+y <

K(+s

-

1) < ( 1 + )(+y

+

2ff)

(39)

> K(+s

-

1 ) > ( 1 + )(+y

+

2ff)

(40)

or y < - ( 1 - )(r

and - ( 1 - )+y

Clearly,thereexistpolicyrulesthatsatisfyeither(39) or (40) andso leadto a determinateequilibrium of the form(28). However,the requirement thatpolicy satisfy one of these conditionsrepresentsa furtherrestrictionon what can be achieved throughpolicyrulesof the form(27), in whichthe nominalinterestrateis allowed to dependon outputandthe inflationforecast. In particular, it is notpossibleto approximate closelythefirst-bestoutcomebl = b2 = 0 by usinga policyruleof theform(27), withoutleavingtherangeof parameter valuesfor whichthereexistsa determinate equilibrium. 16 Thusthe concernto maintainthe determinacyof equilibriumlimitsthe degreeto whicha rule of the form(27) can be usedto stabilizeinflation,even supposingthereis no problemof inducingforecastersto collectinformation andno noise in the forecasts.Furthermore,thereis no ruleof theform(27) thatcanguarantee that,in a rationalexpectations equilibrium,fluctuationsin the inflationrate will be small. In particular, vigorous"targeting" of theinflationforecast(|+1r| large)canneverensurethatinflationwill be stable:Tosee why,notethatif |+ylis alsomadelarge,so as to preserve determinacy of equilibrium, theninflationvariabilityin theuniqueequilibrium with boundedfluctuations is not small,becauseof the excessiveresponseof monetary 16. Proof: Suppose instead that there exists a sequence of policies {(g)n, (g)yn}, and an associated sequence of equilibria{bl, b2n}satisfying (31) for each n, with the propertythat bnl- > O and bn2- > O as as n grows, while the quantity(1 - 8 + aXyn)must not grow at the same rate, and indeed must eventually become an arbitrarilysmall fractionof the quantityin the squarebrackets.This can occur only if lXn| > °° unless |+yn|grows at the same rate, so that 1+1rl/|+yn| remainsboundedand |+y|/|+1r|remainsboundedaway from zero. Thus one obtains a contradiction.

BEN S. BERNANKE AND MICHAELWOODFORD : 673

policyto the fluctuations in outputcausedby supplyshocks.Butif |+ylis chosento be small,so thatb2is smallin theuniquesolutionof theform(28), thenthisequilibriumis no longerthe only one; andthe set of possiblerationalexpectationsequilibriain this case includesequilibriawitharbitrarily largefluctuations in inflation. In thelastsectionwe sawthattheproblemswithusinga ruleof theform(27), in whichonlythe inflationforecastwas considered,couldbe ameliorated by a ruleof the form(32), whichallowspolicyto respondto forecastsof the policyinstrument itself as well as to forecastsof inflation.Unfortunately, problemsof indeterminacy afflictrulesof the form(32) as well. To analyzepolicyrulesof this formwe may restrictattentionto the case R = 1, sinceonly this case is not coveredby the discussionabove. A rule of the form(32) with pR = 1 impliesthatin any rational expectationsequilibrium +1rst+1 =-yYt

(41)

Let us assume+1r7&o.l7 Then(41) impliesthatqTt+l= YYt,wherey---+v/+1r. Combiningthiswith(23) yields YYu (ay + K)EtYt+ X - KEtot+ l

(42)

Equation(42) hasa uniqueboundedsolutionif andonly if y 7&0 and -(1 + ) < - < 1 -

&

.

(43)

Thissolutionis givenby

Yt

w .=1 (

w)

8 ( 8 + K)

(44a)

Substitution of (44a)into(41) yieldsthe uniquesolutionfor inflation: st+ 1

(44b)

K

1 - 8(8

+ w)

Ontheotherhand,if y = Oor if eitherinequalityin (43) failsto hold,equilibrium is indeterminate undera ruleof theform(32). In particular, anyprocessof theform

( 7

+ K ) (Yt

7

t)

e,+l

(45)

17. It is easy to show that a rule of form (32) with + + Odoes not stabilize inflation, unless there is no stochastic disturbanceto the aggregatesupply equation(23).

674

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

where{et+l} is any boundedrandomvariablesuchthatEtet+l = O, representsa boundedsolutionto (42). Thecorresponding solutionfor inflationis thengivenby qTt+l= YYtAs discussedabove,thesesolutionsadmitarbitrary responsesof inflationandoutputto fundamental shocksor responsesto "sunspot" events.In particular,solutionsof theform(45) includeequilibriawitharbitrarily largefluctuations in output(bothin absolutetermsandrelativeto the"natural rate")and,exceptwheny = O,arbitrarily largefluctuations in inflationas well. Condition(43) showsthatdeterminacy of equilibrium requires,in the case of a ruleof the form(32) withR = 1, that1w1be sufficientlylarge.l8However,(44b) indicatesthatthe responseof inflationto supplyshockscanbe madesmallonly by makingI^YIsufficientlysmall.(Recallthatperfectstabilization was achieved,at the endof thelastsection,by a policycorresponding to y = O.) Thustherequirement of determinacy notonlyexcludescompletestabilization of inflationandoutput(around the naturalrate)throughthistypeof policy,butit also does not allowthe first-best equilibrium to be approximated. Indeed,condition(43) substituted intoconditions (44a,b) impliesthat, in any locally uniqueequilibrium,var(w)> (K8/(1 + a))2 var(o)andvar(y- 0) > ((1 - 8)/(1 + b))2var(o). Anypolicyimplyinganequilibriuminvolvingmorestabilization of inflationor outputthanthisresultsin indeterminacy.In particular, the policyR = 1, y = O, +s + O discussedat the end of section2 resultsin indeterminacy. l9 Wehaveexaminedtheproperties of relativelysimplepolicyrules,in the formof (27) or (32), thatlinkthe monetaryauthority's policyinstrument to forecastsof inflationand othervariables;andwe haveshownthat, if we imposethe additional restrictionthattheserulesdo not openthe economyto possibleindeterminacy of equilibrium, theserulescannotbe usedto perfectlystabilizetheeconomy.Now,as a theoreticalmatter,it is nottruethattherequirement of determinacy rulesoutperfect stabilizationby policy rules of any form:To displaya counterexample, let Rtlf denotetheforecastatthebeginningof periodt of Rt+1,Rt2ftheforecastatthebeginningof datet of Rt+2,andYfttheforecastatthebeginningof datet of Yt+l . Then[as provedin BernankeandWoodford (1997)]a policyrulethatresultsin a determinate rationalexpectationsequilibrium with completestabilizationof bothinflationand output(aroundits naturalrate)is givenby20 Rt = R,f l + A-l(R,lf-R2f l) +

+ g

+ (8

I-1)(1-8)

(

f

where+1ris anynonzeroquantity.Further, (46) canbe shownto be a specificexample of a muchwiderclass of ruleswiththeseproperties.Nevertheless,becauseof 18. In the case in which all prices are fixed one period in advance, which correspondsto the limiting case of the model of section 2 with K infinitelylarge, no finite |0YI is large enough, that is, any rule of the form discussed in the text results in indeterminacy. 19. Actually,in this case, because Py= 0, complete stabilizationof inflationis guaranteedin equilibrium; however, equilibriumoutputis indeterminateand the fluctuationsof outputaroundthe "naturalrate" can be unboundedlylarge. 20. We assume here that A 7&0, 8 7&0, and 8 7&1 + A. In the special case that 8 = 1 + A exactly, a more complicatedvariantof this rule will still work.

BEN S. BERNANKE AND MICHAELWOODFORD : 675

thecomplexityof (46), andits sensitivityto someelementsof themodel'sstructure, we do not wishto offerthisparticular ruleas a practicalpolicyproposal. The mainconclusionof this sectionis thatthe requirement of determinacy puts important restrictions on thecentralbank'schoiceof policyrules,particularly policy rulesthatrelatethecentralbank'sinstrument to explicitorimplicitprivate-sector forecasts.We reiteratethatthis resultby no meansprecludesthe use of privatesectorforecastsby the centralbankas sourcesof information not easily attainable by othermeans.But the information contentof private-sector forecastsshouldbe evaluatedin the contextof an explicitstructural modelof the economy;andthis is especiallycrucialin the case of policyrulesthatrespondin a highlysensitivemannerto changesin private-sector forecasts,whetherof inflationor of othermacroeconomicvariables.Such policies must be adoptedwith care. Finally,because conclusionsregarding thedeterminacy of rationalexpectations equilibrium areoften sensitiveto thedynamicspecification of one'smodel,it wouldbe prudentto analyze the predictedperformance of a contemplated ruleunderalternativespecifications. Withthesecaveatsas background, it is alsointeresting to notethattherulegiven in (46), whichdoes achieveperfectstabilizationwithinthe requirement of determinacy,ties policyto forecastsof interestratesandoutputbutnotof inflation.Thus the fact thata centralbank'smainobjectiveis to hit an inflationtargetdoes not imply that forecastsof inflationare moreuseful thanforecastsof othermacroeconomicvariables.Indeed,inflationforecastsareproblematic as a sourceof informationfor the centralbank,for the reasonstressedby Woodford(1994a)and in sections1 and2: If completestabilization of inflationis possible,private-sector inflationforecastscease to containany informationaboutexogenousshocksto the economy.Ontheotherhand,evenwithcompletestabilization, outputforecastswill revealthe conditionalexpectationof futurevaluesof the aggregatesupplyshock0 (andhence,if 8 + 0, thecurrent0); andinterestrateforecasts(or,perhaps,theterm structure)will revealthe conditionalexpectationof futurevaluesof the IS disturbancep (andhence, if A + 0, currentp). Thus,as a generalrule, it makesmore sense for the centralbankto makeuse of the information revealedby theseother forecasts,ratherthanforecastsof the goalvariable. 4. DISCUSSION OF RELATEDPROPOSALS

Althoughwe havefocussedfor concretenesson the effectsof targetingprivatesectorforecasts,thereareseveralproposalsformanagingmonetarypolicythatraise closelyrelatedissues. In this sectionwe brieflyconsidersomeof theseproposals. 4.1 AssetPricesas lndicatorsof lnflationExpectations It is sometimesarguedthatmonetarypolicyshouldrespondto the changesin inflationexpectations thatmaybe inferredfromvariousassetprices,as opposedto the explicit forecastsmadeby individualforecasters.Well-knownexamplesinclude proposalsto adjustmonetarypolicyin responseto movementsin a commodityprice index(forexample,Reynolds1982),to movementsin long-termbondyieldsor in

676 : MONEY,CRED1T, ANDBANKING

interestratespreads(forexample,Goodfriend1993),to CPIfuturesprices(forexample,Dowd 1994;Sumner1995),or in responseto the yield spreadbetweenindexed and nonindexedgovernmentbonds (for example,Hetzel 1990, 1992).21 Reasonsformakinguse of assetpricesas indicators insteadof (oratleastin addition to) explicitforecastsmightincludethe belief that financialmarketsaggregatea greateramountof informationthanis po-ssessedby any smallnumberof market participants alone;a beliefthatpeoplemayrevealtheirbeliefsmoretruthfullyin the waythattheyrisktheirownmoneythanin theirpublicstatements; or a concernthat forecasterscouldbe subjectto politicalmanipulation. Proposalsof thiskind,however,arepotentiallysubjectto all of thedrawbacks of "forecasttargeting" discussedabove.Toillustrate,considera ruleof the form

Rt= 4)7r(Rt-Rtr) + 4)yYt

( )

whereRtrdenotesthe realinterestratepaidon a one-periodindexedbond.Suppose furthermore thatin a rationalexpectationsequilibrium, the yieldson the two types of bondsarelinkedby Rtr= Rt-Etqrt+l

(48)

Thenequilibriumis determinedby relations(33)-(34) and (47)-(48). But, using (48) to eliminateRtr,oneobtainsthesamesystemof threeequationsas in thecaseof policyrule(27), whenqrf= Etqrt+ 1is usedto eliminateEtqrt+ 1 Thusall conclusions withregardto rlllesof the form(27) areobtainedin thiscase as well. Becauseour criticismof "forecasttargeting" rulesof thatkinddidnotdependuponanyassumed inadequacy of the forecasters'inform-ation or difficultyin elicitinghonestreportsof theirconditionalexpectations,theuse of assetpricesto infer"market expectations" doesnot solve anyof the problemspreviouslydiscussed. It is truethatourdiscussionof strategicrandomization by forecastersas a source of forecast"noise"wouldnot applyto the "marketexpectations" impliedby asset prices.However,asset-pricemeasuresof inflationexpectationsarelikelyto be contaminated by othersourcesof noise.Forexample,CampbellandShiller(1996)discuss the possibleuse the spreadbetweenindexedandnonindexedbondyieldsas a measureof inflationexpectations,andpointoutthatsucha measurecouldeasilybe contaminated by changesin expectationsregardingthe futuretax treatmentof the two kindsof bonds,or by changesin the inflationriskpremium.The presenceof theseextraneoussourcesof variationin the yield spreadmakesa policyruleof the form(47) wiffia large| + | as unappealing as a policyruleof the form(27) witha large|+ |. Furtherproblemswith using the inflationexpectationsimplicitin asset prices arisewhentheconnectionbetweenassetpricesandexpectedinflationis notreasonablystraightforward (as it is in the indexedbondcase)butinsteadmaybe sensitive 21. Proposalsof this kind were given particulatattentionwithin the FederalReserve System following the endorsementof an approachof this general type by Vice ChairmanManuel H. Johnson(1988).

BENS. BERNANKE ANDMICHAEL WOODFORD: 677

to the policyregime.Considerfor exampleGoodfriend's (1993) proposalthatthe fundsratebe raisedwheneverlongratesrise(anincreasein longratesbeingtakento indicateanincreasein expectedinflation).Tosimplifytheanalysis,supposethatthe centralbankobservesthe nominalyieldRt on a consol.In accordancewiththe expectationstheoryof thetermstructure, supposethatthisyieldis determined in equilibriumby therelation 00

Rt=(l-)

E

T=t

T-tEtRT+tt

(49)

wherethetermpremium(t iS assumedto be anexogenousstochasticprocess.Then it is easyto describepolicyregimesunderwhichequilibrium fluctuations in thelong rateRltcorrespond largelyto variationsin expectedinflation.Supposefor simplicity thatA - 8 = Oin (24). Conditions(22)-(24) thenimplythat EtRT = EtqrT+ 1 + ((rs)-l(Et5sT+l-Et5flT+2)

-

Substitution of thisinto(49) yields 00

Rlt= (1-ORt + (1-)

E

T-tEtflt+l

+

(1-)+(ffK)

lEt5flt+2 + (t

T=t+ 1

If e is nearone (becauseperiodsareshort),thenthe returnon the consolis essentiallya weightedaverageof theexpectedrateof inflationovervariousfutureperiods (plusthe termpremium,if any). Nonetheless,in this settinga policyruleof the kindthatGoodfriendappearsto advocatewouldnot help to guaranteestableprices.Considera policy rule of the form Rt=

XRt

for sorne+ > O. The completesystemof equilibrium conditionsis thengiven by (22)-(23) and (49)-(50). Note thatthe subsystem(49)-(50) determinesthe processes{Rt,R:, withto referenceto theevolutionof pricesor output,whilethe subsystem (22)-(23) then determinesthe processes{stt, Yt}, given the equilibrium processfor nominalinterestrates. Subsystem(49)-(50) may or may not uniquelydeterminerationalexpectations equilibrium processesfor shortandlong nominalrates.If 1<+<

1++

(51)

then the solution for {Rt,Rlt}is not unique, even if one restrictsattentionto bounded

678

: MONEY, CRED1T,AND BANKING

solutions(andassumesa boundedstochasticprocessfor the termpremium).22 In particular, anyprocessfor the longrateof the form Rl+l = RI +

(et+l-e

ltt)

+

tt

where+-[1 - (1 - ,B)+]/,B,and{vt}is anysequenceof mean-zerorandomvariablesunforecastable one periodin advance,solves (49)_(SO).23 Thecorresponding solutionfortheshortrateis thengivenby (50). Thusequilibrium variabilityin interest ratesmaybe arbitrarily large,andmayincluderesponseto "sunspot" variables. Theproblem,essentially,is thatexpectations thatinterestrateswill be highbecome self-fulfillingbecausetheexpectationof highratesin thefuturecauseslongratesto rise, leadingthe centralbank(thatinterpretsthis as an "inflationscare")to raise shortrates.Thisvariationin interestratesdueto self-fulfillingexpectationsresults, of course,in instabilityof pricesandoutputas well. But even when (49)-(50) uniquelydeterminethe equilibriumpathof nominal interestrates[because(51) does nothold],theresultingsystemof equilibrium conditionsis equivalentto thatwhichobtainsif the monetarypolicyspecifiesan exogenouspathfortheshort-term nominalinterestrate,corresponding to theprocess{Rt} thatsolves(49)-(50). Buta monetarypolicyof thatsortresultsin indeterminacy of the pathsof inflationandoutput,for the samereasonas in ouranalysisaboveof a ruleof the form(27) with+ = py = O.Thusa policyruleof the form(50) results in indeterminacy regardlessof the valueof +. 4.2 InternalCentralBankForecasts A relatedquestionconcernsthe properuse of internalcentralbankforecastsof inflationin settingmonetarypolicy.Certainlycentralbanksdo prepareforecastsof inflation(andof othergoal variables),andtheseforecastsplay an important role in discussionsof how to adjustpolicyto currentconditions.Svensson(1997)suggests thata centralbankthatseeksto achievea targetrateof inflationoughtto treatits own internalinflationforecastas its "intermediate target."24 Svensson'sdiscussion seemsto implyat timesthatthe inflationforecast,once prepared,providesall the information thatpolicymakersneed to haveto set policy.Forexample,he writes (pp. 14-l5)25:

Althoughthe constructionof the forecastis difficultandresource-demanding,the monetarypolicy conclusions from a given inflationforecast are straightforward: If the forecast is above (below) the target, monetarypolicy shouldbe adjustedin a contractionary (expansionary)direction. If the forecast is on target, monetarypolicy is appropriate. 22. This can be shown using the same methods as in section 3. The analysis is simplest if (49) is replacedby the quasi-differencedform Rl,= (1-)R, + E,RI,+ l + (,, where (,--(,-E,g,+ 1. Note that boundedprocesses {R,, RtSsatisfy this equationif and only if they satisfy (49). 23. Condition(51) is just the conditionunderwhich |+| < 1, SO thatthis defines a boundedprocess for the long rate, if {et, tt} are boundedprocesses. 24. The idea that an inflationforecast should be treatedas an "intermediatetarget"is found in various discussions of recent monetarypolicy strategyin the United Kingdom, such as King (1994) and Bowen (1995). Svensson goes beyond thes-ediscussions in stressing that it is an internalforecast that should be targeted. 25. We quote here from the workingpaperversion of Svensson's paper, datedJune 1996.

BEN S. BERNANKEAND MICHAELWOODFORD : 679

Svenssonasserts(p. 3) thattargetingof "thecentralbank'sown structural forecast"does not give rise to the problemsof circularity associatedwithtargetingthe consensusprivate-sector forecast.Some care mustbe takenhere, however:The merefactthatthe forecastis prepared internallydoes not, in itself, haveanyeffect on thevalidityof the analysisin theprevioussections.Suppose,forexample,thata centralbankassignsto a partof its staffthedutyof preparing the inflationforecast, aftercollectingall relevantdataas to thecurrentstateof theeconomy,andthenasks this part of the staff to reporta single number their unconditionalinflation forecast to the policymakingarmof the centralbank.Thepolicymakers thenact in the way indicatedin the abovequotation.Supposefurthermore thatthe staffof the forecastingdepartment arerewardedsimplyon the basisof the accuracyof the forecaststhatthey deliver.Thenthe situationis exactlythe sameas if the central banksolicitsthe forecastsof outsideforecasters,andourpreviousanalysisapplies exactly. Thusit is certainlynottruethatthepolicymakers needno otherinformation from the staffaboutcurrentconditionsotherthantheirinflationforecast.If, forexample, the centralbankregardsthe modelof sections2-3 as an accuraterepresentation of theeconomy,thepolicymakers shouldaskthe staffforthe information neededto implementrule(46), or someotherrulethatachievesthedesiredresponsesto p and 0 shocksas a uniquerational expectations equilibrium.26 Of course,if thatinformationis providedandthepolicyrule(46) is implemented, thenin theresultingrational expectationsequilibriumthe forecastingdepartmentshouldalways forecast inflationto equalthetargetrate.Butthatfactdoesnotimplythatadvisingthepolicymakersto implement(46), andprovidingtheinformation aboutcurrentconditions neededto do so, is equivalentto advisingthemto targetthe inflationforecastand providinginformation only aboutthecurrentvalueof thatforecast. In fact,a carefulreadingof Svensson'sdiscussionindicatesthathe doesnotadvocate a regimeas simpleas ourhypothetical.His qualification thatthe centralbank musttargeta "structural" forecastis a crucialone. This appearsto meannot only thatthecentralbank'sinternalforecastis prepared withtheuse of a structural model, butthatthemodelanddataon thecurrentstateof theeconomyareusedto determinethe policyactionthat,accordingto the model,shouldresultin a forecastof inflationequalto the target.Wehaveno quarrelwithSvensson'srecommendation, if it is understood in thisway. Butit seemsoddto us (andpossiblydangerous) to summarize sucha recommendationwith the phrase"inflationforecasttargeting."Such a summaryinvitesthe interpretation suggestedin ourhypothetical (asdoesthelanguagecitedearlier).Further,in placesSvenssonseemsto suggestthatit wouldbe sufficientfor the staffto presentthe policymakers witha reportof the form,"Ourmodelpredictsthatinflationwill be 1 percentabovetargettwo yearsfromnow if the fundsrateremainsat its currentlevel, butit will be on targetif thefundsrateis raisedimmediately by 50 basispoints."In otherwords,it mightseemthata forecastthatis conditionalupon 26. Of course, the advice of the staff will also be requiredto explain the advantagesof rule (46), which depends upon the form and parametervalues of the structuralmodel (22)-(24).

680

: MONEYsCREDITsAND BANKING

thepolicyactionchosenis all thattheforecastingdepartment needsto produce.But this resultis only possible,in Svensson'sanalysis,becausehe assumesa modelof inflationdeterms inationin whichthedynamiclinkagesbetweenmonetarypolicyand inflationareextremelyrudimentary (as in ouranalysisin section1). Toillustratethispoint,notethatASvensson's structural modelimpliesthatinflation is determined by anequationof theform aTt+2

=

St +

Xt-zRt

+

Et+2

(52)

wherest is an exogenousstatevariableknownat datet, xt is an endogenousstate variablethatis predetermined at datet, Et+2 iS an exogenousrandomdisturbance thatis unforecastable as of datet, andwe haveusedthe samedatingconventionsas in previoussections.Given(52), it is clearthatthe policy thatminimizesthe expectedsquareddeviationof inflationfromtargetis givenby Rt = z

l(St + Xt) -

Thus, revelationto the policymakers of the conditionalforecastimpliedby (52), pamely, sTft(Rt)= St + Xt-wRt

sufficesto allowthemto determinetheoptimalaction(53). But (52) is an unrealistically oversimplified modelof inflationdetermination. In particular, expectationsof futurepolicyplay no role, so thatit is possiblefor the modelto yielda forecastconditionalsolelyuponthecurrentpolicyaction,without anyspecification of a policyrulethatthecentralbankis committedto followin the future.In general,expectations of futurepolicywill be relevantto thedetermination ,ofcurrentinflation(as in our modelof sections2-3), so thata conditionalforecastof thatkindcannotbe "structural." In thedynamicmodelanalyzedin sections 2-3 of thispaper,thereis no obviouswayto communicate the information needed forthepolicymakers to implementtheoptimalpolicy(26) in termsof a conditional inflationforecast.27 4.3 The Role of InfZationForecasts in MonitoringCentralBank Performance

Svensson(1997)arguesthatanotheradvantage of "inflation forecasttargeting" as a strategyfor monetarypolicyis thatit facilitatesmonitoringby the publicof the centralbank'scommitment to its putativeinflationtarget.As we notedin the introduction,the generalproblemis thattherecan be a long delayafterthe announce27. Svensson (1997) provides an example of an economy with forward-lookingelements in which next period's expected inflationis a sufficientstatisticfor policy. This example is ratherspecial, though, in that timing as$umptionsare made so that the expectationof inflationone period aheadcontains information useful to the policymakers,but is independentof currentpolicy actions. Further,Svensson does not show th.at the rationalexpectationsequilibriumhe considersis uniqueunderthe forecast-basedinstrument rule that he proposes.

BENS. BERNANKE ANDMICHAEL WOODFORD: 681

mentof aninflationtargetuntilthetimewhenit candetermined whetherthetargetis beingmet(andeventhen,inflationmaydeviatefromthetargetrateforreasonsoutside the controlof the centralbank).However,Svenssonsuggests,if peoplecan observeimmediatelywhetheror not inflationis forecastedto equalthe targetrate, thencentralbankmisbehavior shouldbecomeapparent soonafterthewrongactions havebeentaken.Recognizingthis,thecentralbankshouldbe less willingto deviate fromits promisedpolicy. Takingthis line of reasoningfurther,one mightseek to ensurecentralbankaccountabilityby mandating publictestimonyas to the bank'ssuccessin keepinginflationforecastson target(forexample,as partof theHumphrey-Hawkins reportto Congressthatis madetwicea yearby theChairman of theFederalReserveBoardin the UnitedStates),or even to imposepenaltiesundera "centralbanker'scontract" fordeviationsof inflationforecastsfromthetargetlevel. Insofaras accountability is judgedto be a seriousproblem,attentionto thebehaviorof inflationforecastsdoes seemdesirableas a centralelementin themonitoring of centralbankbehavior;forit is indeedtrueunderquitegeneralcircumstances thatone propertyof an optimal policyis that(rationally formed)inflationforecastsoughtnotdeviatefromthetarget inflationrate.And this particular propertyof optimalpolicyis one thatis easy to explain,andperhapseasierthanothersto verifyas well. However,again,theseobservations do notimplythatit is desirableforthecentral bankto targettheparticular inflationforecastthatis usedby thepublicorthegovernmentin evaluatingthe centralbank'sperformance. Forthe samereasonsdiscussed earlier,the currentlevel of the inflationforecastshouldnot be the only aspectof currentconditionsthatis closelytrackedby thecentralbank,noris it desirablethat monetary policybe adjustedsharplyinresponseto smalldeviationsof sucha forecast fromtarget.However,on theotherhand,a narrowfocuson theinflationforecastby thecentralbankis notrequiredin orderfortheperformance of monetarypolicyto be monitored inthemannersuggested:Supposethatthecentralbankhassufficientinformationtopursueanoptimalpolicy;say,(46)is implemented. Thenif thepublicforms a rationalforecast,baseduponcorrectknowledgeof thestateof theeconomyandof thecentralbank'saction,andalsoupona correctmodelof inflationdetermination (as assumedby Svensson),thenthe publicwill findthatits forecastof inflationalways equalsthe target.In otherwords,the centralbankcan choosea policythathas the effiectof keepingprivateinflationforecastsequalto thetargetwithoutits havingthe formof a "forecasttargeting" rule,andit is desirablethatit do so. If theprivatesector'sinformation, or modelof theeconomy,doesnot agreewith thatof the centra}bank,however,mattersare morecomplex.Awarenessthatits performance will be evaluatedin termsof private-sector forecaststhatit regardsas incorrectwill surelyinterferewiththecentralbank'spursuitof inflationstabilization (accordingto its own beliefs).But this does not meanthatthe centralbankmust practicenaive"forecasttargeting."It might,for example,implementrule(26), but usingthe privatesector'sestimatesof the statesPtandbt (eventhoughit believes thatit hasbetterinformation), andusingtheprivatesector'sbeliefsabouttheparameters8 and(x(eventhoughit believesthesevaluesareincorrect).Implementation of

682

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

sucha rule(andachievementof a reputation for doingso) wouldresultin privatesectorinflationforecaststhat neverdeviatedfromtarget,exceptperhapsfor the "noise"componentof thoseforecasts.If the centralbank'sinformation is moreaccuratethanthatof the privatesector,thenrequiringthe centralbankto adoptthis aim wouldinvolvea sacrificeof some degreeof inflationstabilizationthatmight otherwisehavebeenachievable; andsucha methodformonitoring centralbankperformancewouldnotbe desirableif the informational differencewerebelievedto be too severe.But it wouldnotresultin the difficultiesstressedearlier,as long as the centralbankrespondsto its estimateof the factorsthatdeterminethe privateforecastsratherthanto its observation of the privateforecaststhemselves. A versionof sucha proposalthatmightalsoreducetheextentto whichthecentral bankis requiredto stabilizeincorrectprivateforecastsratherthanactualinflation wouldbe to simplyrequirethe centralbankto give publictestimonyaboutthe motivationfor its policystance,thatmightwell includediscussionof its own inflation forecast.Private-sector forecaststhatdisagreewith thatof the centralbankmight well be mattersthatwouldrequirecommenton thepartof thecentralbank,butone couldacceptanexplanation on thepartof thecentralbankof how its ownforecasts are madeas sufficientdemonstration of a good-faitheffortto achievethe inflation target.In sucha case, the factthatpubliclyavailableinflationforecastsplayan importantrole in ensuringcentralbankaccountability wouldnot in any way require thatthe centralbanknaivelytargetthoseforecasts. 5. CONCLUSION

Ourconclusion,in brief,is thatthereareno shortcuts for monetaryauthorities attemptingto targetinflationor othermacroeconomic variables.To achievetheir policyobjectives,centralbanksmustbothdevelopstructural modelsof the macroeconomyandgatherrelevantinformation froma varietyof sources.28Monitoring forecastsof boththebank'stargetvariableandothervariablesis likelyto be a useful partof theinformation-gathering process;but"targeting" macroeconomic forecasts, in the sensedescribedin thispaper,is likelyto be riskyor evencounter-productive. 28. It was not our intention in writing this paper to improve employment prospects for economists, though our conclusions have that implication. LITERATURECITED

Bernanke,Ben, andIlianMihov."WhatDoestheBundesbank Target?" EuropeanEconomic Review,forthcoming. Bernanke,Ben, andFredericMishkin."Central BankBehaviorandtheStrategyof Monetary Policy:EvidencefromSix Industrialized Countries." In NBERMacroeconomicsAnnual, editedby OlivierBlanchard andStanleyFischer.Cambridge Mass.:MITPress, 1992. . "Inflation Targeting: A New Strategyfor MonetaryPolicy?"Journal of Economic Perspectives, forthcoming. Bernanke,Ben, andMichaelWoodford. "Inflation ForecastsandMonetaryPolicy."National Bureauof EconomicResearchworkingpaper,1997.

BENS. BERNANKE ANDMICHAEL WOODPORD: 683

Blanchard,Olivier, and CharlesM. Kahn. "The Solution of LinearDifference Models under RationalExpectations."Econometrica 48 (1980), 1305-11. Blinder, Alan S. "CentralBanking in Theory and Practice Lecture II: Credibility,Discretion and Independence."MarshallLecture, University of Cambridge,May 5, 1995. Bowen, Alexander."BritishExperiencewith InflationTargeting" In Inff!ation Targets,edited by LeonardoLeidermanand Lars E. O. Svensson. London:CEPR, 1995. Calvo, Guillermo A. "Staggered Prices in a Utility-MaximizingFramework."Journalof MonetaryEconomics12 (1983), 383-98. Campbell,John, and RobertShiller. "A Scorecardfor IndexedGovernmentDebt." In National Bureau of Economic ResearchMacroeconomics Annual,edited by Ben Bernankeand Julio Rotemberg.CambridgeMass.: MIT Press, 1996. Cochrane,John H. "Identifyingthe OutputEffects of MonetaryPolicy." National Bureauof Economic Researchworking paperno. 5154, June 1995. Debelle, Guy, and StanleyFischer. "How IndependentShould a CentralBank Be?" In Goals, Guidelines,andConstraints FacingMonetary Policymakers, edited by JeffreyFuhrer.Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1994. Dowd, Kevin. "A Proposalto End Inflation."EconomicJournal104 (1994), 828-40. Goodfriend, Marvin. "InterestRate Policy and the Inflation Scare Problem: 1979-1992." FederalReserve Bank of Richmond,EconomicQuarterly 79 (Winter 1993), 1-24. Goodhart,CharlesA. E., and Jose Vinals. "Strategyand Tacticsof MonetaryPolicy: Examples from Europeand the Antipodes."In Goals,Guidelines,andConstraints FacingMonetaryPolicymakers, edited by JeffreyFuhrer.FederalReserve Bank of Boston, 1994. Guesnerie, Roger, and Michael Woodford."EndogenousFluctuations."In Advancesin EconomicTheory SixthWorldCongress,editedby J.-J. Laffont. Cambridge:CambridgeUniversity Press, 1992. Haldane, Andrew G., ed. Targeting lnJqation. London:Bank of England, 1995. Hall, RobertE., and N. GregoryMankiw."NominalIncome Targeting."In Monetary Policy, edited by N. G. Mankiw. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for National Bureau of Economic Research, 1994. Hetzel, RobertL. "MaintainingPrice Stability:A Proposal."FederalReserve Bank of Richmond, EconomicReview(March/April1990), 53-55. . "IndexedBonds as an Aid to MonetaryPolicy." FederalReserve Bank of Richmond, EconomicReview(January/February1992), 13-23. Johnson, Manuel. "CurrentPerspectiveson MonetaryPolicy." CatoJournal8 (1988), 25360. Kerr,William, and RobertG. King. "Limitson InterestRate Rules in the IS Model." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,EconomicQuarterly (Spring 1996), 47-75. King, Mervyn. "MonetaryPolicy in the U.K." FiscalStudies15 (1994), 109-28. King, Robert G., and Mark W. Watson. "Money, Prices, InterestRates, and the Business Cycle." Reviewof EconomicsandStatistics78 (1996), 35-53. Lamont, Owen. "MacroeconomicForecasts and Microeconomic Porecasters."Paper, University of Chicago, May 1996. Laster, David, Paul Bennett, and In Sun Geoum. "RationalBias in Macroeconomic Forecasts." Researchpaperno. 9617, FederalReserve Bank of New York, July 1996. Leiderman,Leonardo, and Lars E. O. Svensson, eds. InflationTargets.London:Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1995. Mayes, David G., and BrendonRiches. "TheEffectiveness of MonetaryPolicy in New Zealand."ReserveBankBulletin(New Zealand)59 (1996), 5-20.

684

: MONEY, CREDIT,AND BANKING

McCallum,BennettT., andEdwardNelson."AnOptimizing IS-LMSpecification forMonetaryPolicyandBusinessCycleAnalysis."NationalBureauof EconomicResearchworking paperno. 5875, January1997. Reynolds,Alan."TheTroublewithMonetarism." PolicyReview21 (Summer1982),19-42. Roberts,JohnM. "NewKeynesianEconomicsandthe PhillipsCurve."Journalof Money, Credit,andBanking27 (November1995,Part1), 975-84. Romer,Christina,andDavidRomer."Federal ReservePrivateInformation andtheBehavior of InterestRates."NationalBureauof EconomicResearchworkingpaperno. 5692, July 1996. Rotemberg, Julio,andMichaelWoodford. "AnOptimization-based Econometric Framework for the Evaluationof MonetaryPolicy."NationalBureauof EconomicResearchMacroeconomicsAnnual,editedby BenBernankeandJulioRotemberg,forthcoming. Sumner,Scott. "TheImpactof FuturesPriceTargeting on the PrecisionandCredibilityof MonetaryPolicy."Journalof Money,Credit,andBanking27 (February1995),89-106. Svensson,LarsE. O. "Inflation ForecastTargeting: Implementing andMonitoringInflation Targets." EuropeanEconomicReview,41 (1997), 1111-46. . "Inflation Targeting: SomeExtensions."Unpublished,IIES,Stockholm,February 1997. West,KennethD. "Comment on Hall andMankiw."In MonetaryPolicy,editedby N. G. Mankiw.Chicago:Univ.of ChicagoPressforNBER,1994. Woodford, Michael."Nonstandard Indicators forMonetary Policy:CanTheirUsefulnessBe JudgedfromForecasting Regressions?" InMonetary Policy,editedby N. G. Mankiw.Chicago:Univ.of ChicagoPressforNBER,1994(a). . "Determinacy of Equilibrium underAlternative PolicyRegimes:Introduction." EconornicTheory4 (1994),323-6 (b). . "Control of thePublicDebt:A Requirement forPriceStability?" NationalBureauof EconomicResearchworkingpaperno. 5684, July 1996. Yun, Tack."NominalPriceRigidity,MoneySupplyEndogeneity,and BusinessCycles." Journalof MonetaryEconomics37 (1996),345-70.

Inflation Forecasts and Monetary Policy

put and interest rates, just as it can to policies based on forecasts of inflation. The most general conclusion of our paper is that central banks should be careful ...

680KB Sizes 4 Downloads 344 Views

Recommend Documents

Core Inflation and Monetary Policy
An alternative strategy could therefore be for monetary policy to target a .... measure of core inflation which excludes food and energy from the CPI is ...... Reserve Bank of New Zealand (1999), 'Minor Technical Change to Inflation Target', News.

Inflation, Unemployment, and Monetary Policy
Jul 5, 2003 - increases in food and energy prices, similar impulses from import prices, ... might be said to "work," in the sense that it can always rationalize the facts. .... (My alternative model allows a fairly wide range of neutral rates.

Core inflation and monetary policy - Dnb
which we will call CPIX inflation, defined as CPI inflation excluding the interest rate ..... variables, the solutions under commitment and discretion coincide.

MONETARY POLICY, INFLATION AND ECONOMIC ...
TER VERKRIJGING VAN DE GRAAD VAN DOCTOR ... Prof. dr J.J.M. Kremers ..... restructuring as an explanation for the slow recovery from the early-1990s ...

Monetary Policy, Expected Inflation, and Inflation Risk ...
Aug 2, 2007 - email: [email protected] ..... premia, and inflation term premia in the benchmark parameterization. ... risk and term premia, benchmark case.

Core inflation and monetary policy - De Nederlandsche Bank
Bank conference on “Measuring Inflation for Monetary Policy Purposes” in ... which we will call CPIX inflation, defined as CPI inflation excluding the interest rate ... First, temporary disturbances and exogenous components make the CPI ...

Inflation, unemployment and monetary policy – new ...
See also the article “The development of inflation in a longer perspective” in Account of Monetary. Policy 2012 ..... the inflation target, inflation expectations for the corporate sector as measured by the. National Institute of .... policy rate

Capacity Utilization, Inflation and Monetary Policy
Feb 1, 2005 - associated with a higher long run rate of capacity utilization and a higher rate of growth. It is .... In addition, higher real wages (when assuming no technical progress) may generate .... Economic Education, Fall, 333-346.

Capacity Utilization, Inflation and Monetary Policy
Feb 1, 2005 - Taylor, J.B. (1999) Monetary policy guidelines for employment and ... Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Princeton.

Monetary Policy, Trend Inflation and the Great Moderation
It is easy to show that the relationship between firm-specific and aggregate marginal costs is a function of aggregate price dispersion, but as ...... Volatility of GDP growth rate. Inflation rate. USA. 0.0. 0.4. 0.8. 1.2. 1.6. 2.0. 0. 4. 8. 12. 16.

Monetary Policy in Vietnam: Alternatives to Inflation Targeting
Jul 28, 2005 - 3.1 Issues Surrounding Scope for Inflation Targeting ............................................. 37 ..... circulation (not officially recorded). It is also likely that the ...

Monetary Policy in Vietnam: Alternatives to Inflation Targeting
Jul 28, 2005 - to ensure the stability of key macro prices during the Doi Moi period. 41 Among them: Hans Genberg, Edwin Truman, ...

Fiscal Policy and Inflation in a Monetary Union i Model ...
Oct 20, 2015 - of its degree of openness # ' (0+1), such that. (1 %) φ (1 B)#. The more open the home country (the greater is #), the lower is the degree of ...

Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Monetary Union
Jul 25, 2015 - more flexible markets would foster a more rapid recovery from the recession generated by the crisis ... and to match features of macroeconomic data for Europe's Economic and .... To the best of our knowledge, our ..... time) must buy t

Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Monetary Union
Jul 25, 2015 - URL: http://www.hec.ca/en/profs/matteo.cacciatore.html ... In the United States, Lawrence Summers called for “bold reform” of the U.S. economy as a key remedy ...... appear in the table are determined as described in the text.

Endogenous Indexing and Monetary Policy Models
I Degree of indexation signi cant ACB may erroneously conclude that the value of commitment is small, price level target welfare-reducing. I What if persistence ...

Sectoral Heterogeneity and Monetary Policy - Jonathan Kreamer
count for dynamic demand effects from durable goods, and systematically utilize forward guidance to reduce sectoral volatility. A calibrated model confirms these.

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching - Semantic Scholar
The degree to which tax shocks affect inflation in an AM/PF regime depends on the transition matrix. ..... 13(1), edited by B. S. Bernanke and J. J. Rotemberg, pp. 323–84. .... Business Cycles? edited by J. C. Fuhrer and S. Schuh, pp. 121–60.

Monetary Policy and Banking Structure
supported by the research fellowships of the Japan Society for the Promotion of. Science for young scientists. ... Kyoto University, Japan, Email: [email protected]. 1 .... examples of two different banking systems, those of the United States.

Openness and Optimal Monetary Policy
Dec 6, 2013 - to shocks, above and beyond the degree of openness, measured by the .... inversely related to the degree of home bias in preferences.4 Our ...