Information, Misallocation and Aggregate Productivity Joel M. David USC

Hugo A. Hopenhayn

Venky Venkateswaran

UCLA

NYU Stern

Sep 2015

1 / 27

This paper “Misallocation,” i.e., dispersion in MP’s ⇒ large losses in TFP and output • But sources of distortions still unclear... • Role of imperfect information? Informational role of financial markets?

1. What we do • Heterogeneous firms choose inputs under imperfect info • Firms learn from internal sources and noisy asset prices • Quantify frictions using stock market/production data in US, China, India

2. What we find • Significant micro uncertainty, esp. in China and India

→ accounts for 20-50% (+...) of MRPK dispersion • Sizable aggregate impact

→ TFP losses: 7-10% in China and India, 4% in US; lower bound...? • Only limited learning from markets; firm internal sources are key 2 / 27

This paper “Misallocation,” i.e., dispersion in MP’s ⇒ large losses in TFP and output • But sources of distortions still unclear... • Role of imperfect information? Informational role of financial markets?

1. What we do • Heterogeneous firms choose inputs under imperfect info • Firms learn from internal sources and noisy asset prices • Quantify frictions using stock market/production data in US, China, India

2. What we find • Significant micro uncertainty, esp. in China and India

→ accounts for 20-50% (+...) of MRPK dispersion • Sizable aggregate impact

→ TFP losses: 7-10% in China and India, 4% in US; lower bound...? • Only limited learning from markets; firm internal sources are key 2 / 27

This paper “Misallocation,” i.e., dispersion in MP’s ⇒ large losses in TFP and output • But sources of distortions still unclear... • Role of imperfect information? Informational role of financial markets?

1. What we do • Heterogeneous firms choose inputs under imperfect info • Firms learn from internal sources and noisy asset prices • Quantify frictions using stock market/production data in US, China, India

2. What we find • Significant micro uncertainty, esp. in China and India

→ accounts for 20-50% (+...) of MRPK dispersion • Sizable aggregate impact

→ TFP losses: 7-10% in China and India, 4% in US; lower bound...? • Only limited learning from markets; firm internal sources are key 2 / 27

Overview

• Simplified model

• Full model and numerical results

• Robustness

• Other evidence

3 / 27

Simplified model Homogeneous good, only capital, no aggregate risk • Continuum of producers:

Yit = Ait Kitα ,

ait ∼ iid, N 0, σµ2



Input choice under incomplete info: • Profit maximization:

maxKit Eit [Ait ] Kitα − RKit

• Conditional on info Iit , ait ∼ N (Eit ait , V)

V is key object: • Misallocation: • Aggregate TFP :

2 σmpk =V

a = a∗ −

1 α σ2 2 1−α mpk

= a∗ −

1 α V 2 1−α

⇒ TFP ↓ in V; size of effect ↑ in α

4 / 27

Simplified model Homogeneous good, only capital, no aggregate risk • Continuum of producers:

Yit = Ait Kitα ,

ait ∼ iid, N 0, σµ2



Input choice under incomplete info: • Profit maximization:

maxKit Eit [Ait ] Kitα − RKit

• Conditional on info Iit , ait ∼ N (Eit ait , V)

V is key object: • Misallocation: • Aggregate TFP :

2 σmpk =V

a = a∗ −

1 α σ2 2 1−α mpk

= a∗ −

1 α V 2 1−α

⇒ TFP ↓ in V; size of effect ↑ in α

4 / 27

Simplified model Homogeneous good, only capital, no aggregate risk • Continuum of producers:

Yit = Ait Kitα ,

ait ∼ iid, N 0, σµ2



Input choice under incomplete info: • Profit maximization:

maxKit Eit [Ait ] Kitα − RKit

• Conditional on info Iit , ait ∼ N (Eit ait , V)

V is key object: • Misallocation: • Aggregate TFP :

2 σmpk =V

a = a∗ −

1 α σ2 2 1−α mpk

= a∗ −

1 α V 2 1−α

⇒ TFP ↓ in V; size of effect ↑ in α

4 / 27

Characterizing V

The firm’s information set Iit 1. Private signal: sit = ait + eit ,

eit ∼ N 0, σe2

pit ≈ ait + ηit ,

ηit ∼ N 0, ση2

2. Stock price:

 

If (ait , eit , ηit ) independent (relaxed later): V=

1 1 2 σµ

+

1 σe2

+

1 2 ση

5 / 27

Characterizing V

The firm’s information set Iit 1. Private signal: sit = ait + eit ,

eit ∼ N 0, σe2

pit ≈ ait + ηit ,

ηit ∼ N 0, ση2

2. Stock price:

 

If (ait , eit , ηit ) independent (relaxed later): V=

1 1 2 σµ

+

1 σe2

+

1 2 ση

5 / 27

Identifying information frictions The challenge: information Iit not directly observable kit =

Eit [ait ] 1−α

2 → In principle, could identify V from σmpk , σk2 , σak , etc...

But, suppose: kit =

Eit [ait + τit ] 1−α

→ Other ‘distortions’ complicate inference from these moments Our strategy: • Use correlation of stock returns with ∆kit and ∆ait (denoted ρpk , ρpa ) • Model implies tight connection between these correlations and V

6 / 27

Identifying information frictions The challenge: information Iit not directly observable kit =

Eit [ait ] 1−α

2 → In principle, could identify V from σmpk , σk2 , σak , etc...

But, suppose: kit =

Eit [ait + τit ] 1−α

→ Other ‘distortions’ complicate inference from these moments Our strategy: • Use correlation of stock returns with ∆kit and ∆ait (denoted ρpk , ρpa ) • Model implies tight connection between these correlations and V

6 / 27

Identifying information frictions The challenge: information Iit not directly observable kit =

Eit [ait ] 1−α

2 → In principle, could identify V from σmpk , σk2 , σak , etc...

But, suppose: kit =

Eit [ait + τit ] 1−α

→ Other ‘distortions’ complicate inference from these moments Our strategy: • Use correlation of stock returns with ∆kit and ∆ait (denoted ρpk , ρpa ) • Model implies tight connection between these correlations and V

6 / 27

Identifying information frictions The challenge: information Iit not directly observable kit =

Eit [ait ] 1−α

2 → In principle, could identify V from σmpk , σk2 , σak , etc...

But, suppose: kit =

Eit [ait + τit ] 1−α

→ Other ‘distortions’ complicate inference from these moments Our strategy: • Use correlation of stock returns with ∆kit and ∆ait (denoted ρpk , ρpa ) • Model implies tight connection between these correlations and V

6 / 27

Identification - our strategy

1. Directly measure ait = yit − αkit (and so, σµ2 )

1

ρpa = r 1+ ρpa



2 ση

V =1− σµ2



ρpa ρpk

2

2 σµ

noise in prices

ρpk relative to ρpa → firm uncertainty 3. Straightforward to add persistence. • E.g., with permanent shocks, ρpk − ρpa



V 2 σµ

Next: Robustness to other distortions τit , measurement error etc. 7 / 27

Identification - our strategy

1. Directly measure ait = yit − αkit (and so, σµ2 ) 2. For now, τit = 0.

1

ρpa = r 1+ ρpa



2 ση

V =1− σµ2



ρpa ρpk

2

2 σµ

noise in prices

ρpk relative to ρpa → firm uncertainty 3. Straightforward to add persistence. • E.g., with permanent shocks, ρpk − ρpa



V 2 σµ

Next: Robustness to other distortions τit , measurement error etc. 7 / 27

Identification - our strategy

1. Directly measure ait = yit − αkit (and so, σµ2 ) 2. For now, τit = 0.

1

ρpa = r 1+ ρpa



2 ση

V =1− σµ2



ρpa ρpk

2

2 σµ

noise in prices

ρpk relative to ρpa → firm uncertainty 3. Straightforward to add persistence. • E.g., with permanent shocks, ρpk − ρpa



V 2 σµ

Next: Robustness to other distortions τit , measurement error etc. 7 / 27

Identification - our strategy

1. Directly measure ait = yit − αkit (and so, σµ2 ) 2. For now, τit = 0.

1

ρpa = r 1+ ρpa



2 ση

V =1− σµ2



ρpa ρpk

2

2 σµ

noise in prices

ρpk relative to ρpa → firm uncertainty 3. Straightforward to add persistence. • E.g., with permanent shocks, ρpk − ρpa



V 2 σµ

Next: Robustness to other distortions τit , measurement error etc. 7 / 27

Identification - other frictions Distortions from correlated and uncorrelated factors (with ait ):   τit = γµit + εit , εit ∼ N 0, σε2 ⇒ kit =

(1 + γ) E [ait ] + εit 1−α

1. Only correlated distortions (γ 6= 0, σε2 = 0):  2 ρpa 2 ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk = σV2 still holds µ

2. Only uncorrelated distortions (γ = 0, σε2 6= 0):  2 σ2 ρpa 2 = σV2 − σ2ε < σV2 (conservative) ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk µ

µ

µ

Note: Results extend to permanent shocks as well

8 / 27

Identification - other frictions Distortions from correlated and uncorrelated factors (with ait ):   τit = γµit + εit , εit ∼ N 0, σε2 ⇒ kit =

(1 + γ) E [ait ] + εit 1−α

1. Only correlated distortions (γ 6= 0, σε2 = 0):  2 ρpa 2 ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk = σV2 still holds µ

2. Only uncorrelated distortions (γ = 0, σε2 6= 0):  2 σ2 ρpa 2 = σV2 − σ2ε < σV2 (conservative) ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk µ

µ

µ

Note: Results extend to permanent shocks as well

8 / 27

Identification - other frictions Distortions from correlated and uncorrelated factors (with ait ):   τit = γµit + εit , εit ∼ N 0, σε2 ⇒ kit =

(1 + γ) E [ait ] + εit 1−α

1. Only correlated distortions (γ 6= 0, σε2 = 0):  2 ρpa 2 ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk = σV2 still holds µ

2. Only uncorrelated distortions (γ = 0, σε2 6= 0):  2 σ2 ρpa 2 = σV2 − σ2ε < σV2 (conservative) ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk µ

µ

µ

Note: Results extend to permanent shocks as well

8 / 27

Identification - other frictions Distortions from correlated and uncorrelated factors (with ait ):   τit = γµit + εit , εit ∼ N 0, σε2 ⇒ kit =

(1 + γ) E [ait ] + εit 1−α

1. Only correlated distortions (γ 6= 0, σε2 = 0):  2 ρpa 2 ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk = σV2 still holds µ

2. Only uncorrelated distortions (γ = 0, σε2 6= 0):  2 σ2 ρpa 2 = σV2 − σ2ε < σV2 (conservative) ⇒ σmpk > V; but, 1 − ρpk µ

µ

µ

Note: Results extend to permanent shocks as well

8 / 27

Identification - Robustness 1. Unaffected by correlation in firm/market information

3. Robust to heterogeneity in α: kit = • Correlated:

1−α 1−αi

Eit (ait ) 1−αi

∝ Eit (ait ) ⇒ kit =

=

1−α Eit (ait ) 1−αi 1−α

(1+γ)Eit (ait ) 1−α

• Uncorrelated: does not affect (ρpk , ρpa )

9 / 27

Identification - Robustness 1. Unaffected by correlation in firm/market information 2. Ambiguous effects from measurement error ρ2pa

• In yit :

1−

2 σµ 2 +σ 2 σµ y

!

1−

>

ρ2pk

ρ2pa ρ2pk

=

V 2 σµ

!

2 σµ 2 +α2 σ 2 σµ k ! 2 −V σµ 2 −V (1−α)2 σ 2 +σµ k

ρ2pa

• In kit : 1 − ρ2pk

> 1−

3. Robust to heterogeneity in α: kit = • Correlated:

1−α 1−αi

Eit (ait ) 1−αi

∝ Eit (ait ) ⇒ kit =

ρ2pa ρ2pk

=

=

V 2 σµ

iff

V 2 σµ

<

2α−1 α2

1−α Eit (ait ) 1−αi 1−α

(1+γ)Eit (ait ) 1−α

• Uncorrelated: does not affect (ρpk , ρpa )

9 / 27

Identification - Robustness 1. Unaffected by correlation in firm/market information 2. Ambiguous effects from measurement error ρ2pa

• In yit :

1−

2 σµ 2 +σ 2 σµ y

!

1−

>

ρ2pk

ρ2pa ρ2pk

=

V 2 σµ

!

2 σµ 2 +α2 σ 2 σµ k ! 2 −V σµ 2 −V (1−α)2 σ 2 +σµ k

ρ2pa

• In kit : 1 − ρ2pk

> 1−

3. Robust to heterogeneity in α: kit = • Correlated:

1−α 1−αi

Eit (ait ) 1−αi

∝ Eit (ait ) ⇒ kit =

ρ2pa ρ2pk

=

=

V 2 σµ

iff

V 2 σµ

<

2α−1 α2

1−α Eit (ait ) 1−αi 1−α

(1+γ)Eit (ait ) 1−α

• Uncorrelated: does not affect (ρpk , ρpa )

9 / 27

Quantitative analysis: Model

1. Monopolistic competition: Yt =

 R

θ−1 θ

Ait Yit



θ θ−1

di

2 2. Production: Yit = Kitα1 Lα it

• Case 1: both factors chosen under imperfect info • Case 2: only K chosen under imperfect info, L adjusts ex-post

⇒ Preserves maxKit ΠEit [Ait ] Kitα − RKit ; with αCase 1 > αCase 2 3. AR(1) process for log Ait :

ait = ρait−1 + µit ,

µit ∼ N 0, σµ2



4. Explicit model of stock market trading ⇒ Preserves pit ≈I ait + ηit

10 / 27

Quantitative analysis: Model

1. Monopolistic competition: Yt =

 R

θ−1 θ

Ait Yit



θ θ−1

di

2 2. Production: Yit = Kitα1 Lα it

• Case 1: both factors chosen under imperfect info • Case 2: only K chosen under imperfect info, L adjusts ex-post

⇒ Preserves maxKit ΠEit [Ait ] Kitα − RKit ; with αCase 1 > αCase 2 3. AR(1) process for log Ait :

ait = ρait−1 + µit ,

µit ∼ N 0, σµ2



4. Explicit model of stock market trading ⇒ Preserves pit ≈I ait + ηit

10 / 27

The stock market Unit measure of firm equity traded by 2 type of agents 1. Investors: can purchase up to single unit at price pit 2. Noise traders: purchase random quantity Φ (zit ) , zit ∼ N 0, σz2



Information of investors: • Private signal: sijt = ait + vijt , vijt ∼ N 0, σv2



• Stock price: pit

Trading: buy asset if Eijt Πit ≥ pit Market clearing:

or

sijt > sbit

  sbit − ait 1−Φ + Φ (zit ) = 1 σν | {z } | {z } Noise traders Investors

⇒ Info in price:

sbit = ait + σν zit



ση2 = σv2 σz2



11 / 27

The stock market Unit measure of firm equity traded by 2 type of agents 1. Investors: can purchase up to single unit at price pit 2. Noise traders: purchase random quantity Φ (zit ) , zit ∼ N 0, σz2



Information of investors: • Private signal: sijt = ait + vijt , vijt ∼ N 0, σv2



• Stock price: pit

Trading: buy asset if Eijt Πit ≥ pit Market clearing:

or

sijt > sbit

  sbit − ait 1−Φ + Φ (zit ) = 1 σν | {z } | {z } Noise traders Investors

⇒ Info in price:

sbit = ait + σν zit



ση2 = σv2 σz2



11 / 27

The stock market Unit measure of firm equity traded by 2 type of agents 1. Investors: can purchase up to single unit at price pit 2. Noise traders: purchase random quantity Φ (zit ) , zit ∼ N 0, σz2



Information of investors: • Private signal: sijt = ait + vijt , vijt ∼ N 0, σv2



• Stock price: pit

Trading: buy asset if Eijt Πit ≥ pit Market clearing:

or

sijt > sbit

  sbit − ait 1−Φ + Φ (zit ) = 1 σν | {z } | {z } Noise traders Investors

⇒ Info in price:

sbit = ait + σν zit



ση2 = σv2 σz2



11 / 27

The stock market Unit measure of firm equity traded by 2 type of agents 1. Investors: can purchase up to single unit at price pit 2. Noise traders: purchase random quantity Φ (zit ) , zit ∼ N 0, σz2



Information of investors: • Private signal: sijt = ait + vijt , vijt ∼ N 0, σv2



• Stock price: pit

Trading: buy asset if Eijt Πit ≥ pit Market clearing:

or

sijt > sbit

  sbit − ait 1−Φ + Φ (zit ) = 1 σν | {z } | {z } Noise traders Investors

⇒ Info in price:

sbit = ait + σν zit



ση2 = σv2 σz2



11 / 27

Parameterization: general parameters

Parameter

Description

Target/Value

Time period

3 years

β

Discount rate

0.90

α1

Capital share

0.33

α2

Labor share

0.67

θ

Elasticity of substitution

6

• If K and L both chosen under imperfect information (case 1)



α=

θ−1 θ

= 0.83

• If only K chosen under imperfect information (case 2)



α = 0.62

12 / 27

Parameterization: country-specific parameters

Parameter

Description

ρ

Persistence of fundamentals

σµ2

Shocks to fundamentals

σe2

Firm private info

σv2

Investor private info

σz2

Noise trading

Targets )

From observed ait = revit − αkit

    ρpi ρpa    σ2 p

13 / 27

Identifying info frictions - quantitative model

1.4 1.2

0.15

Noise in prices

Posterior variance, V

0.2

0.1

0.05

1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2

0

−0.1

0 0.1 Relative correlation

0.2

0 0.2

0.3

0.4 Corr(dp,da)

0.5

0.6

Size of noise trader shock

4.5 4 ⇒ Same intuition as in simplified version: 3.5 3

• ρpa → noise in prices 2.5 • (ρpi − ρpa ) → V

2 1.5 1 0.17

0.18

0.19 0.2 0.21 Volatility of returns

0.22

14 / 27

The impact of informational frictions

V 2 σµ

V 2 σmrpk

a∗ − a

US

0.41

0.22

0.04

China

0.63

0.34

0.07

India

0.77

0.48

0.10

US

0.63

0.35

0.40

China

0.65

0.39

0.55

India

0.86

0.56

0.77

Case 2 (α = 0.62)

Case 1 (α = 0.83)

• Substantial posterior uncertainty (US firms best informed)

⇒ significant misallocation, losses in TFP and output • Effects increase with α 15 / 27

Discussion

1. Case 1 vs. Case 2 • Interpret our results as bounds; but can we say something more...? • Suggestive statistics from the US data •

2 σmrpl

= 0.57

2 σmrpk V • 2 computed σµ

with Nit ≈ 0.5 σV2 computed with Kit µ

2. Transitory vs. permanent MRPK deviations • Informational frictions → transitory deviations • US data: transitory ≈ 1/3 of total • V accounts for 60% in case 2; entirety in case 1

16 / 27

Discussion

1. Case 1 vs. Case 2 • Interpret our results as bounds; but can we say something more...? • Suggestive statistics from the US data •

2 σmrpl

= 0.57

2 σmrpk V • 2 computed σµ

with Nit ≈ 0.5 σV2 computed with Kit µ

2. Transitory vs. permanent MRPK deviations • Informational frictions → transitory deviations • US data: transitory ≈ 1/3 of total • V accounts for 60% in case 2; entirety in case 1

16 / 27

Sources of learning

Share from source ∆a

Private

Market

Case 2 US China India

5% 4% 3%

92% 96% 89%

8% 4% 11%

Case 1 US China India

23% 30% 12%

91% 96% 96%

9% 4% 4%

1. Significant learning ⇒ significant aggregate gains 2. Learning primarily from private sources Interpretation? Manager skill/incentives, info collection/processing, etc... 3. Only small role for market-generated info ⇐ just too much noise in prices 17 / 27

Effect of US information structure

Case 2

Case 1

∆a

∆a

Market Information China India

1% 1%

2% 4%

Private Information China India

3% 5%

6% 26%

Shocks China India

1% 2%

10% 20%

1. Gains from US private info > US market info 2. Differences in fundamentals → differential impact of friction

18 / 27

Robustness: correlated information

Are we picking up correlation between firm and investors’ signals ? • Correlated errors → ↑ ρpk →↑ V? • Strategy: Re-estimate V assuming sijt = sit + vijt V 2 σµ

V 2 σµ

= ait + eit + vijt

baseline

a∗ − a

a∗ − a baseline

Case 2 (α = 0.62) US

0.41

0.41

0.040

0.040

China

0.58

0.63

0.070

0.075

India

0.68

0.77

0.100

0.114

⇒ Results almost identical to baseline !

19 / 27

Robustness: correlated information

Are we picking up correlation between firm and investors’ signals ? • Correlated errors → ↑ ρpk →↑ V? • Strategy: Re-estimate V assuming sijt = sit + vijt V 2 σµ

V 2 σµ

= ait + eit + vijt

baseline

a∗ − a

a∗ − a baseline

Case 2 (α = 0.62) US

0.41

0.41

0.040

0.040

China

0.58

0.63

0.070

0.075

India

0.68

0.77

0.100

0.114

⇒ Results almost identical to baseline !

19 / 27

Robustness: measurement error in revenues What if observed

yˆit = yit + yit

2 yit ∼ N(0, σy )?

2 • σy → ↓ ρpa →↑ V

• Strategy: Re-estimate V with corrected moments

Baseline

2 = 10% σ 2 (∆y ) σy

2 = 25% σ 2 (∆y ) σy

V

V 2 σµ

V

V 2 σµ

V

V 2 σµ

Case 2 US China India

0.08 0.16 0.22

0.41 0.63 0.77

0.05 0.14 0.17

0.28 0.58 0.65

0.01 0.10 0.14

0.07 0.51 0.61

Case 1 US China India

0.13 0.18 0.26

0.63 0.65 0.86

0.12 0.18 0.25

0.62 0.69 0.91

0.07 0.17 0.22

0.42 0.73 0.89

⇒ Upward bias in V, but cross-country results biased downward. 20 / 27

Robustness: measurement error in revenues What if observed

yˆit = yit + yit

2 yit ∼ N(0, σy )?

2 • σy → ↓ ρpa →↑ V

• Strategy: Re-estimate V with corrected moments

Baseline

2 = 10% σ 2 (∆y ) σy

2 = 25% σ 2 (∆y ) σy

V

V 2 σµ

V

V 2 σµ

V

V 2 σµ

Case 2 US China India

0.08 0.16 0.22

0.41 0.63 0.77

0.05 0.14 0.17

0.28 0.58 0.65

0.01 0.10 0.14

0.07 0.51 0.61

Case 1 US China India

0.13 0.18 0.26

0.63 0.65 0.86

0.12 0.18 0.25

0.62 0.69 0.91

0.07 0.17 0.22

0.42 0.73 0.89

⇒ Upward bias in V, but cross-country results biased downward. 20 / 27

Robustness: measurement error in capital What if observed

kˆit = kit + kit

2 kit ∼ N(0, σk )?

2 • σk → ↓ ρpa , ρpk → V ?

• Strategy: Re-estimate V with corrected moments Baseline

2 = 10% σ 2 (∆y ) σk

V

V 2 σµ

V

V 2 σµ

Case 2 US China India

0.08 0.16 0.22

0.41 0.63 0.77

0.11 0.17 0.22

0.59 0.69 0.79

Case 1 US China India

0.13 0.18 0.26

0.63 0.65 0.86

0.17 0.21 0.27

0.85 0.79 0.95

⇒ Our approach underestimates uncertainty ! 21 / 27

Robustness: measurement error in capital What if observed

kˆit = kit + kit

2 kit ∼ N(0, σk )?

2 • σk → ↓ ρpa , ρpk → V ?

• Strategy: Re-estimate V with corrected moments Baseline

2 = 10% σ 2 (∆y ) σk

V

V 2 σµ

V

V 2 σµ

Case 2 US China India

0.08 0.16 0.22

0.41 0.63 0.77

0.11 0.17 0.22

0.59 0.69 0.79

Case 1 US China India

0.13 0.18 0.26

0.63 0.65 0.86

0.17 0.21 0.27

0.85 0.79 0.95

⇒ Our approach underestimates uncertainty ! 21 / 27

Robustness: adjustment costs

Are we re-labeling adjustment costs as info frictions ? • Strategy: Simulate moments under full-info and quadratic adj. costs • Estimate V using these moments

Adj. Cost V

Baseline V

US

0.03

0.08

China

0.06

0.16

India

0.08

0.22

• V (and agg effects) about 1/3 of baseline estimates

⇒ Unlikely that adj. costs are driving our estimates

22 / 27

Robustness: adjustment costs

Are we re-labeling adjustment costs as info frictions ? • Strategy: Simulate moments under full-info and quadratic adj. costs • Estimate V using these moments

Adj. Cost V

Baseline V

US

0.03

0.08

China

0.06

0.16

India

0.08

0.22

• V (and agg effects) about 1/3 of baseline estimates

⇒ Unlikely that adj. costs are driving our estimates

22 / 27

Robustness: financial frictions

Are we picking up financing-related effects of stock prices ? • Stock prices ↑ → Funding constraints ↓ → ρpk ↑ → V ↑? • Strategy: Estimate V for ‘unconstrained’ firms Baseline

US China India

Small Issuers

ρpi

ρpa

V 2 σµ

0.23 0.16 0.25

0.18 0.06 0.08

0.41 0.63 0.77

ρpi 0.15 0.18 0.20

Top Quartile

ρpa

V 2 σµ

ρpi

ρpa

V 2 σµ

0.06 0.06 0.08

0.58 0.60 0.62

0.19 0.24 0.25

0.14 0.05 0.07

0.46 0.76 0.93

⇒ Unlikely that the financing channel is driving our results

23 / 27

Robustness: financial frictions

Are we picking up financing-related effects of stock prices ? • Stock prices ↑ → Funding constraints ↓ → ρpk ↑ → V ↑? • Strategy: Estimate V for ‘unconstrained’ firms Baseline

US China India

Small Issuers

ρpi

ρpa

V 2 σµ

0.23 0.16 0.25

0.18 0.06 0.08

0.41 0.63 0.77

ρpi 0.15 0.18 0.20

Top Quartile

ρpa

V 2 σµ

ρpi

ρpa

V 2 σµ

0.06 0.06 0.08

0.58 0.60 0.62

0.19 0.24 0.25

0.14 0.05 0.07

0.46 0.76 0.93

⇒ Unlikely that the financing channel is driving our results

23 / 27

Other evidence: Cross-section • Compute V by sector in the US • Compare to mean squared error in firm revenue forecasts

24 / 27

Other evidence: Cross-section • Compute V by sector in the US • Compare to mean squared error in firm revenue forecasts

0.09

Trans. & PU

0.08 Mfg.

0.07 0.06

Const.

V

0.05 FIRE

Services

0.04 0.03 Ret. Trade 0.02 Whl. Trade

0.01 0 0

0.002

0.004

0.006 0.008 0.01 Forecast Dispersion

0.012

0.014

0.016

24 / 27

Other evidence: Time series • Compute V over time in the US • Compare to other indicators of micro uncertainty

25 / 27

Other evidence: Time series • Compute V over time in the US • Compare to other indicators of micro uncertainty

Deviations from Trend

2

1

0

−1 V Jurado et. al. −2 1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

Year

Source: Jurado, Ludvigson and Ng, ”Measuring Uncertainty”, AER

25 / 27

Related literature Misallocation • Hsieh and Klenow (09), Restuccia and Rogerson (08), Bartelsman et.

al.(13)... • Financial frictions: Buera, Kaboski and Shin (11), Midrigan and Xu (13),... • Adjustment costs: Asker, Collard-Wexler and De Loecker (13) • Information frictions: Jovanovic (13)

Stock price informativeness • Morck, Yeung and Yu (00), Durnev, Yeung and Zarowin (03),...

The “feedback” effect (Bond, Edmans and Goldstein (12)) • Investment: Chen, Goldstein and Jiang (07), Bakke and Whited (10),

Morck, Schleifer and Vishny (90) • R&D spending: Bai, Philippon and Savov (13) • Mergers and acquisitions: Luo (05) 26 / 27

Conclusion

Theory linking micro uncertainty to misallocation and aggregates • Substantial uncertainty and associated aggregate losses • Limited informational role for stock markets • Significant role for private learning ⇒ drives cross-country differences

Where next? • Entry/exit • Other frictions...

27 / 27

Full-info TFP Simplified model: a∗ = General model: a∗ = simple model

general model

1 2



1 σµ2 21−α

θ θ−1



σa2 1−α

Identification with iid shocks

ρpa = r

1 1+

(& in σv σz ) σv2 σz2 2 σµ

ρpk = r 1+ σp2 =



1−β 1−α

1 

σv2 σz2 2 σµ

2

1−

V 2 σµ

2 2 σ + 1  z  1 σµ2 1 2 ρ2pa σ z + ρ2

(% in V)



pa

ident



(% in σz )

Identification with permanent shocks

V ρpk − ρpa 1 σµ = where η = σµ2 η 1 − α σp  1 − η2 η σv2 σz2 + = −1 σµ2 ρpa 2ρ2pa σz2 + 1 σz2 ident

+1+

σv2 σz2 2 σµ

=

1 η

Step 1. cov (p, k) = cov (p, a). • follows from k = E (a|p, si ) • and since we can write a = E (a|p, si ) + ε • cov (a, p) = cov (E (a|p, si ) , p) + cov (ε, p) = cov (k, p) .

Step 2. divide both sides by σa σp so we get [cov (p, k)]2 = ρ (p, a)2 (σa σp )2

(1)

Step 3. By the law of total covariance, σa2 = σk2 + V so σk2 V =1− 2 σa2 σa Substituting (2) in (1) we get   2  ρ (p, a) V 1− 2 = ρ (p, k) σa identical to our identification equation.

ident

(2)

Investment-Q regressions Reduced-form representation (with iid shocks): ∆kit = λ1 (∆µit + ∆eit ) + λ2 ∆pit Use model to derive: λ2 ∝

(1 + γ)V ση2

Intuition: λ2 could be large because of • high uncertainty (high V ) OR • more information prices (low ση2 ) OR • correlated distortions (high γ)

Also, consistency of λ2 requires ∆eit ⊥ ∆µit , ∆pit • Correlated signals → ∆eit correlated with ∆pit → endogeneity ident

Data and parameter values

Target moments

Parameters

ρpi

ρpa

σp2

Case 2 US China India

0.23 0.16 0.25

0.18 0.06 0.08

0.23 0.14 0.23

0.92 0.78 0.93

0.45 0.51 0.53

0.39 0.67 1.04

0.37 0.74 0.69

3.50 4.24 4.36

Case 1 US China India

0.24 0.15 0.26

0.10 0.02 0.00

0.23 0.14 0.22

0.88 0.75 0.88

0.46 0.53 0.55

0.63 0.74 1.39

0.65 1.18 1.69

3.16 3.14 4.14

ρ

σµ

σe

σv

σz

Data source: Compustat NA and Compustat Global.

• Cross-country variation in moments ⇒ variation in parameters • US: less fundamental uncertainty, better private info, less noise in markets results

Full-information adjustment cost model • Value function

    V A˜it , Kit−1 = max G A˜it Kitα˜ − Iit − H (Iit , Kit−1 ) + βEV A˜it+1 , Kit Kit ,Nit

where Iit = Kit − (1 − δ) Kit−1

and

H (Iit , Kit−1 ) = ζKit−1

˜it , Kit in GE • Solve numerically for joint distribution of A • Target ρpa , σp2 , σk2 to estimate (σv2 , σz2 , ζ)



• Simulate data to compute ρpi Back



Iit Kit−1

2

Information, Misallocation and Aggregate Productivity

Quantify frictions using stock market/production data in US, China, India. 2. What we find ...... Unlikely that the financing channel is driving our results. 23 / 27 ...

346KB Sizes 2 Downloads 266 Views

Recommend Documents

Misallocation and Productivity 1 Misallocation and ...
We can show that the equilibrium allocation without distortions is efficient. ... If we had data on the productivity of establishments, and their demands of factors, ...

Capital Reallocation and Aggregate Productivity
Jun 14, 2016 - model with dispersion shocks alone accounts for nearly 85% of the time .... elements: A is aggregate TFP and K is the aggregate stock of capital. ... focus on business cycle, not reallocation moments. 4 .... For the dynamic program of

Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium
Apr 7, 2018 - prices are used to “estimate” marginal products, cost, and utilities. • this is important because it means that the underlying output elasticities ...

Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium
Apr 7, 2018 - Davis et al. (2007), Gordon (2012), Neiman and Karabarbounis (2014), Elsby et al. (2013), Piketty and Zucman (2014), Baqaee (2015), Barkai (2016),. Rognlie (2016), Koh et al. (2016), Gutiérrez and ...... Heterogeneous mark-ups, growth

online appendix: information, misallocation and ...
Variances (of growth rates):. 2 p. ⌘ Var (pit pit1. )=2 2⇠2. 2. µ + 2 v. 2 z. = 2 2⇠2 ✓1 + 2 v. 2 z. 2. µ ◇ 2 u. 2 k. ⌘ Var (kit kit1) = h2(1 + 2). 2. 2. µ + 2. 1. 2 e + 2. 2. 2 v. 2 zi✓ 1. 1. ↵◇. 2. = 2⇣. 1 σ2 e. + 1 σ2 v σ

Long Run Productivity Risk and Aggregate Investment
Apr 24, 2013 - rate shocks are the drivers of business cycles, then matching the joint be- havior of consumption, investment, ..... 6The estimate of the total factor productivity process includes both growth and level components together, i.e. .....

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation - Editorial Express
The smaller is the firm's discount factor the more likely are firing costs ...... cases is a dichotomous aggregation of the objects of controversy in red code versus ...

MISALLOCATION, EDUCATION EXPANSION AND WAGE INEQUALITY
Jan 2, 2016 - results of this study and jointly with the data analysis from the CPS, ..... “Computerisation and Wage Dispersion: An Analytical Reinterpretation.

MISALLOCATION, EDUCATION EXPANSION AND WAGE INEQUALITY
Jan 2, 2016 - understanding the effects of technical change on inequality, this ... 2The terms education, college and skill premium are used interchangeably.

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation - Ridge
the Italian Social Security Institute (INPS) and from CERVED.2. This information allows me ...... be smaller, for example if they have a legal office within the firm.

trade and productivity - CREI
institutional quality as well as geography and take into account the ... financial support from the CREI and CREA research institutes, the European Fund for .... Purchasing power parity (PPP) GDP differs from GDP in that the production of each good i

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation - Editorial Express
sheets of the universe of Italian limited companies. ... Moreover, the effects found are smaller in size for older firms, supporting a .... to get rid of these workers, but this possibility is discounted since hiring occurs in good .... tal accountin

trade and productivity - CREI
Our empirical approach accounts for the endogeneity of trade and ... of openness as a measure of trade can be illustrated using a small open economies.

Aggregate Uncertainty.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying.

05 Moscoso Boedo - Misallocation, Informality and Human Capital ...
05 Moscoso Boedo - Misallocation, Informality and Human Capital.pdf. 05 Moscoso Boedo - Misallocation, Informality and Human Capital.pdf. Open. Extract.

Capital Controls and Misallocation in the Market for Risk: Bank ...
Second, setting capital controls can mitigate the Central Bank's balance sheet losses that emerge from managing exchange rates. In an environment that is similar to the one studied in this paper,. Amador et al. (2016) show that if a country experienc

Choice under aggregate uncertainty
Since sα is chosen uniformly, individual outcomes are identically distributed, but .... Definition 2 A utility U is indifferent to aggregate uncertainty if U(P) = U(Q) for any two lotteries P, ...... Storage for good times and bad: Of squirrels and

R&D and Aggregate Fluctuations
Jan 16, 2012 - Investment in research and development (henceforth R&D) as well as employment in the ... Physical capital is mobile between sectors but with a cost. .... (2000), argues that patent applications are usually taken early ... average 2.7 p

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment
Jun 3, 2016 - Take λ ∈ [0,1] such that [T (J)] (z,uλ) and EJ (z′,u′ λ) are differentiable in λ and compute d dλ. [T (J)] (z,uλ) = C0 + β (C1 + C2 + C3) where.

Aggregate Turnover and Margin Scheme.pdf
Turnover, in common parlance, is the total volume of a business. The term 'aggregate turnover' ... composition levy. Let us dissect the definition in small parts to.

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment
Jun 3, 2016 - 2 such that u1 ⩽ u2,. |J (z,u2) − J (z,u1)| ⩽ Ju |u2 − u1|. Definition 3. Let Ψ : (J, z, u, θ) ∈ B (Ω) × [z,z] × [0,1 − s] × R+ −→ R the function such that.

Finance and Misallocation: Evidence from Plant-Level ...
tions using producer-level data for several countries that differ in the degree of financial ... Keywords: productivity, technology adoption, misallocation, finance frictions. .... In our empirical analysis we associate the modern sector with the off

Finance and Misallocation: Evidence from Plant-Level ...
relatively high quality micro-level data, but also because the two differ .... productivity switch occupations and these account for too small a share of .... first solve the entrepreneur's profit maximization problem and then its consumption-savings

Sentiments and Aggregate Demand Fluctuations
We find that despite the lack of any externalities or nonconvexities in tech- nology or preferences .... functions for each differentiated good based on their sentiments and the id- iosyncratic .... all propositions that follow without loss of genera