September 2013

Intangible Investment and Ramsey Capital Taxation Supplementary Online Appendix Juan C. Conesa Stony Brook University

Begoña Domínguez University of Queensland

ABSTRACT __________________________________________________________________________________ This Appendix derives the implementability condition presented in the main text, shows the first order conditions of the Ramsey problem and the details of the Proof of Proposition 1. __________________________________________________________________________________

1

1

1. The implementability condition

2

First, plugging dividend/equity distribution into the household’s budget constraint to get ct + bt +1 = (1 − τ tn ) wt nt + (1 + rt b )bt

3

+ (1 − τ td ) (1 − τ tc )  f ( km ,t , ku ,t , nt ) − xu ,t − wt nt  + τ tcδ m km ,t − xm ,t  .  

(A1)

4

Then equation (A1) is multiplied by pt = β t u1,t , the accumulation constraint for tangible capital,

5

equation (1) in the main text, by χ tm = (1 − τ td ) pt

6

χ tu = (1 − τ td )(1 − τ tc ) pt ∞

∑ p c + b t

7

1 . The resulting equations are added together and over time to obtain I1,ut

− (1 − τ tn ) wt nt − (1 − τ td ) (1 − τ tc )  f ( km ,t , ku ,t , nt ) − wt nt − xu ,t  + τ tcδ m km,t − xm,t  − (1 + rt b )bt  

t +1

t

1 , and the one for intangible capital, equation (2), by I1,mt

t=0





+ ∑ χ tm km ,t +1 − (1 − δ m ) km ,t − I m ( xm ,t , em,t ) + ∑ χ tu ku ,t +1 − (1 − δ u ) ku ,t − I u ( xu ,t , eu ,t ) = 0.

(

)

t=0

8 9

(

)

t=0

Substituting pt , χtm , and χ tu into the above equation, using the homogeneity of degree one in the final good’s production function and that wages equal the marginal productivity of labor, we obtain ∞

∑  β u

c − β t u1,t (1 − τ tn ) f3,t nt − u1,t (1 − τ td ) (1 − τ tc )  f1,t k m,t + f 2,t ku ,t − xu ,t  + τ tcδ m km,t − xm ,t   

t

1,t t

t=0

10





t=0

t=0

+ ∑ β t u1,t bt +1 − (1 + rt b )bt  + ∑ (1 − τ td ) u1,t ∞

+ ∑ (1 − τ td )(1 − τ tc ) u1,t t=0

11

1 km,t +1 − (1 − δ m ) km ,t − I m ( xm,t , em,t ) m I1,t

(

)

1 ku ,t +1 − (1 − δ u ) ku ,t − I u ( xu ,t , eu ,t ) = 0. u I1,t

(

)

Rearranging, the above equation becomes   Im   Iu  n d d c u1,t ct − u1,t (1 − τ t ) f3,t nt − u1,t (1 − τ t )  m − xm,t  − u1,t (1 − τ t )(1 − τ t )  u − xu ,t   t=0   I1,t   I1,t   ∞ ∞  1   1  + ∑ β t u1,t bt +1 − (1 + rt b )bt  + ∑ β t u1,t (1 − τ td )  m km,t +1 −  (1 − τ tc ) ( f1,t − δ m ) + δ m + (1 − δ m ) m  km,t   I1,t  t=0 t=0  I1,t   ∞

∑β

12

t

∞  1  1 + ∑ β t u1,t (1 − τ td )(1 − τ tc )  u ku ,t +1 −  f 2,t + (1 − δ u ) u  I1,t t=0  I1,t 

   ku ,t  = 0.  

2

1

Substituting in the tax rates through the competitive equilibrium conditions (7)-(9), and imposing

2

the first order conditions for government bonds u1,t = β u1,t +1 (1 + rt b+1 ), and for tangible and intangible

3

capital, equations (10)-(11) in the main text, we find

  Im  Iu I1,mt  I1,ut   β u1,t ct − u2,t nt − u2,t  m − xm,t m  − u2,t  u − xu ,t u   = u1,0 (1 + r0b )b0 + ∑ I 2,t  I 2,t   t=0   I 2,t  I 2,t   1  1  u1,0 (1 − τ 0d )  (1 − τ 0c ) ( f1,0 − δ m ) + δ m + (1 − δ m ) m  km ,0 + u1,0 (1 − τ 0d )(1 − τ 0c )  f 2,0 + (1 − δ u ) u  ku ,0 .   I1,0  I1,0    ∞

t

4

Finally, noting that e j ,t =

5

6

m u2,0 I1,0

(1 − τ ) = u d 0

1,0

7

m I 2,0

, and (1 − τ

d 0

j I j I1,t x j ,t , from the homogeneity of the investment functions, and − I 2,j t I 2,j t

u u2,0 I1,0

)(1 − τ ) = u c 0

1,0

u I 2,0

, from equations (8) and (9), the implementability

condition becomes ∞

∑β

t

u1,t ct − u2,t ( nt + em ,t + eu ,t )  = u1,0 (1 + r0b )b0 +  

t=0

8

u m   u2,0  m  I1,0 I 2,0 u I f 1 km,0 + 2,0 I u f + (1 − δ u ) ) ku ,0 . − + + − δ δ δ   ( ) ( ) 1,0 m m m m  1,0  u m u ( 1,0 2,0  I 2,0   I 2,0 I1,0 I 2,0  

9 10

2. The first order conditions for the Ramsey problem

11

The first order conditions for the Ramsey problem presented in the main text are as follows:

12

[ ct ] :

β t u1,t + λ ( u1,t + ct u11,t )  = β t µt ,

[ nt ] :

β t u2,t + λ ( u2,t − ( nt + em,t + eu ,t ) u22,t )  = β t f3,t µt +

∂Θ , ∂nt

∂Θ em ,t  : β t u2,t + λ u2,t − ( nt + em ,t + eu ,t ) u22,t  = β t χ tmG I 2,mt + ,   ∂em,t

(

)

∂Θ eu ,t  : β t u2,t + λ u2,t − ( nt + em ,t + eu ,t ) u22,t  = β t χ tuG I 2,u t + ,   ∂eu ,t

(

)

∂Θ  xm,t  : β t χ tmG I1,mt + = β t µt , ∂xm,t

3

∂Θ  xu ,t  : β t χtuG I1,ut + = β t µt , ∂xu ,t

1

∂Θ  km ,t +1  : β t χtmG = β t +1µt +1 f1,t +1 + β t +1χ tmG , +1 (1 − δ m ) + ∂k m ,t +1

∂Θ  ku ,t +1  : β t χtuG = β t +1µt +1 f 2,t +1 + β t +1 χtuG , +1 (1 − δ u ) + ∂k u ,t +1

2

with λ , µt , χ tmG , and χ tuG denoting the multipliers on the implementability condition, resource

3

constraint, and tangible and intangible capital accumulation constraints, (1) and (2), respectively, where

4

decentralization constraints and the real value of the initial wealth have been condensed in

5

u m     u2,0  m  I1,0 I 2,0 u b u  Θ = − u1,0 (1 + r0 ) b0 + m  I1,0  u m ( f1,0 − δ m ) + δ m  + (1 − δ m )  km ,0 + 2,0 I f + − k 1 δ ( ) ( )  1,0 2,0 u u ,0 u  I 2,0   I 2,0 I1,0 I 2,0    

  u ∞   u  Iu Im  u   u + ∑ β t θtm  2,mt − β  I1,mt +1  1,u t +1 2,mt +1 ( f1,t +1 − δ m ) + δ m  + (1 − δ m )  2,mt +1  +θtu  2,u t − β ( I1,ut +1 f 2,t +1 + (1 − δ u ) ) 2,u t +1   . I  I   I 2,t +1  I 2,t +1   t =0   I 2,t  2,t +1 I1,t +1   2,t   

6 7

Note that partial derivatives with respect to Θ are zero in the long run because decentralization

8

constraints are not binding in the limit. This is consistent with the results of Proposition 1.

9 10

3. Proof of Proposition 1

11

The proof reproduces the procedure of Albanesi and Armenter (2007) in our setup.1 We show that there

12

exists a welfare improving perturbation to any candidate policy that at steady state features (i) dividend

13

tax rates different from labor tax rates and/or (ii) corporate taxes different from zero. Therefore, by

14

contradiction, the optimal corporate tax is zero and optimal dividend and labor tax rates are equal at

15

steady state.

16

The perturbation, that is considered, is a tax reform that takes place when the economy under the

17

candidate policy is at steady state. Steady-state variables are denoted with superscript ss. Any tax reform

18

to our candidate policy must imply an allocation that is feasible (satisfying resource and capital

1

Albanesi and Armenter (2007) illustrates the general results published in Albanesi and Armenter (2012).

4

1

accumulation constraints) and admissible (satisfying implementability and decentralization conditions).

2

For utility functions that are not logarithmic in consumption, the perturbation involves a tax reform that

3

affects labor reallocation in a given period and does not affect any other periods. For log utilities, since

4

income and substitution effects cancel out, one-period reforms cannot deliver labor reallocation. Then,

5

for this case, the proof considers a tax reform across two periods. Below, the proof for utilities that are

6

non-logarithmic in consumption is presented first and then followed by the one for log utilities.

7 8

3.1. Non-logarithmic utility functions

9

Let’s then consider non-log utilities and a reform that only affects period t. In what follows, we present

10

how the tax reform affects the allocation, through the adjustment in feasibility and admissibility

11

conditions, and then the taxes that decentralize that allocation. The implementability condition requires

12

d ( nt + em,t + eu ,t ) = Ψdct , where Ψ solves d ct u1,t − u2,t ( nt + em,t + eu ,t )  = 0, so that equilibrium is

13

restored within the same period. For our utility function, equation (12) in the main text, Ψ = u1,ss (1 − σ ) .

14

The change in resources is obtained from the derived variation in the capital accumulation constraints

15

(1) and (2), implying I1,mss dxm,t + I 2,mss dem,t = 0 and I1,uss dxu ,t + I 2,u ss deu ,t = 0 as both tangible and intangible

16

capital are not affected. Using the resource constraint ( dct + dxm,t + dxu ,t = f 3, ss dnt ), plugging in the

17

changes in total labor and in resources and using the equilibrium conditions (7)-(9), it follows that

18

u2, ss  1  1 + χ   

  1 − τ ssn 1 − Ψ f dc = (   3, ss ) t d   1 − τ ss

     1 − τ ssn    − 1 f de + − 1 f 3, ss deu ,t .   3, ss m ,t  d c    τ τ 1 − 1 − ( )( )   ss ss   

(

(A2)

)

19

The implied welfare change is β t u1,ss dct − u2, ss d ( nt + em ,t + eu ,t ) = β t ( u1, ss − Ψu2, ss ) dct . It is easy to

20

show that ( u1,ss − Ψu2, ss ) > 0 always, and (1 − Ψf3, ss ) > 0 at the optimum. Therefore, if τ ssn ≠ τ ssd and/or

21

τ ssc ≠ 0, a policy that reallocates the time devoted to labor/effort can potentially increase welfare. 5

1

So far, feasibility and the implementability condition have been imposed. Admissibility also

2

requires the decentralization constraints to hold. As we consider a reform that affects only period t,

3

satisfying the decentralization constraints means that

4

sixth equations in the Ramsey problem stated in the main text) are constant or, in terms of adjustment, u22, ss

5

u2, ss u22, ss

6

7

8 9

u2, ss m  I 21, ss

with D1 =  

m 1, ss

 I



u2,t I

m 2,t

and

u2,t I 2,u t

(the left-hand-side of the fifth and

d ( nt + em ,t + eu ,t ) = D1dem,t ,

(A3)

d ( nt + em ,t + eu ,t ) = D2 deu ,t ,

(A4)

m u u   I 21, I 22, I 22, ss ss ss and D > 0 = −   u 2 u I 2,mss  I I 2, ss  1, ss

  > 0 constant. 

Using (A2)-(A4), a feasible and admissible reform that increases consumption by dct = ε can be written in terms of labor reallocation as deu ,t = Z ε ,

10

dem ,t =

D2 Zε , D1

  D u dnt = −   1 − 2, ss D1  2 + 1 Z ε .   u22, ss  D1    

11

with Z =

(1 − Ψf ) 3, ss

  1 − τ n      1 − τ ssn D2   ss        − 1 f + − 1 f   3, ss 3, ss D1   (1 − τ ssd )(1 − τ ssc )     1 − τ ssd        

. Let’s consider situations close to the

12

optimum so that (1 − Ψf 3, ss ) > 0. If τ ssd > τ ssn and/or τ ssc > 0, then Z > 0. Then the above require an

13

increase in both types of effort, in intangibles and in tangibles, and a decrease in labor. If, instead,

14

τ ssd < τ ssn and/or τ ssc < 0, then Z < 0, and the opposite movement in labor activities is required. Such a

15

reform can be decentralized using (7)-(9) as follows:

16

  D2   f33,ss   u2,ss 1 n  d τ = − D + 1 − D + 1 Z  ε ,    t  3 f3, ss   u22, ss 1  D1   (1 − τ ssn )    

(A5) 6

1

 D2 u 1 d d τ = − Z − 11, ss  D4 t d D1 u1, ss (1 − τ ss ) 

2

 u 1 1 dτ td + dτ tc = −  D5 Z − 11, ss d c  u1, ss (1 − τ ss ) (1 − τ ss ) 

3

  ε , 

(A6)

  ε , 

(A7)

m m u u  m   u    where D3 = −  u11,ss + Ψ u22,ss  , D4 =  I12,m ss − I11,mss I 2,mss  > 0, and D5 =  I12,u ss − I11,u ss I 2,u ss  > 0 are constant. The      

 u1, ss

u2, ss 

 I1,ss

I1,ss I1, ss 

 I1, ss

I1,ss I1,ss 

4

sign of D3 is ambiguous. Then if τ ssd > τ ssn and/or τ ssc > 0, a welfare improving perturbation involves a

5

decrease in dividend taxes and changes in labor and corporate taxes (of ambiguous sign) according to

6

(A5)-(A7). If, instead, τ ssd < τ ssn and/or τ ssc < 0, then the opposite movement in taxes is required. But the

7

welfare improving reform exists and in turn implies that, at steady state, optimal corporate taxes are zero

8

and the optimal levels of dividend and labor taxes coincide at steady state. Moreover, manipulating the

9

first order conditions of the Ramsey problem, optimal dividend and labor tax rates at steady state are

10

 css u11, ss u − ( nss + em , ss + eu , ss ) 22, ss u1, ss u2, ss 

λ  − τ ssd * = τ ssn* =

 u 1 + λ 1 − ( nss + em, ss + eu , ss ) 22, ss  u2, ss 

  

  ,

11

which are clearly positive. Note that λ denotes the multiplier on the implementability condition, which

12

is strictly positive. For our function (12), the tax rate becomes 

λ σ +

13

τ ssd * = τ ssn* =



1

χ 

 1 1 + λ 1 +   χ

.

14 15

3.2. Logarithmic utility functions

16

For utility functions that are logarithmic in consumption, it follows that Ψ = 0, which together with the

17

required change in the decentralization constraints (A3)-(A4), imply no labor/effort reallocation

18

dnt = dem ,t = deu ,t = 0. Therefore there is not a welfare improving perturbation that affects only one 7

1

period. Then, policy reforms that involve periods t and t+1 and no other periods are considered. The

2

proof proceeds as in the case of non-log utility functions. We first present the tax reform through the

3

required adjustment in terms of allocation and then show the taxes that decentralize that allocation.

4

u2,t +1

For period t+1,

I

m 2,t +1

=

u2, ss I

m 2, ss

and

u2,t +1 I

u2, ss

=

u 2,t +1

must hold to meet the decentralization constraints at

I 2,u ss

5

t+2. Then conditions (A2)-(A3) are satisfied at period t+1, which together with the implementability

6

condition d ( nt +1 + dem,t +1 + deu ,t +1 ) = 0, imply that dnt +1 = dem,t +1 = deu ,t +1 = 0. For date t, d ( nt + dem,t + deu ,t ) = 0

7

is satisfied, as well as the following decentralization constraints:

8

9

10 11 12

13 14 15 16

 m  I1,ut +1 I 2,mt +1  u2, ss  f = β  I1,t +1  u − δ + δ + 1 − δ ,  ( ) ( )  1, t + 1 m m m m     I 2,mss  I 2,t +1 I1,t +1   

u2,t I 2,mt u2,t I

u 2,t

= β ( I1,ut +1 f 2,t +1 + (1 − δ u ) )

u2, ss I 2,u ss

(A8)

(A9)

.

Using feasibility (resource and accumulation constraints (1) and (2)) and d ( nt + dem,t + deu ,t ) = 0 , any change affecting period t can be summarized in

dct +

1 I1,mss

dkm,t +1 +

1 I1,uss

 Im   Iu  dku ,t +1 =  2,mss − f3,ss  dem,t +  2,u ss − f3,ss  deu ,t . I     1, ss   I1,ss 

As there is no variation in any labor activity, feasibility requires dct +1 =  I1,mss f1, ss + (1 − δ m ) 

1 m 1, ss

I

dkm ,t +1 +  I1,uss f 2, ss + (1 − δ u ) 

1 I1,uss

dku ,t +1 ,

in period t+1. Adding up the changes in consumption in periods t and t+1 and rearranging, it follows dct + β dct +1 = βτ

c ss

(f

1, ss

 (1 − τ ssn )    1 − τ ssn ) (    − δ m ) dk m ,t +1 +  − 1 f de + − 1 f de . (A10)  (1 − τ ssd )  3, ss m ,t  (1 − τ ssd )(1 − τ ssc )  3, ss u ,t    

17

The implied welfare change is β t u1, ss ( dct + β dct +1 ) . Then, if τ ssn ≠ τ ssd , and/or τ ssc ≠ 0, a policy reform that

18

affects tangible capital and/or reallocates the time devoted to labor/effort could increase welfare. Is there

19

an admissible policy that achieves that?

8

1

We have three taxes in period t and another three in t+1. For period t+1, our policy is similar to

2

(A5)-(A7) but taking into account that effort/labor cannot be reallocated while consumption can still

3

adjust. This implies a variation in labor taxes as in

4

according to

5

I

m 2, t +1 m 1,t +1

I

=

I

u 2,t +1 u 1,t +1

I

1 dτ tn+1 = − D3 dct +1 a change in dividend taxes (1 − τ ssn )

u 1 dτ td+1 = 11, ss dct +1 , and no movement in corporate taxes. The latter means d u1, ss (1 − τ ss )

, which after rearranging becomes dku ,t +1

m m  I 21,  1 I11, ss ss  m − m  m (1 − δ m ) I I1, ss  I1, ss = D6 dk m,t +1 , with D6 =  2, ss > 0. u u  I 21, ss I11,  1 ss  m − u  u (1 − δ u )  I 2, ss I1, ss  I1, ss

6

That is, tangible and intangible capital move in the same direction. Then the variation in consumption at

7

  1 1 t+1 can be written as dct +1 = Ωdkm ,t +1 , with Ω =   I1,mss f1,ss + (1 − δ m )  m +  I1,u ss f 2,ss + (1 − δ u )  u D6  > 0. I1, ss I1, ss  

8

Differentiating the decentralization constraints (A8)-(A9) and rearranging results in

9

m m  I 21, I 22, ss ss  m − m I I 2, ss  1, ss

  dem ,t = D7 dk m ,t +1 , 

(A11)

10

u u  I 21, I 22, ss ss  u − u I 2, ss  I1, ss

  deu ,t = D8 dkm,t +1 , 

(A12)

11

  Im Im where D7 =  β I1,mss (1 − τ ssc ) f12, ss D6 + β I1,mss (1 − τ ssc ) f11, ss − β 11,mss (1 − τ ssc ) ( f1, ss − δ m ) + δ m  (1 − δ m ) + m 21, ssm  ,  I1, ss I 2, ss I1, ss  

12

u u  u  u I11, I 21, ss and D8 =  β I1, ss f 21, ss +  β I1, ss f 22, ss − β u f 2, ss (1 − δ u ) + u ssu   I1, ss I 2, ss I1, ss  

   D6  .  

13

Let’s consider a steady state with τ ssd > τ ssn and/or τ ssc > 0. Using (A10)-(A12), a feasible and

14

admissible reform that decreases consumption at period t by dct = − a , increases consumption at period

15

t+1 by dct +1 = 1 ( a + ε ) and therefore raises welfare by β t u1, ss ( dct + β dct +1 ) = β t u1, ssε > 0 , can be written

16

in terms of labor reallocation and changes in tangible capital as

β

9

deu ,t = Zε ,

1 2

dem ,t =

 1 1  dnt = − deu ,t − dem ,t = −  +  dkm ,t +1 ,  D9 D10 

3

4

5

D10 deu ,t , D9

dkm ,t +1 =

with Z =

1 1 (a + ε ). Ωβ

dct + β dct +1   (1 − τ ssn )  (1 − τ ssn ) − 1 D10   βτ ssc ( f1, ss − δ m ) D10 +    f − 1 +  (1 − τ ssd )  3, ss D9  (1 − τ ssd )(1 − τ ssc )      

m m  I 22,  1   I 21, ss ss , D9 =    m − m  , I 2, ss    D7   I1, ss f3, ss  

6

u u and D10 =  1   I 21,u ss − I 22,u ss  . D9 and D10 have ambiguous sign. While the sign in the required change of  I 2, ss   D8   I1, ss

7

the allocation is not determined, we expect an increase in both types of effort, a decrease in labor and a

8

raise in tangible capital. Using (7)-(9), such a reform can be decentralized as

9

f  1 1 1 1 1 dτ tn = D3a − 33, ss  + (a + ε ),  n (1 − τ ss ) f3, ss  D9 D10  Ω β m m  I 21, u11, s I11, 1 ss d dτ t = − a +  m − mss d I u1, ss (1 − τ ss )  2, ss I1,ss

10

11

 1 1 1 D ( a + ε ) − D11 10 Z ε ,  m D9  I1, ss Ω β

u u  I 21, u11, s I11, 1 1 ss d c dτ t + dτ t = − a +  u − u ss d c I u1, ss (1 − τ ss ) (1 − τ ss )  2, ss I1, ss

 D6 1 1 ( a + ε ) − D12 Z ε ,  u I Ω β  1, ss

12

1 1 dτ tn+1 = − D3 ( a + ε ) , n (1 − τ ss ) β

13

u 1 1 dτ td+1 = 11, ss ( a + ε ) , d u1, ss β (1 − τ ss )

14

dτ tc+1 = 0,

15

u u u u m m m m  u   m  where D11 =  I12, ss − I 22, ss + I 2, ss  I 21, ss − I11, ss   > 0, and D12 =  I12,u ss − I 22,u ss +  I 21,u ss − I11,u ss  I 2,u ss  > 0. As mentioned m m m  m m     

16

 I1, ss 

I 2, ss

I1, ss  I 2, ss

I1, ss  

 I1, ss

I 2, ss

 I 2, ss

I1, ss  I1, ss 

earlier, dividend and labor taxes should decrease and corporate taxes should not change in period t+1 10

1

(as D3 > 0 for Ψ = 0 ). The sign in the change of other taxes is ambiguous. If, instead, τ ssd < τ ssn and/or

2

τ ssc < 0, the reform may require a transfer of resources from t+1 to t, and the sign of the changes in

3

allocation and taxes would be the opposite. In any case, a welfare improving perturbation exists and, in

4

consequence, our candidate policy is not optimal. Therefore, the optimal corporate tax is zero at steady

5

state and the optimal level of dividend and labor tax rates are positive and identical at steady state.

6 7 8 9 10 11

References Albanesi, S., Armenter, R., 2007. Understanding capital taxation in Ramsey models. Unpublished Manuscript. Albanesi, S., Armenter, R., 2012. Intertemporal distortions in the second best. Review of Economic Studies 79, 1271-1307.

11

Intangible Investment and Ramsey Capital Taxation ...

1 Sep 2013 - p u β. = the accumulation constraint for tangible capital,. 4 equation (1) in the main text, by. ( ). 1,. 1. 1. , m d t t t m t p. I χ τ. = − and the one for intangible capital, equation (2), by. 5. ( )( ). 1,. 1. 1. 1 . u d c t t t t u t p. I χ τ τ. = −. −. The resulting equations are added together and over time to obtain. 6. ( ) ( ) ( ).

116KB Sizes 0 Downloads 176 Views

Recommend Documents

Intangible investment and Ramsey capital taxation
sweat). In our setup, firms can always respond to changes in the timing of taxation. We ... to a great variety of settings.2 This paper reexamines these standard policy prescriptions in a more ...... Review of Economics and Statistics 80, 365–373.

Entrepreneurship, taxation and capital investment
eliminating capital taxation would simply encourage saving and aggregate capital .... Moskowitz and Vissing-Jorgensen (2002) show that venture capitals account for less than one .... Labor income and assets plus interest net of the income tax ..... O

Intangible Capital, Barriers to Technology Adoption and ...
Feb 7, 2008 - The neglect of intangible capital leads to a narrow definition of ..... innovators, so that education speeds the process of technological diffusion.

Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation
Aug 13, 2010 - system that treats labor and capital income separately as a tax base. The reform ... In the proposed tax system, the reward for an additional work effort is not .... Preferences: Households rank a bundle of consumption and leisure acco

Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation
Aug 13, 2010 - Abstract. Capital taxation which is negatively correlated with labor supply is proposed. This paper uses a life-cycle model of heterogeneous ...

Vintage Capital, Investment, and Growth
model of vintage capital and some properties of its solution. Section 4, .... an analytic function defined on @; otherwise it is defined on a proper subset of C.

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
May 7, 2017 - Transfer of responsibilities for administration of the program ..... Centers by either supplying the Small Business Development Centers with a ...

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
Aug 22, 2012 - 2.4(15E). Application for the investment tax credit. 2.5(15E). Verification of qualifying businesses and community-based seed capital funds.

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
Aug 22, 2012 - each of the individual owners of the entity on the basis of each owner's pro rata share of the earnings of the entity, and the individual owners may claim their respective credits on their individual income tax returns. For investments

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
29 Mar 2017 - each of the individual owners of the entity on the basis of each owner's pro rata share of the earnings of the entity, and the individual owners may claim their respective credits on their individual income tax returns. For investments

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
Jun 20, 2018 - Funds which could not meet the threshold of $500,000 in capital ...... which a valid Iowa “S” election is in effect, and such holder has no tax ...

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
Aug 16, 2017 - Transfer of responsibilities for administration of the program ..... Centers by either supplying the Small Business Development Centers with a ...

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
Sep 13, 2017 - The telephone number is (515)281-3204. Application forms may also be obtained by contacting a Small Business. Development Center in the ...

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
Apr 25, 2018 - A balance sheet, certified by the chief executive officer and the chief financial officer of the qualifying business, that reflects the qualifying ...

CAPITAL INVESTMENT BOARD, IOWA[123]
Aug 22, 2012 - Analysis, p.2. Capital Investment Board[123]. IAC 8/22/12. 4.11(15E). Notification to the department of revenue. 4.12(15E). Other provisions ...

Intangible Capital, Barriers to Technology Adoption ...
I add intangible capital to a variant of the neoclassical growth model and study the im- plications of this extension for cross-country income differences. I calibrate the parameters associated with intangible capital by using new estimates of invest

Taxation of Human Capital and Wage Inequality: A ... - Fatih Guvenen
JEL Codes: E24, E62 ...... (Amsterdam: North-Holland) 18. ... KRUEGER, D. (2006), “On the Optimal Progressivity of the Income Tax Code”, Journal of Monetary.

Capital Taxation, Intermediate Goods, and Production ...
p1 − f1(X) = 0. (4) p2 − f2(X−K)=0. (5). Example: Profit-maximization in Chamley-Judd implies that wages and the interest rate are equal to the marginal products of labor and capital, respectively. Finally, there is a resource constraint for ea

Mirrlees Meets Modigliani-Miller: Optimal Taxation and Capital Structure
Mar 17, 2010 - long-run time series data of the corporate income tax rate and the ..... will be assigned in period 1, in particular, how big (αh,αl) in (3.4) are.

Taxation of Human Capital and Wage Inequality: A ...
the impact of labour market (tax) policies on the determination of wage inequality, focusing on male workers and .... Europe. Finally, a number of recent papers share some common modeling elements with ours but ..... Figure 2 plots the progressivity