Turn Taking: Intertemporal Cooperation and Symmetry through Intratemporal Asymmetry by Sau-Him Paul Lau and Vai-Lam Mui (2010)

8

Other Proofs (Not for Publication)

The following result is useful in subsequent analysis. From (3) and δ ∈ (0, 1), we have à ! à ! h+l h−l h + δl = (1 + δ) + (1 − δ) 2 2 Ã

!

h+l > (1 + δ) . 2

(B1)

Proof of Lemma 1. We obtain three preliminary results useful for the proof of Lemma 1. First, define U (p) = p2 (t) + (1 − p)2 (s) + p (1 − p) (h + l)

(B2)

as a player’s current-period payoff when both players choose Tough with probability p. Using (B2), it is straightforward to obtain !

Ã

h i h+l h+l − U (p) = p2 + (1 − p)2 + 2p (1 − p) − U (p) 2 2 2

=p

Ã

!

Ã

!

h+l h+l − t + (1 − p)2 −s 2 2

(B3)

> 0. Second, from Table 2 and (B2), we have Vi (p, p) ³

´

³

= p2 [t + δVi (p, p)]+(1 − p)2 [s + δVi (p, p)]+p (1 − p) h + δV L +(1 − p) p l + δV H = U (p) + δ

nh

i

³

p2 + (1 − p)2 Vi (p, p) + p (1 − p) V H + V L

Therefore, we obtain

Vi (p, p) =

³

U (p) + δp (1 − p) V H + V L h

1 − δ p2 + (1 − p)2 23

i

´

.

´o

.

(B4)

(B5)

´

From (6), (7), (B3) and (B5), we have V

H

L

+V −Vi (p, p) = 2

=

=

n

h

1 − δ p2 + (1 − p)2

{1 − δ [1 − 2p (1 − p)]}

(1 − δ)

³

V H +V L 2

´

³

V H +V L 2

h

´

io ³

V H +V L 2

³

h

´

h

=

1−δ

− U (p)

p2

³

i

³

´i

− U (p) + δp (1 − p) V H + V L

1 − δ p2 + (1 − p)2 h+l h2

³

i

− U (p) + δp (1 − p) V H + V L

V H +V L 2

h

h

− U (p) + δp (1 − p) V H + V L

1 − δ p2 + (1 − p)2

1 − δ p2 + (1 − p)2

+ 2δp (1 − p)

h

´

+ (1 − p)2

> 0.

i i

´i

(B6)

Third, h > l implies V H > V L . This inequality, together with (B6), leads to VH >

VH +VL > Vi (p, p) . 2

(B7)

We now prove Lemma 1. Using (6) and (7), we have V H = h + δl + δ 2 V H .

(B8)

From (B4), we have nh

i

³

´o

p2 + (1 − p)2 Vi (p, p) + p (1 − p) V H + V L . (B9) We prove Lemma 1 by showing that (a) the coefficient of δ 2 in (B8) is larger than that in (B9), and (b) h + δl in (B8) is larger than s + δU (p) in (B9). First, (B7) implies that s+δVi (p, p) = s+δU (p)+δ 2

h

i

V H = p2 + (1 − p)2 + 2p (1 − p) V H h

i

³

´

> p2 + (1 − p)2 Vi (p, p) + p (1 − p) V H + V L .

Second, (4), (B1) and (B3) imply that

Ã

!

h+l h + δl − [s + δU (p)] > (1 + δ) − [s + δU (p)] 2 =

Ã

!

"

#

h+l h+l −s +δ − U (p) 2 2 > 0. 24

´i

This proves Lemma 1. Proof of Lemma 2. For the accommodating case, l > t. According to (B7), V H > Vi (p, p). Combining these results, we obtain (9a). Proof of Lemma 3. The following analysis applies to the symmetric equilibrium supported by the TTIR strategy with p∗1 = p∗2 = p∗ and V1∗ = V2∗ = V ∗ . From (8), (9), and the first equality of (12), we have 1 − p∗ =

(V H

V L − t − δV ∗ > 0. − s − δV ∗ ) + (V L − t − δV ∗ )

(B10)

Also, (6), (7) and the first equality of (12) imply p∗ − 0.5 =

h − l − (1 + δ) (s − t) . 2 (1 + δ) [(V H − s − δV ∗ ) + (V L − t − δV ∗ )]

(B11)

It is easy to see that the denominator of (B11) is positive. For the numerator, either t − s ≥ 0 or t − s < 0 can be consistent with t > l. If t − s ≥ 0, it is easy to conclude from (3) that the numerator of (B11) is positive. If t − s < 0, then (4), t > l and 0 < δ < 1 imply h − l − (1 + δ) (s − t) > h − l − 2 (s − t) "Ã

!

#

(B12)

h

i

h+l =2 − s + t − l > 0. 2 Combining (B10), (B11), and (B12), we have (18). From the second equality of (11), we have h

i

p∗ (δ) V L (δ) − t − δV ∗ (δ, p∗ (δ)) = [1 − p∗ (δ)] V H (δ) − s − δV ∗ (δ, p∗ (δ)) , where the dependence of p∗ on δ, and V ∗ on δ and p∗ (δ) are written explicitly. Differentiating the above expression with respect to δ, and rearranging, gives (19). Consider the denominator of (19). Combining (18) and (B21) below, the third term in the denominator of (19) is positive. The first two terms in the denominator of (19) are positive when (8) and (9) hold. Therefore, we have ³

´

³

´

V H − s − δV ∗ + V L − t − δV ∗ + δ (1 − 2p∗ )

∂V ∗ > 0. ∂p∗

(B13)

Consider the numerator of (19). First, (18) implies p∗ > 1 − p∗ > 0. 25

(B14)

Second, using (6) and (7), we have Ã

!

Ã

∂V ∗ ∂V ∗ ∂V L ∂V H −δ −V∗ − −δ −V∗ ∂δ ∂δ ∂δ ∂δ

!

∂V L ∂V H − ∂δ³ ∂δ ´ H −∂ V − V L

= =

∂δ h−l > 0. = (1 + δ)2

(B15)

Third, using (B6), we have ( "

#)

∂ VH +VL − V ∗ (δ, p∗ (δ)) δ ∂δ 2 h

h+l 2

h



i



⎬ δ h+l − U (p∗ ) ∂ ⎨ 2 h i = ∂δ ⎩ 1 − δ (p∗ )2 + (1 − p∗ )2 ⎭ i

− U (p∗ )

(B16)

=n h io2 > 0. 1 − δ (p∗ )2 + (1 − p∗ )2

∂ (δV H ) L H H Fourth, (7) implies ∂V∂δ = = δ ∂V∂δ + V H , and (6) implies ∂V∂δ = ∂δ ∂ (δV L ) L = δ ∂V∂δ + V L . Using these relationships, (B15) and (B16), we have ∂δ

´i ∂V ∗ ∂ h ³ H ∂V L −δ −V∗ = δ V −V∗ ∂δ ∂δ ∂δ " Ã

!#

" Ã

∂ ∂ VH +VL VH −VL −V∗ + = δ δ ∂δ 2 ∂δ 2 " Ã !# VH −VL ∂ > δ ∂δ 2 ⎡ ³

´

³

!#

´⎤

H ∂ δV L 1 ⎣ ∂ δV ⎦ = − 2 ∂δ ∂δ

1 = 2

Ã

∂V L ∂V H − ∂δ ∂δ

!

(B17)

> 0.

Therefore, (B14), (B15), and (B17) imply that ∗

p

Ã

!

Ã

∂V L ∂V H ∂V ∗ ∂V ∗ −δ − V ∗ − (1 − p∗ ) −δ −V∗ ∂δ ∂δ ∂δ ∂δ Ã

!

Ã

! !

∂V ∗ ∂V ∗ ∂V L ∂V H −δ − V ∗ − (1 − p∗ ) −δ − V ∗ > 0. > (1 − p ) ∂δ ∂δ ∂δ ∂δ (B18) ∗

26

That is, the numerator of (19) is negative. Combining (B13) and (B18) gives Lemma 3. Proof of Proposition 2. 14 To show the existence of p∗ ∈ (0, 1) satisfying (12) for the mutual-tough case, we define the following continuous function g (p) =

[V H

V H − s − δV (p) −p − s − δV (p)] + [V L − t − δV (p)]

(B19)

over p ∈ [0, 1], where V (p) = Vi (p, p) according to (10). It is easy to observe that g (.) is a well-defined function for every p ∈ [0, 1], and the solution to (12) is defined by g (p) = 0. Using (B5) and (4) to (7), we can show that for all δ ∈ (δ T T , 1), g (0) =

[V H

=

V H − s − δV (0) −0 − s − δV (0)] + [V L − t − δV (0)] VH −s−δ

³

s 1−δ

´

V H + V L − s − t − 2δ

and g (1) =

[V H =

³

s 1−δ

´

> 0,

(B19a)

V H − s − δV (1) −1 − s − δV (1)] + [V L − t − δV (1)] h

− VL−t−δ

³

t 1−δ

V H + V L − s − t − 2δ

´i ³

t 1−δ

´

< 0.

(B19b)

Applying the Intermediate Value Theorem, we know that there exists a p ∈ [0, 1] such that g (p) = 0. 15 Moreover, g (p) = 0 does not hold at p = 0 or p = 1, as observed in (B19a) and (B19b). Therefore, we conclude that the solution to (12) exists in the interval (0, 1). The proof of the uniqueness of the solution to (12) for the mutual-tough case is also similar to that of Proposition 1, except that the analysis holds only for δ ∈ (δ T T , 1) when t > l, whereas it holds for all δ ∈ (0, 1) when t < l. Proof of Proposition 3. At the symmetric equilibrium supported by the 14 An

important feature that distinguishes the proof of Proposition 2 from that of Proposition 1 is that condition (9a) does not hold for all p ∈ (0, 1) for the mutualtough case, but it does hold for p = p∗ when δ > δ T T . 15 We use the Intermediate Value Theorem instead of the Fixed Point Theorem because f (p), as defined in (A1), is not necessarily a mapping from [0, 1] to [0, 1] for the mutual-tough case.

27

TTIR strategy, the second equality of (11) can be rewritten as h

i

h

i

p∗ (θ) V L (θ) − t − δV ∗ (p∗ (θ)) = [1 − p∗ (θ)] V H (θ) − s − δV ∗ (p∗ (θ)) , (B20) H L ∗ ∗ ∗ where the dependence of V on θ, V on θ, p on θ, and V on p (θ) are explicitly stated. It is clear from (6), (7), (10) and (24) that V ∗ depends on θ via p∗ (θ) only. Differentiating (B20) with respect to θ, and simplifying, we obtain (26) in the main text. The sign of various components of (26) are obtained as follows. We know from (3), (5), (6), (7), (24), (25), and the first equality of (A2) when p∗1 = p∗2 = p∗ and V1∗ = V2∗ = V ∗ that ∗

∂V (1 + δ) t − (h + δl) = = ∗ ∂p (1 − δp∗ )2 (1 + δ)

h

(1 + δ) t − (1 + δ)

³

h+l 2 ∗ 2

´

+ (1 − δ)

(1 − δp ) (1 + δ)

³

h−l 2

´i

< 0,

(B21)

H

∂V λ = > 0, ∂θ (1 + δ) (1 + θ)2 and

³

∂ VH +VL ∂θ

´

= 0.

(B22)

(B23)

Moreover, (8) and (9) hold for t < l and δ ∈ (0, 1) or for t > l and δ ∈ (δ T T , 1). When 0.5 < p∗ < 1, both the denominator and numerator of (26) are positive. Thus, 0.5 < p∗ < 1 is a sufficient condition for ∂p∗ > 0. ∂θ

(B24)

Moreover, since 2p∗ (1 − p∗ ) is decreasing in p∗ when 0.5 < p∗ < 1, we conclude from (23) and (B24) that 0.5 < p∗ < 1 is a sufficient condition for ∂E (D) ∂p∗ ∂E (D) × = ∂θ ∂p∗ ∂θ to be positive. Since 0.5 < p∗ < 1 is satisfied for game G∞ with t > l and δ ∈ (δ T T , 1) according to Lemma 3, this proves part (a). Since V H > V L , it is easy to see from (B20) that V H − s −δV ∗ > V L − t − δV ∗ when t ≥ s. Consequently, p∗ > 1 − p∗ and thus, 0.5 < p∗ < 1. This proves part (b).

28

Intertemporal Cooperation and Symmetry through ...

It is easy to see that the denominator of (B11) is positive. For the numerator, either t − s ... inator of (19) are positive when (8) and (9) hold. Therefore, we have.

110KB Sizes 0 Downloads 273 Views

Recommend Documents

Determinacy Through Intertemporal Capital Adjustment ...
Sep 2, 2002 - sectors, kct and kxt are the capital stocks in the two sectors, rct and rxt are the ... attached to (2b) and by µct and µxt the current value multipliers.

Determinacy Through Intertemporal Capital Adjustment ...
Sep 2, 2002 - Externalities,” Economics Letters, 2001, 72, 355–360. Hall, Robert E., “Relation Between Price and Marginal Cost in U.S. Industry,” Journal of.

Sustaining Cooperation through Strategic Self ...
Norwegian Business School, email: [email protected]. .... office. Unlike the model presented here, they do not allow members to exert self-interested actions ...

Encouraging Node Cooperation through Payment Incentive ... - IJRIT
Incentive protocols use credits to stimulate the selfish nodes cooperation, but the .... The extensive use of digital signature operations for both the data and the ...

Encouraging Node Cooperation through Payment Incentive ... - IJRIT
The extensive use of digital signature operations for both the data and the ACK packets ... Sprite, the source node appends its signature to each packet and each ...

Symmetry and Equivalence - PhilArchive
Unfortunately, these mutually reinforcing half-arguments don't add up to much: each ...... Torre, C. (1995), “Natural Symmetries and Yang–Mills Equations.” Jour-.

Symmetry and Equivalence - PhilArchive
My topic is the relation between two notions, that of a symmetry of a physical theory and that of the physical equivalence of two solutions or models of such a theory. In various guises, this topic has been widely addressed by philosophers in recent

Intertemporal Disagreement and Empirical Slippery ...
In this article I point out another location at which these arguments may go wrong: ... 4 J. E. Olson and D. B. Kopel, 'All the Way down the Slippery Slope: Gun Prohibition ..... not take the sincere belief of a clairvoyant that the world will end in

pdf-175\innovation-through-cooperation-the-emergence-of-an-idea ...
... Science and Philosophy. Page 3 of 8. pdf-175\innovation-through-cooperation-the-emergenc ... my-management-for-professionals-by-georg-weiers.pdf.

Culture and cooperation
In this paper, we provide an answer by analysing the data of Herrmann et al. (2008a) .... shall analyse in detail below, showed a large diversity of punishment ...

Symmetry and Guess and Check.pdf
... a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Symmetry and Guess and Check.pdf. Symmetry and Guess a

Cooperation in Social Dilemmas through Position ...
Jun 7, 2017 - Keywords: Social Dilemmas; Public Goods; Position Uncertainty; Voluntary Con- tributions .... our mechanism applies to other social dilemmas.

Risk preferences, intertemporal substitution, and ...
Feb 15, 2012 - EIS is bigger than one or habits are present—two assumptions that have .... aggregate data on the volatility of output and consumption growth, ...

intertemporal budget constraint and public
the sum of all current and expected future non-interest outlays — expressed in ... economy by taking into account the growth of national income. In such a case, ...

Symmetry and Evidential Support
Sep 16, 2011 - Since they compose the synonym ..... Popper,K.R. The Logic of Scientific Discovery; Science Editions, Inc.: New York, NY, USA, 1961. 15. Miller ...

Dividend Taxation and Intertemporal Tax Arbitrage
Jul 29, 2008 - model go through three stages: When they are started, their marginal source of ..... In section 2 we develop our basic life-cycle model of capital ...

Supervision and effort in an intertemporal efficiency ...
benefit from paying their workers more than the market clearing wage, thus generating involuntary ... pay efficiency wages in order to reduce workers' shirking.

Symmetry Axioms and Perceived Ambiguity
Kyoungwon Seo. §. June 12, 2017. Abstract. Since at least de Finetti [7], preference symmetry assumptions have played an important role in models of decision ...

Coevolving Communication and Cooperation for ... - Semantic Scholar
Chicago, Illinois, 12-16 July 2003. Coevolving ... University of Toronto. 4925 Dufferin Street .... Each CA agent could be considered a parallel processing computer, in which a set of .... After 300 generations, the GA run converged to a reasonably h

Kinked Social Norms and Cooperation
Keywords: Kinked Demand, Symmetric Games, Norms of Behaviour,. Coalitions. ... Neither ineffi cient nor asymmetric PE allocations can, in fact, by definition ...