Kinked Social Norms and Cooperation Sergio Currarini (U. Venezia Cà Foscari) & Marco A. Marini (U. Urbino "Carlo Bo) September 2007 Abstract We investigate which speci…c social norrns of behauiour - here narrowly interpreted as a commonly shared expectations over people behaviour can sustain a cooperative outcome. We show that in a symmetric setting a speci…c social norm, one shaping the expected. response of all players in the event of individual or coalitional deviations from any collective choice, plays a special role in making.a cooperative outcome stable. Such a norm turns out to be strikingly similar to that assumed in the classical kinkeddemand model by Robinson (1933) and Sweezy (1939) (see also Hall and Hitch (1939)) for …rms operating in imperfectly competitive markets. Keywords: Kinked Demand, Symmetric Games, Norms of Behaviour, Coalitions.

1

Introduction

Often in their social interaction individuals adopt simple behavioural procedures. Social scientists talk to various degree, and with di¤erent meanings, of heuristics, conventions and norms of behaviour. Their emergence can be spontaneous, arising from the evolution of shared expectations into prescriptions and then into norms of behaviour (see, for instance, Lewis 1969, Bicchieri, 1990 and Castelfranchi et a1., 2002). This is a pervasive phenomenon in modern economies and economic actors, as companies’ managers, market traders and CEOs as well as workers and people in general appear similarly inclined to adopt simple procedures rather than complex and elaborate strategies, specially when they have to promptly react to unexpected events. Once established within an organization, i.e.a …rm, a set of norms may constitute its corporate culture.1 Since usually norms are strictly linked to social expectations and then to conjectures individuals form over the behaviour of other people, it is worth to investigate wich form these forces have to take to sustain a cooperative outcome 1 ”The corporate culture acts as a perception …lter, a¤ects the interpretation of information, sets moral and ethical standards, provide rules, norm and heuristics for action, and in‡uences how power and authority are wielded in reaching decision regarding what action to pursue”. (Brown, 1995, p. 197)

1

of the economy (i.e. an e¢ cent social outcome) against individual and coalitional deviations. Furthermore, it may be interesting to know whether these norms supporting cooperation are in general rational and if they correspond to some form of reciprocity. A very recent stream of literature has provided strong experimental evidence showing that even in one-shot games with anonymous players people may reward fair behaviour and punish unfair behaviour, even when such a reaction is detrimental to their material payo¤ (see, for a survey, Fehr, Fischbacher and Gachter 2002). Usually this literature classi…es agents’ propensity to support cooperation as i) strong reciprocity, ii) rational altruism or iii) altraism, when, in turn: i) players cooperate conditionally to the cooperation of opponents even when costly; ii) they cooperate only when strictly convenient; iii) they always cooperate, whatever is their expectations over other players’behaviour. In this paper we focus on a simple symmetric and monotone strategic setting and we …nd that a speci…c norm of behaviour - one shaping the expected response of all players in the event of an individual or a coalitional deviation from a collective choice - plays a special role in making the cooperative outcome stable. Such a norm turns to be strikingly similar to that assumed in the classical kinked-demand model by Robinson (1933) and Sweezy (1939) (see also Hall and Hitch (1939)) for …rms operating in imperfectly competitive markets. More speci…cally, we show that for all symmetric games in which such a ’kinked’social norm (KSN) is expected by all players, a Pareto e¢ cient outcome can never be improved upon by any single player or coalition of players. The paper is organized as follows. In the next subsection we present a simple example introducing the main idea of the paper. Section 2 illustrates the setting of the paper. Section 3 presents the main paper results. Section 4 applies these results to the classical kinked-demand model

1.1

An Illustrative Example

To provide an intuition of the logic underlying our results, let us introduce a symmetric two-player game in strategic form in which both players can choose between three strategies, A, B and C, with payo¤s illustrated by the following 3x3 bimatrix:

A B C

A a; a d; f e; h

B f; d b; b l; m

C h; e m; l c; c

Now, let assume that at least a symmetric Pareto e¢ cient outcome (SPE), i.e, an outcome maximizing the sum of all players’payo¤s, exists for this game. As a start, suppose that when every player i = 1; 2 changes from a given strategy 0 xi to a new strategy xi she.expects the the opponent will fully conform to her new choice, i.e., xj = x0i , with j 6= i. It is easy to see that when such a 2

symmetric (ot fully conformist) social norrn of behaviour (SSN) is accepted by all players, this implies that a SPE outcome is the only stable outcome of the game. Neither ine¢ cient nor asymmetric PE allocations can, in fact, by de…nition, give both players a payo¤ greater or equal to the one provided by the SPE outcome. For the same reason, no asymmetric outcomes can be stable against a deviation leading (via the SSN) to the SPE outcome itself. Altough it is not suprising that a full coordination attitude always leads players to a SPE outcome, an important question arises. Is the symmetric social norm the only expected behaviour sustaining cooperation in a symmetric setting? In order to answer this question suppose that all players share a norm of behaviour - that we denote kinked social norrn (KSN) - dictating that when a player i deviates from strategy xi to a new strategy x0i she expect her opponent to respond with a weakly lower strategy xj x0i under positive spillovers (PS) and with a weakly higher strategy xj x0i under negative spillovers (NS).2 To see that such a KSN can support a SPE outcome, assume …rst that players’strategies can be ordered and A > B > C. Let also our game to possess positive spilovers (PS). Therefore, the following inequalities hold: i) a > f > h; ii) d > b > rn and iii) e > :l > c. Assume …rsr that (c; c) ís a SPE outcome. Immagine now that one of the players, say player 1, decides to deviate from this outcome playing A instead of C and, in so doing, she expects the opponent will respònd with a weakly lower strategy. than C, in this case either A, B or C. As a result, player 1 may expect to get either a, h or f , respectively. However, if either a,h or f can improve upon c for player 1, by the PS property a > f > h, and. by the symmetry of the game we obtain that (a; a) can improve on (c; c) for both players, contradicting the fact that (c; c) is a SPE outcome. The same would occur if either (b; b) or (a; a) were a SPE and a deviating player expects her opponent to respond with a weakly lower strategy. Note that the entire reasoning can be repeated under negative spilovers (NS), in which case the KSN would dictate that players are expected to respond to any opponent’s deviation with a strategy weakly lower than deviators.3 Therefore, the above example shows that the stability of a cooperative outcome can be supported by both SSN and KSN. The same cannot be said of a norm implying that players respond with strictly higher strategies than deviators under PS and strictly lower under NS. Suppose, for instance, that (c; c) is a SPE and PS holds. If player l switch from C to B and expects xj > x0i ; the opponent will play A > B and player 1 can easily improve upon c, since there are no constraints in the game imposing that d has to be lower than c. As a …nal remark, we can preliminarly observe that when the game actions are strategic complements (in the sense of Bulow et al., 19S5) and then players’ best replies are increasing, a SPE of the game is stable whenever every player after a deviation expects a rational reponse from her opponent. 2 Note

that the monotone spillover property (ui (xi ; xj ) either strictly increasing or strictly decreasing in xj for every i = 1; 2 and j 6= i) is a very common property of games applied to economic and social analysis. 3 In our example this can be simply done by assuming A < B < C and repeating all steps shown above.

3

2

The Setting

Since the aim of the paper is to …nd social norrns of behaviour (in the narrow interpretation given above) ensuring the stability of a cooperative outcome independently by the peculiar features of the players (as preferences, relative in‡uence or bargaining power) we adopt here a very simple symmetric setting in which players are endowed with the same strategy space and perceive symmetrically all strategy pro…les of the game. To simplify further, we constrain our setting to possess some forms of monotonicity of players’ payo¤s with respect to their opponents’choices. Even so, the resulting setting is still rather general and many well known economic applications (as Cournot and Bertrand oligopoly, public goods games and many others) easily …t into its structure. We denote a a monotone symmetric n-player game in strategic form as a triple GS = N; (Xi ; ui )i2N , in which N = f1; :::; i; :::; ng is the set of players, Xi = X R is every player’s strategy space, assumed compact and convex, ui : X1 ::: Xn ! R+ is the payo¤ function of every player i, assumed continous and strictly quasiconcave, and in which the following two properties hold: P1. (Symmetry) For every i 2 N and for any arrangement of the strategy indexes u1 (x1 ; x2 ; ::; xn ) = u2 (x2 ; x1 ; ::; xn ) = ::: = un (xn ; x2 ; ::; x1 ): P2. (Monotone Spillovers) For every i; j 2 N with j 6= i and every xj > x2j we have either ui (x

1 j ; xj )

(1) x1j

>

> ui (x

j ; xj )

> ui (x

2 j ; xj )

(2)

< ui (x

j ; xj )

< ui (x

2 j ; xj )

(3)

positive spillovers (PS) or ui (x

1 j ; xj )

negative spillovers (NS), where x j = (x1 ; :::; xj 1 ; xj+1 ; ::; xn ): Moreover, since we extend the analysis to strategy pro…les taken by coalitions of players, we denote by S N any coalition of players, and by N nS itsQ complement with respect to N . For each coalition S, we denote by xS 2 XS i2S Xi a pro…le of strategies for players in S N , and use the notation x = xN . Finally, let de…ne a Pareto Optimum (PO) for GS as a strategy pro…le x 2 X n such that there exists no alternative pro…le which is preferred by all players and is strictly preferred by at least one player. The Pareto Optimum xe is e¢ cient (PE) if it maximizes the sum of the payo¤s of all players in N . Henceforth, when referring to a cooperative outcome of the game, we allude to one of its PE. In our setting, as shown in the following Lemma, a PE strategy pro…le for every coalition S N (included the grand coalition) turns out to be always symmetric. P Lemma 1 For all S N; xe 2 arg maxxS 2XS i2S ui (xS ; xN nS ) implies xei = xej for all i,j 2 S and for all xN nS 2 XN nS : 4

xeS

Proof. Suppose xei 6= xej for some i; j 2 S: By symmetry we can derive from a new vector x0S by permuting the strategies of players i and j such that X X 0 ui (xS ; xN nS ) = ui (xeS ; xN nS ) (4) i2S

i2S

and hence, by the strict quasiconcavity of all ui (x); for all 2 (0; 1) we have that: X X 0 ui ( xS + (1 )xeS ; xN nS ) > ui (xeS ; xN nS ): (5) i2S

i2S

0

Since, by the convexity of X; the strategy vector xS + (1 )xeS 2 XS ; we obtain a contradiction. An important implication of Lemma 1 is that when the players of a given coalition S N deviate opportunistically by a given pro…le of strategy x 2 X n , they will all play the same maximizing strategy.

3

Main Results

In this section we present the main results of the paper. Let us …rst de…ne both a Symmetric Social Norm (SSN) and a Kinked Social Norm (KSN) of behaviour in the setting introduced above (see …gures 1-3 for SSN and KSN in a two-player case). De…nition 2 (Symmetric Social Norm) We say that a Symmetric Social Norm (SSN) is active in the game GS ; if every coalition of players S N deviating from a given pro…le of strategies x 2 X n with a x0S 2 X s such that x0S 6= xS , expects the following response sN nS (x0S ) : X s 7! X n s by players j 2 N nS : sN nS (x0S ) = f 8j 2 N nS; xj 2 Xj xj = x0i g :

(6)

De…nition 3 (Kinked Social Norm) We say that a Kinked Social Norm (KSN) is active in the game GS ; if every coalition of players S N deviating from a given pro…le of strategies x 2 X n with a x0S 2 X s such that x0S 6= xS , expects the following response kN nS (x0S ) : X s 7! X n s by players j 2 N nS : kN nS (x0S ) = f 8j 2 N nS; xj 2 Xj xj

x0i g :

(7)

x0i g :

(8)

under positive spillovers(PS) and kN nS (x0S ) = f 8j 2 N nS; xj 2 Xj xj under negative spillovers(NS). Note that in both cases there is no presumption of rational behaviour behind these norms and the reactions of players may not correspond to their best reply maps. Finally, let us introduce a general de…nition of stability of a strategy pro…le in our game GS under an arbitrary social norm. 5

De…nition 4 A strategy pro…le x 2 X n is stable under the social norm X s 7! X n s if there exists no S N and x0S 2 X s such that ui (x0S ; uh (x0S ;

0 N nS (xS )) 0 N nS (xS ))

N nS

:

ui (x) 8i 2 S; uh (x) for some h 2 S:

>


0

ui (xS ; sN nS (xS )) > ui (xe ) 8i 2 S:

(9) 0

By the property of sN nS (xS ) and Lemma 1 it must be that sj (xS ) = xi for every j 2 N nS and i 2 S so that 0

ui (x ) > ui (xe ) for all i 2 N , implying

X

ui (x0 ) >

i2N

X

ui (xe )

(10)

(11)

i2N

contradicting that xe is a PE outcome. To show that no other strategy pro…le in GS can be stable under SSN, suppose by contradiction that an arbitrary ine¢ cient pro…le x 2 X n is stable under SSN. Therefore, for every i 2 N it must be that 0 0 ui (x) ui (xS ; sN nS (xS )): (12) 0

Take now xS = xeS ; since xeS 2 X s is an admissible deviation for every S N . It follows that ui (x) ui (xeS ; sN nS (xeS )) (13) and then by SSN ui (xe )

ui (x)

6

(14)

for all i 2 N; thus implying

X

X

ui (x)

i2N

ui (xe )

(15)

i2N

contradicting the ine¢ ciency of x (we know by Lemma 1 that every e¢ cient pro…le must be symmetric). Although the above result is not surprising since we expect that full coordination among players yields a PE allocation. However, if we relax the strict quasiconcavity of players’payo¤ and let asymmetric PE to exist in GS , they would not be stable either under SSN. In fact, with such asymmetric allocations at least one of the players receive less than in a SPE allocation and therefore he has an incentive, under SSN, to switch to the SPE. The next result concerns the alternative social norm de…ned above. Proposition 6 When a Kinked Social Norm (KSN) is active on GS , the cooperative outcome (SPE) xe 2 X n is stable. Proof. By De…nition 2, a KSN active on GS implies kN nS (x0S ) x0S under x0S under NS, for every x0S 2 X s : When kN nS (x0S ) = x0S PS and kN nS (x0S ) we know that, by Proposition 1, that xe 2 X n is stable. We need to prove that the same holds when kN nS (x0S ) < x0S under NS and kN nS (x0S ) > x0S under PS. Assume …rst that positive spillovers (PS) hold in GS . Assume also by contradiction that the SPE xe 2 X n is not stable and there exists a S N and a x0S 2 X s such that 0

0

ui (xS ; kN nS (xS )) > ui (xe ) 8i 2 S:

(16)

0

Using PE, Lemma 1 and the fact that kj (xS ) < x0i for every j 2 N nS and i 2 S, we obtain 0

0

0

0

ui (xS ; xN nS ) > ui (xS ; kN nS (xS )) > ui (xe ) and then, by the symmetry of GS X X ui (x0 ) > ui (xe ) i2N

(17)

(18)

i2N

a contradiction.

4

The Classical Kinked Demand Revisited

To illustrate our main results, let us introduce a simple example with two symmetric …rms. The original idea of the kinked demand model (Robinson 1936, Sweezy 1939) was the following: when a …rm, say …rm 1, rises its price, it expects that other …rms (here …rm 2) rise their price comaparatively less (underreaction). Conversely, when …rm 1 lowers its price, it expects …rm 2 to reduce 7

its price even more (over-reaction). This conjecture yields the well known model of kinked demand (see …gure 4). Suppose now that the two …rms are charging the consumers the pair of prices (p1 ; p2 ), and that these prices are perfectly cooperative for the …rms, i.e., they maximize the sum of pro…ts of the two …rms. The ’kinked demand’norm of behaviour dictates the following: 0

0

0

0

If p0i

>

if p0i

pi for i = 1; 2, then kj (pi ) < pi , for j 6= i:

<

pi for i = 1; 2, then kj (pi ) < pi , for j 6= i; 0

where p0i indicates any price di¤erent from pi and kj (pi ) the price expected by the rival, whenever a …rm decides to change its own price. Note that no presumption of best response is assumed for kj (:). Now we can show that the pair of prices (pe1 ; pe2 ) is stable under the kinked norm of behavior. Suppose one …rm, say …rm 1, decides to deviate from the pair of strategies (pe1 ; pe2 ) to improve 0 upon its pro…t, that is, 1 p01 ; k2 (p1 ) > 1 (pe1 ; pe2 ). It is well known that in a model of price competition the e¤ect of a rise in competitors’prices yields a 0 (positive spillover). Thus, if positive e¤ect on a …rm’s pro…t, that is, @@pji 1

0

p01 ; k2 (p1 ) >

1

(pe1 ; pe2 ) ;

it must be that 1

By symmetry,

1

0

p01 ; p2 0

p01 ; p2 = X

0

p01 ; k2 (p1 ) >

1

2

i

1

(pe1 ; pe2 ) :

0

p01 ; p2 , and then, 0

p01 ; p2 >

i=1;2

X

i

(pe1 ; pe2 ) ;

i=1;2

contradicting the e¢ ciency of the perfectly cooperative outcome. The same result obviously holds when it is …rm 2 to deviate. This implies that when all …rms expect a kinked demand response from the other …rms, that is, when kinked social norm becomes the established norm of behaviour for all …rms, no pro…table deviations are possible from the perfectly collusive outcome (monopoly pricing). Surprisingly, the model easily extends to the case in which the …rms set quantities instead of prices. The ’kinked demand’norm of behavior now dictates the following: 0

0

0

0

if qi0

>

if qi0

qi for i = 1; 2, then kj (qi ) > qi , for j 6= i;

<

qi for i = 1; 2, then kj (qi ) > qi , for j 6= i; 0

where qi0 indicates any quantity di¤erent from qi , and kj (qi ) the quantity set by the rival as a response. Again, it is well known that in in a model of quantity competition the e¤ect of a rise in competitors’quantities yields a negative e¤ect 0, just because, this lowers on a …rm’s pro…t (negative spillovers), that is, @@qji 8

the market price p (q1 ; q2 ). Hence, if …rm 1 pro…tably deviates from the pair of 0 strategies (q1 ; q2 ), that is, 1 q10 ; k2 (q1 ) > 1 (q1 ; q2 ), it follows that 1

0

q10 ; q2

1

0

q10 ; k2 (q1 ) >

0

1

(p1 ; p2 ) :

0

Then, by symmetry, 1 q10 ; q2 = 2 q10 ; q2 , and this contraddicts the e¢ ciency of the pair of strategies (q1 ; q2 ).

5

Graphics

Figure 1 - SSN in a two-player case

9

Figure 2

Figure 3

Figure 4

References [1] Bicchieri, C. (1990), "Norms of Cooperation", Ethics, 100, pp.838-861. 10

[2] Brown, A. D. (1995), Organizational Culture. London: Pitman [3] Castelfranchi, C., M. Miceli (2002). "The mind and the future: The (negative) power of expectations" Theory & Psychology,12, pp.335-366. [4] Fehr, E., U. Fischbacher and S. Gachter (2002), "Strong Reciprocity, Human Cooperation, and the Enforcement of Social Norms", Human Nature, 2003 [5] Hall, R.L. and Hitch, C. J.(1939), "Price Theory and Business Behaviour", Oxford Economic Papers, 2, pp.12-45. [6] Hart and Mas Collel’s (2000, 2001a, 2001b, 2003a, 2003b) [7] Lewis, D. K. (1969). Convention. Cambridge, Harvard University Press. [8] Robinson, J. (1933), "Economics of Imperfect Competition", London, Macmillan. [9] Sweezy, P. M. (1939), "Demand under Conditions of Oligopoly", Journal of Political Economy, 47, pp.568-573.

11

Kinked Social Norms and Cooperation

culture.1 Since usually norms are strictly linked to social expectations and then ..... Definition 4 A strategy profile x ) Xn is stable under the social norm σN\s. &.

157KB Sizes 4 Downloads 276 Views

Recommend Documents

Kinked Social Norms and Cooperation
Keywords: Kinked Demand, Symmetric Games, Norms of Behaviour,. Coalitions. ... Neither ineffi cient nor asymmetric PE allocations can, in fact, by definition ...

Social Norms and Community Enforcement
We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. ... crux of the matter is information transmission among the community members. Given this, we propose ..... 1' (1- )e,(I-BA)-lp. (1). 1+g and.

Prosocial norms and degree heterogeneity in social ...
Nov 12, 2010 - the key element for social norms to thrive in such networks [10]. .... Subjects face ten different situations with the following structure: lI am willing ...

Conformism, Social Norms and the Dynamics of ...
Jul 13, 2017 - not only on the second largest eigenvalue of the adjacency matrix but also ... consider a more general utility function where the ex ante heterogeneity of all individuals is introduced. In Section 10, we propose other applications of o

Social Emulation, the Evolution of Gender Norms, and ...
Abstract. In this dissertation, I develop theoretical models of the role of social ... In the third essay, “Do Public Transfers Crowd Out Private Support to the Elderly?:

Governmental Action, Social Norms, and Criminal ...
observed within and between U.S. cities. While these economic ... The strength of the social crime norm is measured by the moral costs that arise from committing a ..... media, the same need not hold true for minor changes. For that reason, I ...

Enforcing Social Norms: Trust-building and community ...
Apr 3, 2014 - are completed on eBay and other internet sites, where buyers and sellers trade .... transmission of unverifiable information (cheap talk).3 ..... The set of achievable payoffs includes payoffs arbitrarily close to efficiency for the ...

Conformism, Social Norms and the Dynamics of ...
Mar 29, 2018 - the initial norms of all agents belonging to the same communication class, where the weights are determined by the ... these two types of behaviors can arise endogeneously in the steady-equilibrium, even for ex ...... network for aggre

Enforcing Social Norms: Trust-building and community ...
Apr 3, 2014 - build trust by not deviating from the equilibrium action even though ..... suppose it is player 1 who wants to deviate from (â1, â2) while ...... my beliefs after being infected, I must also condition on the information from my own.

Culture and cooperation
In this paper, we provide an answer by analysing the data of Herrmann et al. (2008a) .... shall analyse in detail below, showed a large diversity of punishment ...

The leading eight: Social norms that can maintain ...
not, even if he has no experiences of direct interaction with them. .... call this a ''reputation dynamics'', and denote it by d. (Ohtsuki and ...... Center for the study of ...

Emergence of cooperation in adaptive social ...
As such, adaptive social dynamics and behavioral differences benefit the entire community .... mutations, the dynamics reduces to transitions between homogeneous states of the .... dilemmas in structured heterogeneous populations. P. Natl.

Cooperation in Social Dilemmas: Free Riding May Be ... - CiteSeerX
We acknowledge support from a Social Sciences & Humanities Re- ..... Ninety-seven 1st-year students at ... computer players and was told that one of the other three “players” .... of participants differed in the degree to which they punished.

Cooperation in Social Dilemmas: Free Riding May Be ... - CiteSeerX
version of the article; Shigeru Terai for assistance with programming;. Trina Hancock ...... ide rs and non p rov id ers. Reward-Punish condition. Punish-Reward.

Social bonds predict future cooperation in male Barbary ...
Social bonds have been construed as mental representations mediating social interactions among indi- viduals. It is problematic, however, to differentiate this ...

emergence of cooperation Social structure of primate ...
May 14, 2009 - Social structure of primate interaction networks facilitates the ... groups network reciprocity augmented the fixation probability for cooperation.

Cooperation in Social Dilemmas through Position ...
Jun 7, 2017 - Keywords: Social Dilemmas; Public Goods; Position Uncertainty; Voluntary Con- tributions .... our mechanism applies to other social dilemmas.

Cooperation in Social Dilemmas: Free Riding May Be ... - CiteSeerX
2002; G. Hardin, 1968; R. Hardin, 1971; Olson, 1965; Ostrom,. 1990), and the use of .... In cooperative situations like large-group public goods, these personal ..... weighted least squares to analyze the categorical data on the number of ...

Epistemic Norms and Natural Facts
Distinctions of degree can also usefully be drawn between various .... information one has, the more internalist this kind of epistemic normativity will be. Even this ... technology of truth-seeking … a matter of efficacy for an ulterior end, truth

Epistemic Norms and Natural Facts
open when M1's truth is settled is to beg the question against the view that the same fact. 5 ... claims on this list. Equally importantly, a single normative sentence might have two (or more) ..... 363) says that 'an account of the source of epistem