No 2007 – 16 November

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages _____________

Isabelle Méjean Lise Patureau

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages _____________ Isabelle Méjean Lise Patureau

No 2007 – 16 November

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

Contents 1

Introduction

8

2

Theoretical framework 10 2.1 Main assumptions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 2.2 The general equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

3

Minimum wages and the location of production 17 3.1 With exogenous skilled-labor wages (β = 0) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 3.2 With endogenous skilled wages adjustment (β 6= 0) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 3.3 Sensitivity analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

4

Conclusion

24

A

Appendix A.1 The interior equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . A.2 The general equilibrium in the corner equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . A.3 Minimum wage shocks and location decisions under exogenous skilled wages . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

28 28 29

3

30

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

L OCATION D ECISIONS AND M INIMUM WAGES

N ON - TECHNICAL SUMMARY The impact of labor-market institutions on macroeconomic performances lies at the heart of current debates among both economic and political circles. Debates are particularly vivid in Europe, where countries have implemented various labor-market policies over the last decades to cope with high levels of unemployment. In particular, as underlined by Dolado, Felgueroso and Jimeno (2000) and Dickens, Machin and Manning (1999), there has been a considerable resurgence of interest regarding minimum wages, which are an important feature of a large number of OECD labor markets. When asking for the impact of minimum wage policies, two broad and opposite arguments emerge. On the one hand, high minimum wages prevent flexibility on the labor market, and by raising marginal costs, lead to adverse effects on labor demand and employment. On the other hand, minimum wages help maintaining the purchasing power of low-skilled workers and sustaining aggregate demand. Review of the vast labor-market literature devoted to this question yields contrasted results in terms of labor-market performances. The adverse effect of minimum wage obtained in the neoclassical model is questioned in non-competitive frameworks, as shown by Bhaskar and To (1999) in an oligopsonistic model, Cahuc and Zylberberg (1999) in a search-equilibrium model, Manning (1995) in an efficiency wage model or Cahuc and Michel (1996) in a training-enhancing framework. The related empirical literature does not reach a clear-cut conclusion either.1 But in any case within that strand of literature, reasoning is held for a given production structure, thereby neglecting the key role of endogeneity in firms’ location decisions. Contrasting with the existing literature, the present paper takes into account this latter dimension by studying the impact of minimum wage policy on country’s attractiveness for investors. To this aim, wage rigidities are introduced in a twocountry model analyzing firms’ location choices in an international setting. Minimum wages at once affect the relative cost of producing and aggregate demands. However, because of international trade costs, firms located in the domestic country benefit more than their foreign competitors from the demand increase (a phenomenon called “home market effect”). We show that several conditions must be achieved for the country’s attractiveness to rise with an unilateral minimum wage increase, i.e. for the aggregate demand impact (the “home market effect”) to dominate the negative cost effect in firms’ location choices: • the purchasing power gain of unskilled workers (paid at the minimum wage) has to be less than compensated by a reduction in the demand for unskilled labor. This notably requires skilled and unskilled workers to be weak substitutes. 1

Papers that focus on “natural experiments” do not get any clear-cut impact of minimum wage shocks on employment (See Card and Krueger (1994) for the US, Machin and Manning (1996) for the UK, and Dolado et al. (1996) in several European countries). Yet, empirical papers on individual data most obtain a significant (and negative) impact of minimum wage on the specific segment of lowskilled workers (see Kramarz and Philippon (2001), Portugal and Cardoso (2006), Laroque and Salanié (1999)).

4

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

• the minimum wage increase should not come along with a too substantial drop in skilled workers’ wage. The purchasing power gain on the unskilled labor segment would therefore be compensated by an opposite adverse effect on the other strand of the labor market (i.e. the skilled-labor one), notably if the share of skilled workers in the population is large enough. • international trade costs have to be large enough for the “home market” effect to play its role. Our results suggest that the globalization process, by reducing barriers to trade, tends to reinforce international social competition. While increasing the mobility of production factors, it introduces new constraints in the design of economic policy, that should be taken into account when trying to maintain national competitiveness. A BSTRACT The paper contributes to the living debate on the controversial effects of minimum wage policy on economic performances, focusing on its impact on firms’ location choice. The question is investigated through a theoretical model, that incorporates features from the new trade literature (Krugman (1991)) and the labor-market literature. In a two-country framework, we model endogenous entry of firms under wage rigidity. In this setting, the impact of an unilateral increase in the home country’s minimum wage is analyzed. The policy shock is shown to have a twofold influence on the relative attractiveness of the home country, simultaneously affecting its relative cost competitiveness and the aggregate demand addressed to firms. The final effect on firms’ location decisions notably depends on the way skilled and unskilled labor markets adjust. Our overall results suggest that the impact of labor-market policies on firms’ location decisions have to be taken into account when evaluating their whole consequences in the national economy. JEL Classification: F12, F16, F21, J31, F41 Keywords: Minimum wage, Home Market Effect, Firms location decisions.

5

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

D ÉCISIONS DE L OCALISATION ET S ALAIRES M INIMUMS R ÉSUMÉ NON - TECHNIQUE L’impact des règles de fonctionnement du marché du travail sur les performances macroéconomiques fait actuellement l’objet de débats économiques et politiques. Les discussions sont particulièrement vives en Europe, où différentes réformes du marché du travail ont été mises en oeuvre au cours des dernières décennies pour tenter de réduire un chômage élevé. On observe notamment, comme le notent Dolado, Felgueroso and Jimeno (2000) et Dickens, Machin and Manning (1999), un regain d’intérêt pour les politiques de salaire minimum, en place dans de nombreux pays de l’OCDE. On considère généralement que le salaire minimum a deux types d’effets. D’une part, le salaire minimum réduit la flexibilité du marché du travail : en augmentant les coûts salariaux, il tend à diminuer la demande de travail et l’emploi. D’autre part, en garantissant un certain niveau de pouvoir d’achat aux travailleurs peu qualifiés, il soutient la demande globale. La littérature sur le fonctionnement du marché du travail qui s’intéresse à cette question aboutit à des résultats contrastés. L’effet pervers du salaire minimum obtenu dans un cadre néoclassique est remis en cause lorsque l’analyse est conduite dans un cadre non-concurrentiel, comme le montrent Bhaskar and To (1999) dans un modèle de concurrence oligopolistique, Cahuc and Zylberberg (1999) dans le cas du modèle de recherche d’emploi, Manning (1995) dans un cadre avec salaire d’efficience ou Cahuc and Michel (1996) dans un cadre avec apprentissage. La littérature empirique ne parvient pas non plus à des résultats tranchés2 . Dans tous les cas cependant, cette littérature maintient l’hypothèse de constance de la structure productive, et néglige donc la question de l’endogénéité des choix de localisation des firmes. A l’inverse, le présent document prend explicitement en compte cette dimension et analyse l’impact de la politique de salaire minimum sur l’attractivité d’un pays au regard des investisseurs. A cette fin, des rigidités salariales sont introduites dans un modèle à deux pays, étudiant la localisation des firmes au niveau international. Le salaire minimum affecte alors à la fois le coût relatif de production et la demande agrégée. Or, du fait des coûts à l’échange international, une hausse de la demande bénéficie favantage aux firmes situées sur le territoire qu’à celles situées à l’étranger (c’est l’effet “home market”). Notre analyse met en évidence plusieurs conditions pour que le pays bénéficie d’une hausse unilatérale de salaire minimum en termes d’attractivité auprès des investisseurs, c’est-à-dire pour que l’effet positif de la demande (effet “home market”) puisse l’emporter sur l’effet négatif des coûts dans le choix de localisation des firmes : • le gain de pouvoir d’achat des travailleurs non-qualifiés (rémunérés au salaire minimum) ne doit pas être compensé par une baisse de la demande de travail non-qualifié. 2

Les articles qui étudient certaines “expériences naturelles” n’obtiennent aucun effet clair des chocs de salaire minimum sur l’emploi (cf. Card and Krueger (1994) dans le cas américain, Machin and Manning (1996) pour le Royaume-Uni, et Dolado et al. (1996) pour plusieurs pays européens). En revanche, les études empiriques sur données individuelles obtiennent généralement un effet significativement négatif du salaire minimum sur la population des travailleurs peu qualifiés (Kramarz and Philippon (2001), Portugal and Cardoso (2006), Laroque and Salanié (1999)).

6

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

Pour cela, il faut que travailleurs qualifiés et non-qualifiés soient peu substituables. • la hausse du salaire minimum ne doit pas conduire à une diminution trop forte de la rémunération des travailleurs qualifiés. Le gain de pouvoir d’achat sur le segment nonqualifié du marché du travail pourrait alors, compte tenu du poids de chaque catégorie, être compensé par un effet opposé sur le segment du travail qualifié. • les coûts de l’échange international doivent être suffisamment élevés pour que joue l’effet “home market”. Nos résultats suggèrent ainsi que la globalisation, en venant réduire les obstacles aux échanges internationaux, tend à renforcer la concurrence sociale entre pays. En augmentant la mobilité des facteurs de production, elle introduit de nouvelles contraintes sur les décisions de politique économique qui doivent être prises en tenant compte de leur impact sur la compétitivité nationale. R ÉSUMÉ COURT Cet article s’inscrit dans la controverse sur l’effet des politiques de salaire minimum sur les performances économiques. En particulier, il s’intéresse à leur impact sur les choix de localisation des firmes. Cette question est analysée à travers un modèle théorique combinant des aspects de la nouvelle théorie du commerce international (Krugman, 1991) et de la littérature sur le fonctionnement du marché du travail. Dans un cadre à deux pays, nous analysons l’impact d’une hausse unilatérale du salaire minimum. Le choc de salaire a un double effet sur l’attractivité du pays, un effet de compétitivité relative et un effet sur la demande agrégée adressée aux entreprises par les consommateurs nationaux. L’impact total dépend des ajustements sur chaque segment, qualifié et non qualifié, du marché du travail. Nos résultats suggèrent que l’impact des politiques de marché du travail sur les choix de localisation des entreprises doit être pris en compte lors de l’évaluation de ce type d’intervention publique. Classification JEL : F12, F16, F21, J31, F41 Mots-clé : Salaire minimum, Effet Home Market, Choix de localisation des firmes

7

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

L OCATION D ECISIONS AND M INIMUM WAGES3 Isabelle MEJEAN4 Lise PATUREAU5

1

Introduction

The impact of labor-market institutions on macroeconomic performances lies at the heart of current debates among both economic and political circles. Debates are particularly vivid in Europe, where countries have implemented various labor-market policies over the last decades to cope with high levels of unemployment. In particular, as underlined by Dolado, Felgueroso and Jimeno (2000) and Dickens, Machin and Manning (1999), there has been a considerable resurgence of interest regarding minimum wages, which are an important feature of a large number of OECD labor markets.6 When asking for the impact of minimum wage policies, two broad and opposite arguments emerge. On the one hand, high minimum wages prevent flexibility on the labor market, and by raising marginal costs, lead to adverse effects on labor demand and employment level, as shown theoretically in the standard neoclassical framework (the “price competitiveness effect” hereafter). On the other hand, one major argument for minimum wage policy is tied to its role on aggregate demand. Minimum wages help maintaining the purchasing power of low-skilled workers, which are the labor-market segment the most vulnerable to international competition and skill-biased technological changes.7 A high-minimum wage policy would therefore entail an “income effect” that helps sustaining aggregate demand. The debate is all the less shut down, since the increasing degree of trade and financial liberalization in the recent decades puts more arguments into play. In particular, the easier mobility of production factors opens new opportunities for firms to choose in which country to locate and produce, a dimension that is likely to alter the aggregate performances of minimum wage policy as well. In the paper, we pay a particular attention to this dimension, asking how minimum wage policy affects firms’ location decisions in an international setting. Review of the vast labor-market literature devoted to minimum wage policy yields contrasted results in terms of labor-market performances. The adverse effect of minimum wage ob3

We would like to thank Philippe Martin, Pierre-Philippe Combes, Martine Carré, Matthieu Crozet and Jean-Olivier Hairault for helpful comments. The paper has also benefited from remarks made by the participants of the T2M conference 2006, the AFSE annual congress 2006 and of the seminars organized at CEPII, CREST and THEMA. Omissions and mistakes are, of course, ours. 4 CEPII ([email protected]). 5 THEMA, University of Cergy-Pontoise, France ([email protected]). 6 As illustrated by the recent increases in the US minimum wages (in 1990, 1991, 1997), the imposition of a minimum wage in the United Kingdom (2000) after its suppression in 1993 or recent successive rises in the French “SMIC” over legal requirements. 7 See Dolado, Felgueroso and Jimeno (2000) or Biscourp and Kramarz (2003)

8

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

tained in the neoclassical model is questioned in non-competitive frameworks, as shown by Bhaskar and To (1999) in an oligopsonistic model, Cahuc and Zylberberg (1999) in a searchequilibrium model, Manning (1995) in an efficiency wage model or Cahuc and Michel (1996) in a training-enhancing framework. The related empirical literature does not reach a clear-cut conclusion either.8 But in any case within that strand of literature, reasoning is held for a given production structure, thereby neglecting the key role of endogeneity in firms’ location decisions. Contrasting with the existing literature, the present paper takes into account this latter dimension by analyzing the impact of minimum wage policy on country’s attractiveness for foreign investors. We investigate the question in a theoretical new trade theory framework. Initiated by Krugman (1991)’s seminal paper, new trade theory focuses on the determinants of production patterns and firms’ location decisions in an international setting. It identifies two major determinants ; relative production costs, and aggregate demands. This framework is thus particularly well-suited to capture the twofold impact of minimum wage on firms’ location choices. With respect to the new trade literature, which mostly assumes flexible labor market, the originality of the paper lies in explicitly relating labor market imperfections and endogenous entry of firms. Dewit, Görg and Montagna (2003), Hajkova, Golub, Mizra, Nicoletti and Yoo (2003) or Javorcik and Spatareanu (2005) empirically study the role of labor-market institutions in foreign direct investment (FDI) flows, focusing on employment protection laws. This paper sheds light on another aspect of labor-market institutions, that is minimum wage policy. On this topic, and in the theoretical field, Picard and Toulemonde (2001) provide a notable contribution in a model with wage bargaining. Yet, their analysis is set in partial equilibrium, which prevents from taking into account the income effect of minimum wage policy. In a general equilibrium framework with wage rigidity, Strauss-Kahn (2005) investigates the impact of globalization on the extent of vertical specialization and the employment inequality between skilled and unskilled workers. Unlike this paper, we focus on horizontal FDI flows in minimum wage countries, consistently with empirical evidence suggesting that horizontal motives strongly dominate vertical ones in explaining world-wide FDI flows (Markusen and Matusz (2002)). We explicitly study the impact of cross-country differences in minimum wage policy on location decisions.9 With respect to the labor-market literature, we deliberately choose to adopt a simple framework regarding the labor-market functioning. In an otherwise competitive setting, nominal rigidity is introduced through minimum wage constraints. Absent any agglomeration ef8 Papers that focus on “natural experiments” do not get any clear-cut impact of minimum wage shocks on employment (See Card and Krueger (1994) for the US, Machin and Manning (1996) for the UK, and Dolado, Kramarz, Machin, Manning, Margolis and Teulings (1996) in several European countries). Yet, empirical papers on individual data most obtain a significant (and negative) impact of minimum wage on the specific segment of low-skilled workers (see Kramarz and Philippon (2001), Portugal and Cardoso (2006), Laroque and Salanié (1999)). 9 Note that our theoretical framework models entry and exit of firms between two similar countries that only differ in terms of their minimum wage policy. This allows to study the impact of minimum wages on horizontal FDI flows. On the other hand, this framework does not allow to capture the specific dimension of outsourcing linked to the decision of shutting down one entity in a given country, to open a new one abroad.

9

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

fect, these wage rigidities would be predicted to have negative aggregate effects, because of their depressive impact on labor demand. Conversely, in a general-equilibrium setting with endogenous entry of firms, we show that minimum wage policy has non-trivial effects. A minimum wage increase in the domestic market is shown to have a twofold impact on firms’ profits and location decisions. On the one hand, it increases the relative cost of producing in the country. On the other hand, it also affects its aggregate demand. Both elements come into play regarding the final impact on the country’s attractiveness. Under Home Market Effect, the income effect may counterbalance the competitiveness loss for national firms and maintain the country’s attractiveness. The arbitrage between both effects notably depends on adjustments that occur on the labor market and of the degree of liberalization in international trade. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents our general framework which incorporates the main features of the New Trade theory and wage rigidities. After solving the model in general equilibrium, we study the impact of a rise in the domestic minimum wage on firms’ entry decisions in Section 3. Last, Section 4 concludes.

2 2.1

Theoretical framework Main assumptions

The world economy is divided in two countries, Home and Foreign, with foreign variables ¯ (L ¯ ∗ ) unskilled and denoted with a star. The domestic (foreign) country is populated with L ∗ ¯ ¯ Q (Q ) skilled workers. As standard in the literature, we assume that workers are perfectly mobile across sectors but immobile across countries. Skilled and unskilled workers only differ by their productivity levels denoted aQ and aL , with aL < aQ . Without loss of generality, productivity levels are assumed to be identical across countries (aL = a∗L and aQ = a∗Q ). The representative household in each country consumes two types of goods, a homogeneous and a differentiated good. They are produced given a sector-specific technology using skilled and unskilled labor. As standard in the New Trade framework, the homogeneous good (denoted by Z) is produced under constant returns to scale in a perfectly competitive environment; it is freely traded across countries to balance the current account. As a consequence, the law of one price holds at the world level, which makes good Z a convenient candidate to serve as numéraire. In the following, all prices are thus expressed in terms of the homogeneous good. In the differentiated good sector, monopolistic competing firms produce for both their domestic and export markets, under increasing returns to scale and costly international trade. Varieties produced by firms operating in the Home country are defined over the interval [0 ; n] and indexed by h. Similarly, foreign varieties are defined as f ∈ [0 ; n∗ ]. The total number of varieties in equilibrium is endogenously determined, as well as firms’ location under free entry. Firms enter a country as long as the production is profitable, given a fixed cost of producing (consisting in F units of homogeneous good) and a variable cost that depends on skilled- and unskilled-labor wages. As firms operate under monopolistic competition, the number of produced varieties in equilibrium matches the number of operating firms. In other

10

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

words, each active firm settles in a single location to serve both markets. As the exposure of the model further shows, we retain some simplifying assumptions regarding the functioning of the labor market. Labor supply is exogenous (each worker offers one unit of labor to national firms). In each country, the labor market is perfectly competitive and should define equilibrium wages, apart from minimum wages. However, national governments maintain the purchasing power of workers by setting a fixed minimum wage (w and w∗ units of the numéraire good). As long as the minimum wage is binding, labor markets do not clear in equilibrium and some workers are left unemployed.

2.1.1

Households

Within a country, all workers are assumed to belong to the same family, that includes a representative consumer. As a result, the unemployment insurance system can be neglected from the analysis, the redistribution from employed to unemployed workers taking place inside each representative “family”.10 Optimal demand functions are derived at the aggregate national level, by considering the program of the representative consumer. In the following, the domestic household’s problem is solved, results being symmetric in the foreign country. Utility of the representative household is an increasing function of her consumption of homogeneous and differentiated goods. As in Strauss-Kahn (2005), we assume the following Cobb-Douglas consumption basket: µ 1−µ C(CX , CZ ) = CX CZ

0<µ<1

(1)

CZ is the consumption level of the homogeneous good Z and CX is a composite good of all consumed varieties of differentiated goods aggregated according to the following CES specification: σ "Z # σ−1 Z n∗ n σ−1 σ−1 CX = c(h) σ dh + c(f ) σ df 0

0

with σ ≥ 1 the constant elasticity of substitution across varieties and c(h) (c(f )) the consumption level of a variety produced in the home (foreign) country. The domestic household finances her consumption expenditures using her labor revenues and residual profits she perceives as the owner of firms. The domestic household’s income I (expressed in the numéraire good Z) thus decomposes into: I = wQ Q + wL + Π where Q is the employment level of skilled workers and L the employment level of unskilled workers. In the following, the minimum wage is assumed to be binding on the unskilled labor market, while it is set below the equilibrium wage for skilled workers (i.e. wQ > w). As ¯ whereas there is some a consequence, the labor market for skilled workers clears (Q = Q) 10

Introducing an unemployment insurance system would not alter our results as long as it is financed by lump-sum taxes on employed workers. Studying its role would be relevant in a setting with endogenous labor supply and distorsive taxes, which is left for further research.

11

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

¯ Last, Π are residual profits of positive level of unemployment for unskilled workers (L < L). local firms, equal to zero in the long run equilibrium when firms are free to enter a national market. In this setting, the budget constraint for the representative domestic household can be expressed as: Z n Z n∗ ¯ + wL p(h)c(h)dh + (2) p(f )c(f )df + CZ ≤ wQ Q 0

0

where p(h) and p(f ) are equilibrium prices for varieties produced in the domestic and foreign country respectively. The minimum wage level affects aggregate demand directly through the purchasing power of low-skilled workers and indirectly through the labor-market equilibria (i.e. through wQ and L). Maximizing the representative household’s consumption (1) under her budget constraint (2) leads to the optimal demand functions: I PX CZ = (1 − µ)I −σ  p(h) CX , c(h) = PX −σ  p(f ) CX , c(f ) = PX CX

= µ

(3) (4) h ∈ [0; n]

(5)

f ∈ [0; n∗ ]

(6)

with the associated expenditure-minimizing price index in sector X defined as: PX =

2.1.2

hR

n 0

p(h)1−σ dh +

R n∗ 0

p(f )1−σ df

1 i 1−σ

Firms in the homogeneous sector

The homogeneous good sector is perfectly competitive and integrated at the world level. Good Z is produced under a constant-returns-to-scale technology combining skilled and unskilled workers. In the domestic country, the production function is: yZ = (aL lZ )β (aQ qZ )1−β

0<β<1

with yZ the production of homogeneous good, obtained from qZ and lZ units of skilled and unskilled labor. β is assumed to be identical across countries. Profit maximization in that sector yields a decreasing relation between skilled and unskilled unit labor costs: β wQ = β 1−β (1 − β) aQ

12



w aL

−β  1−β

(7)

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

with the associated optimal demand functions for unskilled and skilled labor respectively: w wQ

= β

yZ lZ

(8)

(1 − β)

=

yZ qZ

(9)

Equation (7) helps analyzing the expected effects of minimum wage policy in terms of wage dispersion. As shown by equation (7), an increase in the domestic exogenous minimum wage level, presumably designed to sustain low-skilled workers’ purchasing power, occurs at the expense of skilled workers, whose wage decreases in terms of numéraire. By raising the marginal cost of production, such a policy indeed exerts an upward pressure on the equilibrium price for homogeneous good in the domestic country. The domestic wage for skilled workers has to decrease to preserve the law of one price in the homogeneous good market. This perverse effect on skilled wages is consistent with empirical evidence in the labor-market literature, stressing that changes in the minimum wage have a significant impact on wage inequality (see Lee (1999) for evidence on US data). Situation in the foreign market is symmetric. As the homogeneous good market is perfectly integrated at the world level, the price of good Z is equalized across countries in equilibrium. Given equation (7) and its foreign counterpart, this implies the following relationship linking relative wages for skilled and unskilled workers:11 

2.1.3

w w∗



 =

∗ wQ wQ

1−β (10)

Firms in the monopolistic sector

In the monopolistic sector, production costs can be decomposed into a fixed and a variable components. To start producing a variety, a firm incurs a fixed cost of F units of homogeneous good that implicitly defines the minimum operating profit firms must achieve for the production to be profitable (see Krugman (1991)). Once entered the market, the firm faces a technological constraint, that combines skilled and unskilled labor according to the following CES specification: h

y(h) = α

−γ

[aQ q(h)]

γ−1 γ

−γ

+ (1 − α)

[aL l(h)]

γ−1 γ

γ i γ−1

γ > 0,

0<α<1

where q(h) and l(h) are the quantities of skilled and unskilled labor used as inputs in the production of y(h) units of variety h. In this expression, α is a weighting parameter that determines the share of value added paid to skilled workers, whereas γ measures the elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled labor. Both parameters have a peculiar 11

We ensure that the Non Full Specialization condition holds, i.e. that some positive amount of homogeneous good is produced in each country. Skilled labor endowments are thus set below the level required to cover the world demand of good Z.

13

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

importance, as they determine the sensitivity of labor demand to changes in the relative cost of unskilled labor (i.e. changes in w). Once produced, variety h can be sold to the domestic household or exported. Shipping goods abroad entails transportation “iceberg” costs τ à la Samuelson (1954): to sell one unit abroad, a firm has to produce τ > 1 units because of a real loss occurring during transport.12 Let p(h) (p∗ (h)) denote the price of one unit of variety h sold in the domestic (foreign) market. The profit function of the domestic firm h is then: π(h) = p(h)c(h) + p∗ (h)c∗ (h) − wl(h) − wQ q(h) − F

(11)

The program of differentiated producers can be decomposed into two steps. First, each firm decides (or not) to enter the domestic or the foreign market. Second, it draws up its production plans by optimally setting prices and quantities to produce. The program can be solved backward by first considering the optimization problem of firms that already entered the market. Minimizing the total cost function yields the marginal cost of producing one unit of variety h (in terms of the numéraire good): 1 "  1−γ  1−γ # 1−γ wQ w (12) M C(h) = α + (1 − α) aQ aL and the associated optimal unskilled and skilled labor demands: l(h) = δy(h) q(h) = (1 − δ)y(h)

(13) (14)

with δ the share of unskilled workers in the domestic (foreign) marginal cost of producing the differentiated good (δ ∗ being similarly defined):  1−γ w δ ≡ (1 − α) 0<δ<1 aL M C(h) Firm h sets its prices p(h) and p∗ (h) so as to maximize its profit (equation (11)) given the optimal marginal cost (12) and the demand for good h from both domestic and foreign households (equation (5) and its foreign counterpart). In the monopolistic framework à la Dixit and Stiglitz (1977), firms optimally set prices by applying a constant mark-up over marginal cost, multiplied by the iceberg cost for exported goods. Respectively for domestic and foreign sales, equilibrium prices for variety h are: p(h) p∗ (h)

σ M C(h) ≡ p σ−1 σ = τ M C(h) ≡ τ p σ−1

=

12

(15) (16)

Given that our main focus is on location choices in the monopolistic good sector, we do not introduce such transport costs in the homogeneous sector. Modifying this assumption would not drastically affect our results as long as the homogeneous good is produced under constant returns to scale.

14

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

The situation in the foreign country is perfectly symmetric. Moreover, as firms in a given location are confronted with the same constraints, one can suppress indexes h and f in the following.

2.2

The general equilibrium

2.2.1

Free entry and the location of the production

To characterize the model solution, optimal demands and prices are first used to rewrite profits of domestic and foreign firms (equation (11) and its foreign counterpart) as:   ∗ µ I 1−σ I π = −F (17) + φρ σ ∆ ∆∗  ∗  µ I I + φρσ−1 −F (18) π∗ = ∗ σ ∆ ∆ with: • φ ≡ τ 1−σ the parameter called “freeness” of trade by Baldwin, Forslid, Martin, Ottaviano and Robert-Nicoud (2005). It increases between 0 and 1 when trade barriers diminish (lower τ ) or varieties become less substitutable (higher σ), • ρ ≡ M C/M C ∗ the relative cost of producing the differentiated good in the domestic market, that depends on relative unit labor costs for skilled and unskilled workers, • ∆ ≡ n + n∗ φρσ−1 and ∆∗ ≡ n∗ + nφρ1−σ transformations of the price indices in the differentiated good sector. Equations (17) and (18) deliver useful insights regarding the deep mechanisms of the model. First, they put in evidence a “Home Market Effect” in production (see Martin and Rogers (1995)): ceteris paribus, the share of local sales in the profits of monopolistic firms is higher than the share of exports as long as trade costs are strictly positive (φ < 1). This asymmetry implies that, every thing else equal, an increase in domestic demand (dI > 0) favors domestic firms more than foreign ones, leading to an increase in the relative number of firms located in the home country. Second, a cost gap in the differentiated good sector (induced here by cross-country differences in minimum wages) reduces relative profits of firms located in the high-cost country, thus its attractiveness. These cost and demand effects are key elements in the model as their interaction determines where firms ultimately locate in the long run. To determine the spatial long-run equilibrium, free-entry conditions are used, that draw profits towards zero: π=0 and π∗ = 0 (19) Combining the expressions for domestic and foreign firms profits (17) and (18) with the zeroprofit condition (19) leads to the following relation between aggregate incomes and the total number of active firms in equilibrium: µ (n + n∗ )F = (I + I ∗ ) (20) σ

15

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

As usual in the Dixit-Stiglitz’s framework, the total amount paid to cover fixed costs is proportional to the world expenditure spent in the monopolistic sector. At this point, three polar cases must be distinguished regarding the spatial distribution of production in equilibrium: • two corner equilibria in which the production of differentiated good is fully concentrated in a single country (i.e. n = 0 or n∗ = 0), • an interior equilibrium in which some varieties of the differentiated good are produced in both countries (n > 0 and n∗ > 0). In the interior equilibrium, operating profits are equalized across countries and the relative number of active firms in each country is: I(1 − φρσ−1 ) − I ∗ φ(ρσ−1 − φ) n = ∗ ∗ n I (1 − φρ1−σ ) − Iφ(ρ1−σ − φ)

(21)

Equation (21) underscores the previously discussed determinants of firms’ location decisions, namely the cost and demand determinants. In the interior equilibrium, the higher domestic demand (I/I ∗ ), the higher the relative number of firms located in the domestic country (n/n∗ ), in a convex way because of the Home Market Effect. As well, the lower the relative cost of producing differentiated goods in the Home country (ρ), the higher the relative number of domestic firms. As shown in Appendix A.1, the interior equilibrium is only sustainable for a small enough cost gap. Outside this interval, production is entirely concentrated in the low-cost country and the number of active firms is simply determined by the corresponding zero-profit condition. Table 1 summarizes the equilibrium pattern of production as a function of the relative cost of producing in each country.

Table 1: Equilibrium pattern of production Relative marg. cost ρ Productive structure

ρ

ρ CE =0

n∗

| |

IE n > 0, n∗ > 0

| |

CE n=0

CE means “Corner Equilibrium”, IE “Interior Equilibrium”; ρ and ρ defined in Appendix A.1.

2.2.2

Market equilibria

The resolution of the model is achieved considering the various market-clearing conditions: - On the skilled labor market: As the fixed minimum wage is assumed lower than the ∗ equilibrium wage for skilled workers (w < wQ and w∗ < wQ ), full employment holds ¯ ¯∗. in equilibrium on that labor-market segment, hence Q = Q and Q∗ = Q

16

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

- On the unskilled labor market: As long as the minimum wage is binding and endowments large enough, it is not balanced and the effective unskilled employment level in each country (L, L∗ ) is determined by the optimal labor demands coming from both sectors:13 = wnl + wlZ wL ∗ ∗ w L = w ∗ n∗ l ∗ + w ∗ l Z ∗

= nδ(σ − 1)F + βyZ ∗ = n∗ δ ∗ (σ − 1)F + βyZ

(22) (23)

- On each of the (n + n∗ ) differentiated goods markets: Each firm produces the amount just sufficient to cover the demand emanating from the domestic and foreign markets: y y∗

= c + τ c∗ = c∗ + τ c

- On the homogenous good market: Given i) the domestic and foreign consumers’ optimal demand (equation (4) and its foreign counterpart), and ii) the demand for good Z coming from monopolistic firms so as to cover the fixed costs, the resource constraint for the integrated world market of good Z is: ∗ y Z + yZ = (1 − µ)(I + I ∗ ) + (n + n∗ )F

In the long-run equilibrium, national equilibrium incomes solely depend on the employment ¯ + wL and I ∗ = w∗ Q ¯ ∗ + w∗ L∗ . Using the level of skilled and unskilled workers: I = wQ Q Q labor-market equilibrium conditions (equations (22) and (23)), one can see that they notably depend on the equilibrium productive pattern: I I∗

3

= yZ + n(σ − 1)F ∗ = yZ + n∗ (σ − 1)F

(24) (25)

Minimum wages and the location of production

This section focuses on the effect of a marginal increase in the domestic minimum wage (dw > 0) regards the spatial distribution of firms, starting from the symmetric equilibrium. In the symmetric equilibrium, minimum wages and labor endowments are identical across ¯ = Q ¯∗, L ¯ = L ¯ ∗ ). In that case, it is trivial to show that the number countries (w = w∗ , Q of firms entering each market is equalized across countries (n = n∗ ), as well as national ∗ incomes (I = I ∗ ), employment levels (L = L∗ ), skilled wages (wQ = wQ ) and the produc∗ tion of homogenous good (yZ = yZ ). We start from the benchmark symmetric equilibrium to investigate the properties of the model following an unilateral increase in the domestic minimum wage (dw > 0). 13

The unskilled labor market is not equilibrated in the Walrasian sense and adjustment occurs through quantities.

17

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

Analytical results are derived by differentiating the model in the specific case when unskilled labor is only required in the production of differentiated goods (i.e. when β = 0). In that case, production of homogenous good Z uses skilled labor only. As detailed in Appendix A.3.1, good Z’s market equilibrium condition thus implies that skilled wages are equal to the exogenous productivity level aQ ized in both countries and become exogenous. This simplifying assumption has the nice property of allowing analytical derivation of the effects of a domestic minimum wage increase on location decisions in optimum. Results are discussed in Section 3.1. However, it also implies that minimum wage shocks do not spread into the skilled labor market, thereby eliminating part of the story. It is thus removed in Section 3.2, which investigates the effects of a domestic minimum wage increase in the general case where β > 0.

3.1

With exogenous skilled-labor wages (β = 0)

In this section, we restrict the use of unskilled workers to the differentiated good sector and assume the homogeneous good to be produced with skilled labor only (β = 0). Equilibrium skilled wages (expressed in terms of numéraire) equal the productivity level of skilled workers aQ , as shown by Z-firms’ first-order condition (equation (7) with β = 0). As a result, minimum wage changes have no distorsive effect on the remuneration of skilled workers. To get insights about the impact of the wage shock on location decisions, the model is differentiated around the symmetric equilibrium. In a first step, we determine the short-run effect of the shock on the profitability of firms already located in both countries (i.e. for a given number of existing firms n, n∗ ). This allows to infer the long-run impact on the spatial distribution of firms in a second step. Moreover, as the fixed cost of producing is set identical across countries, one can restrict the analysis to the impact of the wage shock onto relative ∗ ≡ π∗ + F . operational profits, πop ≡ π + F and πop ∗ in the symmetric equilibrium, one can derive the Given the values for I, I ∗ , p, p∗ , PX and PX short-run elasticity of operating profits to w in each country. As detailed in Appendix A.3, it can be decomposed in two elements, the Price Competitiveness Effect (P CE hereafter) and the Income Effect (IE hereafter): φ dπop /πop σ−1 1−γ = −2(σ − 1)δ + µδ(1 − δ) (26) 2 dw/w n= (1 + φ) σ 1 +φ ∗ ˙ n ˙ =0 {z } | {z } | P CE

∗ ∗ dπop /πop dw/w n= ˙ n ˙ ∗ =0

IE

φ σ−1 φ(1 − γ) = 2(σ − 1)δ + µδ(1 − δ) 2 (1 + φ) σ 1+φ {z } | {z } | P CE

(27)

IE

The Price Competitiveness Effect is always negative for domestic firms and positive for foreign ones. The Income Effect may be positive or negative in both countries. The Price Competitiveness Effect may be rationalized as follows. The domestic policy shock leads to an increase in the cost of unskilled workers. Given that skilled wages are exogenous, the increase in w translates into an increase in the relative cost of unskilled labor (w/wQ ),

18

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

which entices domestic firms to substitute skilled to low-skilled workers. Yet, as long as both types of labor are not perfect substitutes, firms cannot fully compensate for the relative increase in production costs. By raising the relative cost of producing in the domestic country, the wage shock lowers price competitiveness of domestic firms relative to that of foreign ones, both on the local and export markets. Conversely, foreign firms competitiveness on both markets benefits from the domestic policy shock. For given values of n, n∗ and starting from the symmetric equilibrium, one can indeed show that: d(p/PX ) > 0, dw

∗ ∗ d(τ p/PX ) d(p∗ /PX ) d(τ p∗ /PX ) > 0, < 0, <0 dw dw dw

Absent any income effect, the wage shock would always negatively affect the relative attractiveness of the domestic country, as underlined by Picard and Toulemonde (2001). With free entry of firms, the relative increase in domestic production costs would entice a larger number of firms to locate and produce abroad. In that respect, the relocation of firms strengthens the negative impact of the minimum wage shock on domestic employment and production obtained in the neo-classical framework with an exogenous number of firms. However, operating profits are also altered by aggregate demand changes in the domestic country, leading to the Income Effect.14 Every thing else equal, the domestic wage shock tends to increase aggregate income by raising low-skilled workers’ purchasing power. Nevertheless, it also reduces demand for low-skilled labor coming from each domestic monopolistic firm, and aggregate unskilled labor demand as well. Besides, there is no effect on the skilled labor-market segment, given that skilled wages are left unaffected by the minimum wage shock in a context with full employment. As a result, for the existing number of firms, the income effect may be positive or negative. As shown by equations (26) and (27), the (necessary and sufficient) condition for it to be positive is γ < 1, that is the elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled workers should be low. If positive, the income effect increases profits in both countries. However, as shown by comparing both IE terms in equations (26) and (27), the upward pressure is stronger for local firms than for foreign ones because of the Home Market Effect. Ceteris paribus, the income effect enhances the domestic country’s attractiveness in relative terms. Short-run analysis of the changes in the profits of domestic and foreign incumbents further allows to derive the effect of the wage shock on the spatial distribution of firms. As firms are free to decide where to locate, the ultimate long-run impact on the relative number of firms located in the home country depends on the short-run changes in profits in the domestic country relative to those in the foreign one. Namely, the minimum wage increase leads to a concentration of firms in the domestic country if the short-run elasticity of domestic profits In the special case where skilled wages are ultimately exogenous, foreign aggregate income I ∗ remains unaffected by the unilateral change in w in the short run. This will no longer be the case when β 6= 0. 14

19

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

to the wage shock is larger than the elasticity of foreign profits. It is the case if:15 φ (σ − 1) 1−φ −4(σ − 1)δ >0 + µδ(1 − δ)(1 − γ) (1 + φ)2 σ 1+φ {z } | {z } |

(28)

IE

P CE

Every thing else equal, the price competitiveness effect always benefits to foreign firms, thereby reducing the domestic country’s relative attractiveness. On the other hand, as long as the income effect is positive (γ < 1), it raises domestic attractiveness in relative terms as well because of the home market effect. If strong enough, the income effect may even more than compensate for the price competitiveness loss, in what case the relative number of firms located in the domestic country rises when the minimum wage increases. As shown by equation (28), the balance between the cost and demand effects depends on the parameters γ, δ, µ, and φ. Their influence goes by different transmission channels. • µ, γ and δ affect the response of domestic income to the wage shock (dI/dw). The lower the elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled labor in the differentiated sector (γ), the more limited the substitution of skilled to unskilled workers induced by the relative increase in w/wQ and the stronger the income effect. As well, low δ and high µ tend to favor the income effect every thing else equal. • The size of trade barriers (φ) alters the impact of a change in aggregate income on domestic profits relative to foreign ones in the short run (i.e. dπ/dI relative to dπ ∗ /dI). The higher φ, i.e. the lower transport costs, the smaller the benefit of being located in the market whose national income increases.16 When international trade barriers are low (φ high), following the domestic minimum wage shock, more firms choose to enter the foreign market to benefit from an improved price competitiveness, and to export on the domestic market whose income has increased with the minimum wage shock. This last result is of particular interest for economic policy design in the current context of trade liberalization. A high-minimum wage policy is all the more likely to negatively affect the country’s relative attractiveness as international trade is free (φ high). In that case indeed, given that skilled labor cost is unaffected by the minimum wage increase, pressures exerted by cost competitiveness motives are more prevalent in the arbitrage faced by firms regarding location choices. This result however relies on the exogeneity of skilled wages, and may accordingly be altered when wQ adjusts to changes in w, as investigated in the next section.

3.2

With endogenous skilled wages adjustment (β 6= 0)

Analysis driven in Section 3.1 has been conducted in the particular case where skilled wages are independent of minimum wage policy, achieved by setting β = 0. We now depart from 15

See details in Appendix A.3. Note that the impact of the elasticity of substitution across varieties σ is ambiguous. As σ is high, competition between firms is keener, and the negative PCE stronger. Yet it also strengthens the Home Market Effect by reducing φ, raising the (possibly positive) IE. 16

20

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

that assumption to take into account the potential distorsive effects of minimum wage policy on the whole remuneration structure. As shown by equation (7) when β 6= 0, an increase in w leads to a drop in the equilibrium wage of skilled workers wQ . Endogenous adjustments of wQ alter the impact of the wage shock on firms’ location decisions, with respect to those derived in Section 3.1. Taking into account endogenous skilled wages adjustment is therefore likely to enrich the analysis concerning the impact of an unilateral minimum wage increase on location decisions. We investigate that point by relying on numerical simulations of the model, given the calibration of structural parameters displayed in Table 2.

Table 2: Calibration µ 0.55

α 0.53

F 1

aQ 1

aL 0.86

γ 0.7

β 0.4

σ 6

τ 1.2

sQ 0.5

The share of differentiated goods in the utility function µ is taken from Strauss-Kahn (2005). The value for α is taken from Salanié (2000)’s estimate of the share of skilled workers in the French value-added during the 1990s. The literature delivers contrasted results regards the value of the elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled workers. We set γ = 0.7 based on Gianella (1999).17 The ratio aL /aQ is chosen so as to reproduce the relative productivity level of unskilled workers observed in the data (arbitrarily setting aQ = 1).18 The value τ = 1.2 lies within the range commonly found in the literature (see Hummels (2001) among others). The elasticity of substitution across varieties σ = 6 corresponds to a mark-up rate of 20%, consistently with Broda and Weinstein’s (2006) estimates. We arbitrarily set the fixed cost of production F = 1.19 The calibration of the share of unskilled labor in sector Z’s production β obeys the following technical requirements: i) the minimum wage level has to be higher than the unskilled wage that would prevail in the flexible case, for the constraint to be binding on the unskilled labor market, and ii) this should not be the case on the skilled-labor market. Meeting the two requirements (namely the second one) imposes some constraint on the calibration of β, which is set to 0.4.20 Last, and as discussed below, ¯ Q the model’s predictions are sensitive to the calibrated value of sQ ≡ Q+ ¯ L ¯ , that is the share 17

Note that this calibration meets the condition for the income effect to be positive in the case β = 0. Calibration is based on French data, using information delivered by the OECD-STAN database. Productivity in the services sector is taken as reference for aL , whereas the productivity of skilled workers corresponds to the productivity in total manufacturing. Reference year is 2000. 19 Simulation exercises show that the value for F does not play a crucial role in our results. 20 Precisely, we solve the program as follows. First, the model is solved without imposing any minE E imum wage constraint, leading to equilibrium wages {wL , wQ } on both unskilled and skilled labor ¯ and Q). ¯ We then impose a minimum wage level w that is 1% markets (for exogenous values of L E E superior to wL , checking that w < wQ . 18

21

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

of skilled workers in the working population. In what follows, it is set equal to 0.5, which is presumably a lower bond when considering the actual share of minimum-wage workers in OECD countries. We check that the value could be increased without altering qualitative results. Given calibration summed up in Table 2, the model is simulated to study the effects of an unilateral increase in the domestic minimum wage w on optimal firms’ location decisions. Figure 1 reports the equilibrium values of n and n∗ , for increasing values of w relative to w∗ .21

Figure 1: Spatial impact of a domestic shock on minimum wages 1.76 n

1.75

n* symmetric case

1.74 1.73 1.72 1.71 1.7 1.69 1.68

1

1.002

1.004

1.006

1.008

1.01

w/w∗

In the general case with β 6= 0, one can still rationalize the impact of minimum wage policy on the spatial distribution of firms into a price competitiveness effect (PCE) and an income effect (IE). However, endogenous changes in the remuneration of skilled workers substantially affect both mechanisms. First regarding PCE, the decrease in wQ reduces domestic monopolistic firms’ competitiveness loss induced by the minimum wage increase. Second, the Income Effect is affected by the reduction in the equilibrium wage of skilled workers as well. As previously (β = 0), the upward pressure on aggregate income induced by the increase in w is counteracted by the decrease in unskilled employment. Besides, it is now dampened by the decrease in wQ under full employment on the skilled labor-market segment. Every thing else equal, endogeneity in wQ reduces the case of a positive Income Effect with the policy shock. The final outcome is again driven by the balance between both effects. Simulations show that it is notably affected by the share of skilled workers in the working population (sQ ), according to the following underlying mechanisms: As for the symmetric equilibrium, for each value of w departing from w∗ , we check that the model’s solution is the interior one, and that minimum wages values are still binding as required. 21

22

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

• The Income Effect is all the more negative as the share of skilled workers is high. With endogenous skilled wages, the remuneration of this labor-market segment is negatively affected by the wage shock (as shown by equation (7)). This is all the more likely to imply a negative income effect as the share of skilled workers in the working population is high. • The Price Competitiveness Effect is shown to be sensitive to sQ as well. Namely, the lower sQ , the less negative the competitiveness loss induced by the minimumwage shock. This is because, under decreasing marginal productivity of labor the equilibrium wage of skilled workers decreases relatively more when the supply of ¯ (hence sQ ) is small. Would the endogenous decrease in wQ be skilled workers Q strong enough, the minimum wage shock could even imply a positive PCE. However, simulation results suggest that this is the case for an implausibly low share of skilled workers in the population. For reasonable values of the parameter sQ , the PCE induced by the minimum wage shock remains negative, and is reinforced by a negative IE. Accordingly, the minimum wage increase reduces the domestic country’s attractiveness, as shown in Figure 1 where n/n∗ decreases all the more since w/w∗ rises. When wQ adjusts to changes in w, the minimum-wage shock is thus more likely to induce an attractiveness loss for the high minimum-wage country because the positive impact on unskilled workers’ income is partially compensated by a drop in the remuneration of skilled workers. Next section asks how these results are affected by changes in other key parameters of the model.

3.3

Sensitivity analysis

Section 3.1 derives analytical conditions under which an unilateral increase in w positively influences the propensity of firms to locate in the high-minimum wage country. According to equation (28), it namely depends on i) the degree of substitution between skilled and unskilled workers in the differentiated sector (γ should be low), and ii) the size of trade costs (τ should be high). By symmetry, this section investigates the results sensitivity to both parameters under endogenous skilled wages. To that aim, we simulate the model for increasing values of γ and φ and look at how it affects the relative number of firms located in the domestic country when its minimum wage is 1% higher than in the foreign country. Other structural parameters are calibrated as reported in Table 2. Results are illustrated in Figure 2.

Sensitivity analysis to γ: We first investigate the role of the elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled labor in the differentiated good sector. As displayed in the left-panel of Figure 2, the ratio n/n∗ is all the lower as γ is high. This is consistent with our previous analytical results derived in Section 3.1, according to which the case of an attractiveness gain for the high-minimum wage country becomes less and less likely as skilled and unskilled workers become more substitutable. Similar mechanisms are 23

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

Figure 2: Sensitivity analysis Relative number of firms in the asymetric case

Relative number of firms in the asymetric case 1

n/n*

n/n*

0.962

0.98

0.961 0.96

0.96

0.959

0.94 0.958

0.92

0.957 0.956

0.9 0.955

0.88

0.954 0.953

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

γ

0.8

0.9

1

1.1

1.2

0.86

0.1

0.2

0.3

φ

0.4

0.5

at work with endogenous skilled wages. The income effect is all the more negative as γ is high and the home country’s relative attractiveness as well.

Sensitivity analysis to φ: Section 3.1 makes clear that, with exogenous skilled wages, a increase in w all the more reduces the home country’s attractiveness as trade costs are low, i.e. as φ is high. This is still the case when endogenous skilled wage adjustments are taken into account, as shown by the sensitivity analysis to φ reported in the right-panel of Figure 2. As in the case with exogenous skilled wages, the attractiveness loss of the high minimumwage country is all the stronger since international trade is liberalized: the ratio n/n∗ decreases with φ. First, trade liberalization makes the cost-competitiveness of firms more prevalent in international competition. Every thing else equal, the negative PCE induces firms to locate in the low-cost country. Second, with endogenous skilled wages, this effect is strengthened by the negative income effect in the home country. For both price-competitiveness and market potential motives, firms are all the more enticed to settle in the foreign country as international trade is free.

4

Conclusion

Using insights of the labor-market literature and the new trade theory, the paper contributes to the living debate on the controversial effects of labor-market policies on attractiveness for FDI. Precisely, our theoretical framework puts into evidence the link between minimum wage policy and the rationale behind firms’ location choices in an international setting. In that framework, we show that the impact of a minimum wage increase on the country’s attractiveness is far from being trivial. Firms’ location decisions are affected through both the

24

0.6

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

negative cost effect of the wage shock, and the possibly positive effect on aggregate demand. The final effect crucially depends on adjustments on the labor market. Precisely, we show that it depends on i) the extent to which skilled wages adjust to minimum wage changes, ii) the magnitude of the substitution effects between skilled and unskilled workers, and iii) the share of skilled labor among workers. Namely, when neglecting the distorsive effects on the remuneration of skilled workers, the minimum wage shock may benefit to the home country in terms of attractiveness, because it increases aggregate demand. However, for reasonable parameter values, this is no longer the case when endogenous changes in the equilibrium wage for skilled workers are taken into account. Last, our overall results suggest that the perverse effect of a high-minimum wage policy on the country’s attractiveness for FDI is strengthened in a world of increasing free trade. This explains the increasing interest of political and economic circles in the question of the efficiency of national labor-market institutions in a more and more globalized world.

25

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

References Baldwin, R., Forslid, R., Martin, P., Ottaviano, G. and Robert-Nicoud, F. (2005), The Footloose Capital Model, in ‘Economic Geography and Public Choice’, Princeton University Press, chapter 3. Bhaskar, V. and To, T. (1999), ‘Minimum Wages for Ronald McDonald Monopsonies: A Theory of Monopsonistic Competition’, Economic Journal 190, 190–203. Biscourp, P. and Kramarz, F. (2003), ‘Internationalisation des entreprises industrielles et emploi: une analyse sur la période 1986-1992’, Economie et Statistique 363-365, 60–91. Broda, C. and Weinstein, D. E. (2006), ‘Globalization and the Gains from Variety’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2), 541–585. Cahuc, P. and Michel, J. (1996), ‘Minimum Wage, Unemployment and Growth’, European Economic Review 40, 1463–1482. Cahuc, P. and Zylberberg, A. (1999), Job Protection, Minimum Wage and Unemployment, Technical Report 9914, CEPREMAP Working paper. Card, D. and Krueger, A. (1994), ‘Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania Wage’, American Economic Review 84, 772–793. Dewit, G., Görg, H. and Montagna, C. (2003), Should I Stay or Should I Go? A Note on Employment Protection, Domestic Anchorage, and FDI, IZA Discussion Papers 845, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). Dickens, R., Machin, S. and Manning, A. (1999), ‘The Effects of Minimum Wages on Employment: Theory and Evidence from Britain’, Journal of Labor Economics 17(1), 1– 22. Dixit, A. and Stiglitz, J. (1977), ‘Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity’, American Economic Review 67(3), 297–308. Dolado, J., Felgueroso, F. and Jimeno, J. (2000), The Role of the Minimum Wage in the Welfare State: An Appraisal, Technical Report 2452, CEPR Discussion Paper. Dolado, J., Kramarz, F., Machin, S., Manning, A., Margolis, D. and Teulings, C. (1996), ‘The Economic Impact of Minimum Wages in Europe’, Economic Policy 23, 317–372. Gianella, C. (1999), Une Estimation de l’élasticité de l’emploi Peu Qualifié à son Coût, Technical Report G9912 bis, INSEE Document de travail. Hajkova, D., Golub, S., Mizra, D., Nicoletti, G. and Yoo, K. (2003), Policy and International Integration: Influences on Trade and Foreign Direct Investment, Technical Report 356, OECD Economic Dpt Working Paper. Hummels, D. (2001), ‘Time as Trade Barrier’, Purdue University Working paper .

26

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

Javorcik, B. S. and Spatareanu, M. (2005), ‘Do Foreign Investors Care about Labor Market Regulations?’, Review of World Economics (Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv) 127(3), 375– 403. Kramarz, F. and Philippon, T. (2001), ‘The Impact of Differential Payroll Tax Subsidies on Minimum Wage Employment’, Journal of Public Economics 82, 115–46. Krugman, P. (1991), ‘Increasing Returns and Economic Geography’, Journal of Political Economy 99(3), 483–99. Laroque, G. and Salanié, B. (1999), ‘Breaking Down Married Female Non-Employment in France’, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers 2239. Lee, D. (1999), ‘Wage inequality in the United States during the 1980s: Rsising dispersion or falling minimum wage?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 977–1023. Machin, S. and Manning, A. (1996), ‘Employment and the Introduction of a Minimum Wage in Great-Britain’, Economic Journal 106, 667–673. Manning, A. (1995), ‘How Do We Know That Real Wages are Too High?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 1111–1126. Markusen, J. and Matusz, S. (2002), ‘Discriminating among Alternative Theories of the Multinational Enterprise’, Review of International Economics 10(4), 694–707. Martin, P. and Rogers, C. A. (1995), ‘Industrial location and public infrastructure’, Journal of International Economics 39(3-4), 335–351. Picard, P. M. and Toulemonde, E. (2001), The Impact of Labor Markets on Emergence and Persistence of Regional Asymmetries, IZA Discussion Papers 248, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). Portugal, P. and Cardoso, A. R. (2006), ‘Disentangling the Minimum Wage Puzzle: An Analysis of Worker Accessions and Separations’, Journal of the European Economic Association 4(5), 988–1013. Salanié, B. (2000), ‘Une Maquette Analytique de Long Terme du Marché du Travail’, Economie et Prévisions 146, 1–13. Samuelson, P. A. (1954), ‘The Transfer Problem and Transport Costs, II: Analysis of Effects of Trade Impediments’, Economic Journal 64, 264–289. Strauss-Kahn, V. (2005), ‘Firms Location Decision Across Asymmetric Countries and Employment Inequality’, European Economic Review 49, 299–320.

27

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

A

Appendix

A.1

The interior equilibrium

In the interior equilibrium, the relative number of firms in each country is jointly determined by the nullity of (17) and (18) and the relative number of active firms in each country is: I(1 − φρσ−1 ) − I ∗ φ(ρσ−1 − φ) n = ∗ ∗ n I (1 − φρ1−σ ) − Iφ(ρ1−σ − φ) This relation is only valid in the interior equilibrium, i.e. for n/n∗ > 0. It is the case if both I(1 − φρσ−1 ) − I ∗ φ(ρσ−1 − φ) > 0

(29)

I ∗ (1 − φρ1−σ ) − Iφ(ρ1−σ − φ) > 0

(30)

and Manipulating equation (29) yields that: I(1 − φρσ−1 ) − I ∗ φ(ρσ−1 − φ) > 0 I + φ2 I ∗ ⇔ ρσ−1 < ≡ρ φ(I + I ∗ ) Besides, after some calculus on equation (30), you get that: I ∗ (1 − φρ1−σ ) − Iφ(ρ1−σ − φ) > 0 φ(I + I ∗ ) ≡ρ ⇔ ρσ−1 > 2 φ I + I∗ Taken together, this means that condition (21) holds if and only if: φ(I + I ∗ ) < φ2 I + I ∗

ρσ−1

<

I + φ2 I ∗ φ(I + I ∗ )

For this to hold, one has to ensure that it is always the case that: I + φ2 I ∗ φ(I + I ∗ ) < 2 ∗ φ I +I φ(I + I ∗ ) that is: [I + φ2 I ∗ ][φ2 I + I ∗ ] > φ2 (+ + I ∗ )2 ⇒ I ∗ I(1 − φ2 )2 > 0 Provided that both aggregate incomes are positive, it it always true that

28

φ(I+I ∗ ) φ2 I+I ∗

<

I+φ2 I ∗ φ(I+I ∗ ) .

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages ∗

) As long as ρσ−1 < φ(I+I φ2 I+I ∗ , production is entirely concentrated in the domestic (low mini∗ mum wage) country (i.e. n = 0). This corner equilibrium is stable because no foreign firm has an incentive to enter the foreign market:

 I∗ σ−1 I + φρ −F nφρ1−σ n  ∗  I + φ2 I F ∗ − (I + I ) I + I∗ φρ1−σ µ σ

E {Π∗ (f )|n∗ = 0} = =

which is negative, provided that ρσ−1 <



φ(I+I ∗ ) φ2 I+I ∗ .

2 ∗

I+φ I On the other hand, if ρσ−1 > φ(I+I ∗ ) , production is entirely concentrated in the foreign country (i.e. n = 0), as the production in the domestic country is unprofitable:

E {Π(h)|n = 0} = =

which is negative, provided that ρσ−1 >

A.2

 ∗ I 1−σ I + φρ −F n∗ φρσ−1 n∗   F I + φ2 I ∗ ∗ − (I + I ) I + I∗ φρσ−1 µ σ



I+φ2 I ∗ φ(I+I ∗ ) .

The general equilibrium in the corner equilibrium

This section details one of the two corner equilibria, when n = 0 and n∗ > 0. The second one (when n∗ = 0 and n > 0) can be inferred by symmetry. As soon as:

ρσ−1 >

1 + φ2 I ∗ φ(I + I ∗ )

the relative marginal cost is so low in the foreign country, that all firms are enticed to enter the foreign market to produce and serve it. The number of differentiated varieties produced in the domestic country becomes null. As a result, n = 0 while n∗ > 0. In such a corner equilibrium, the general equilibrium solution is defined by the following

29

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

system: wQ ∗ wQ

I I



∗ M CX

A.3 A.3.1

= aQ β = aQ β

β 1−β

β 1−β



w aL



w∗ aL

(1 − β) (1 − β)

−β  1−β

−β  1−β

= yZ ∗ = yZ + n∗ (σ − 1)F 1 "   ∗ 1−γ # 1−γ ∗ 1−γ wQ w + (1 − α) = α aQ aL

n∗

=

∗ yZ + yZ

=

µ I + I∗ σ F (1 − µ)(I + I ∗ ) + n∗ F

Minimum wage shocks and location decisions under exogenous skilled wages The case of exogenous skilled wages (β = 0)

In the following, we derive analytical results in the special case where unskilled workers are only in use in the differentiated good sector, whereas good Z is entirely produced from skilled workers. Analytically, this is achieved by setting β equal to 0. This is a convenient case to study because equilibrium skilled wages are then equalized across countries and insensitive to minimum wage shocks. In that case indeed, Z-firms’ first-order condition in both countries (equation (7) and its foreign counterpart) yield: 1=

∗ wQ wQ ∗ = ⇔ wQ = wQ = aQ aQ aQ

Moreover, as unskilled workers are only employed by differentiated good producers, labormarket equilibria imply: wL = nδ(σ − 1)F w L∗ = n∗ δ ∗ (σ − 1)F ∗

with δ and δ ∗ defined as in the general case.

A.3.2

Symmetric equilibrium

In the symmetric equilibrium, minimum wages and labor endowments are set identical across ¯=Q ¯∗, L ¯=L ¯ ∗ ). As a consequence, the number of firms entering each countries (w = w∗ , Q

30

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

market is identical in both countries, i.e. the equilibrium is an interior one. From equations (20), (21), (24) and (25), we characterize the symmetric equilibrium as follows:

n = n∗ I = I∗ Q = Q∗ L = L∗

¯ µ Q σ − µ(σ − 1)δ F σ ¯ = Q σ − µ(σ − 1)δ ¯ = Q ¯ µ(σ − 1)δ Q = σ − µ(σ − 1)δ w

=

In that case, as trade flows of differentiated goods are balanced, each country produces the quantity of homogeneous good necessary to cover the representative household’s consumption and the fixed costs paid by domestic firms: ∗ yZ = y Z = CZ + nF

A.3.3

Impact of a minimum wage shock

After writing operating profit of domestic firms as follows:

π

op

py µ = = σ σ

"

p PX

1−σ

 I+

τp PX

#

1−σ I



(31)

we can decompose the short-term effect of the wage shock on domestic firms’ operational profits in two elements: dπ op /π op dπ op /π op dI/I = dw/w dI/I dw/w | {z } Income Effect

∗ ∗ d(p/PX )/(p/PX ) dπ op /π op dπ op /π op d(τ p/PX )/(τ p/PX ) + + ∗ ∗ d(p/PX )/(p/PX ) dw/w d(τ p/PX )/(τ p/PX ) dw/w | {z } Price Competitiveness Effect

31

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007-16

Totally differentiating (31) around the symmetric equilibrium derived in A.3.2, we get:

=

dI/I dw/w

=

op

op

1−σ p I PX  1−σ 1−σ  p I+ Pτ ∗p I∗ PX X 

dπ op /π op dI/I

¯ I−Q I (1

− γ)(1 − δ) =ES

=

(1 − σ)

d(p/PX )/(p/PX ) dw/w

=

n∗ φδ nρ1−σ +n∗ φ

=ES 

∗ ∗ d(τ p/PX )/(τ p/PX ) dw/w

=

µδ σ−1 1+φ σ (1

p I PX 1−σ  1−σ  τp p I∗ I+ P ∗ PX X

dπ /π d(p/PX )/(p/PX )

=

1 1+φ

(1 − σ) 

p PX

n∗ δ nφρ1−σ +n∗

=ES

=ES

1−σ 1+φ

=ES

φ(1−σ) 1+φ

φδ 1+φ 1−σ

I∗  1−σ I+ Pτ ∗p I∗

τp P∗ X

1−σ

− γ)(1 − δ)

1−σ



dπ op /π op ∗ )/(τ p/P ∗ ) d(τ p/PX X

=ES

X

δ 1+φ

This allows us to derive the expression of domestic profits to the domestic minimum wage around the symmetric equilibrium: σ−1 1−γ φ dπ op /π op ES + µδ(1 − δ) = −2(σ − 1)δ dw/w (1 + φ)2 σ 1+φ which is positive if: µ(1 − δ)(1 − γ) > σ

2φ 1+φ

Using the same reasoning as previously, we can decompose the effect of the wage shock on the foreign firms’ profits (in the short run), in two elements: dπ op ∗ /π op ∗ dπ op ∗ /π op ∗ dI/I = dw/w dI/I dw/w | {z } Income Effect

∗ ∗ d(τ p∗ /PX )/(τ p∗ /PX ) dπ op ∗ /π op ∗ dπ op ∗ /π op ∗ d(p∗ /PX )/(p∗ /PX ) + + ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ d(τ p /PX )/(τ p /PX ) dw/w d(p /PX )/(p /PX ) dw/w | {z } Price Competitiveness Effect

32

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

where: 

dπ op ∗ /π op ∗ dI/I

=

dI/I dw/w

=



τ p∗ PX

τ p∗ PX

1−σ

¯ I−Q I (1

1−σ

I 1−σ  p∗ I∗ I+ P ∗



=

(1 − σ) 

d(τ p∗ /PX )/(τ p∗ /PX ) dw/w

=

−n∗ ρ1−σ δ nρ1−σ +n∗ φ

τ p∗ PX

dπ /π ∗ )/(p∗ /P ∗ ) d(p∗ /PX X

=

∗ ∗ d(p∗ /PX )/(p∗ /PX ) dw/w

=

(1 − σ) 

− γ)(1 − δ)

I  1−σ p∗ I+ P ∗ I∗

=ES

(1−σ)φ 1+φ

=ES

1−σ 1+φ

X

=ES

−δ 1+φ 1−σ

p∗ P∗ X

 ∗ 1−σ

τp PX

−nφρ1−σ δ nφρ1−σ +n∗

µδ σ−1 1+φ σ (1

∗ 1−σ

τp PX

1−σ

 op ∗

φ 1+φ

X

− γ)(1 − δ) =ES

dπ op ∗ /π op ∗ d(τ p∗ /PX )/(τ p∗ /PX )

op ∗

=ES

=ES

I∗  1−σ ∗ I+ Pp∗ I∗ X

−φδ 1+φ

As a result, we get: σ−1 φ(1 − γ) dπ op ∗ /π op ∗ ES φ + µδ(1 − δ) >0 = 2(σ − 1)δ 2 dw/w (1 + φ) σ 1+φ In the long-run, the impact of the wage shock on the country’s attractiveness is determined by its relative effect on domestic and foreign operational profits. Namely, the relative number of domestic firms increases if the elasticity of operational profits to the shock is higher than the elasticity of foreign profits: −2(σ−1)δ

φ σ−1 1−γ φ σ−1 φ(1 − γ) + µδ(1−δ) > 2(σ−1)δ + µδ(1−δ) (1 + φ)2 σ 1+φ (1 + φ)2 σ 1+φ ⇔ −4(σ − 1)δ

φ σ−1 1−φ + µδ(1 − δ)(1 − γ) >0 2 (1 + φ) σ 1+φ

We obtain equation (28).

33

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007 - 16

List of working papers released by CEPII No

Title

1

Authors

2007-15 MIRAGE, Updated Versio of the Model for Trade Policy Analysis Focus on Agriculture and Dynamics

Y. Decreux & H. Valin

2007-14 Mondialisation des services de la mesure à l'analyse

I. Bensidoun & D. Ünal-Kesenci

2007-13 How are wages set in Beijing 2007-12 IMF Quotas at Year 2030

2007-11 FDI and Credit Constraints: Firm Level Evidence in China 2007-10 Fiscal Policy in Real Time

J. De Sousa & S. Poncet A. Bénassy-Quéré, S. Béreau, Y. Decreux, C. Gouel & S. Poncet J. Héricourt & S. Poncet J. Cimadomo

2007-09

Global Ageing and Macroeconomic Consequences of Demographic Uncertainty in a Multi-regional Model

J. Alho & V. Borgy

2007-08

The Effect of Domestic Regulation on Services Trade Revisited

C. Schwellnus

2007-07

The location of domestic and foreign production affiliates by French multinational firms

2007-06

Specialisation across Varieties within Products and North-South Competition Trade Costs and the Home Market Effect

2007-05 2007-04

The Impact of Regulations on Agricultural Trade: Evidence from SPS and TBT Agreements

T.Mayer I. Méjean B. Néfussi L. Fontagné, G. Gaulier & S. Zignago M. Crozet & F. Trionfetti A.-C. Disdier, L. Fontagné

1

Working papers are circulated free of charge as far as stocks are available; thank you to send your request to CEPII, Sylvie Hurion, 9, rue Georges-Pitard, 75015 Paris, or by fax : (33) 01 53 68 55 04 or by e-mail [email protected]. Also available on: \\www.cepii.fr. Working papers with * are out of print. They can nevertheless be consulted and downloaded from this website. 1

Les documents de travail sont diffusés gratuitement sur demande dans la mesure des stocks disponibles. Merci d’adresser votre demande au CEPII, Sylvie Hurion, 9, rue Georges-Pitard, 75015 Paris, ou par fax : (33) 01 53 68 55 04 ou par e-mail [email protected]. Egalement disponibles sur : \\www.cepii.fr. Les documents de travail comportant * sont épuisés. Ils sont toutefois consultable sur le web CEPII.

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

& M. Mimouni 2007-03

International Comparisons of Living Standards by Equivalent Incomes

2007-02

Does Risk Aversion Drive Financial Crises? Testing the Predictive Power of Empirical Indicators

V. Coudert & M. Gex

2007-01

Asian Catch Up, World Growth and International Capital Flows in the XXIst Century : A Prospective Analysis with the INGENUE 2 Model

M. Aglietta, V. Borgy, J. Château, M. Juillard, J. Le Cacheux, G. Le Garrec & V. Touzé

2006-27

Current Account Reversals and Long Term Imbalances: Application to the Central and Eastern European Countries

K. Benhima & O. Havrylchyk

2006-26

On Legal Origins and Brankruptcy Laws: the European Experience (1808-1914)

2006-25

Taux d'intérêt et marchés boursiers : une analyse empirique de l'intégration financière internationale

2006-24

Changing Patterns of Domestic and Cross-Border Fiscal Policy Multipliers in Europe and the US

2006-23

Market Access Impact on Individual Wage: Evidence from China

2006-22

FDI in Chinese Cities: Spillovers and Impact on Growth

2006-21

Taux d'intérêt et marchés boursiers : une analyse empirique de l'intégration financière internationale

2006-20

World Consistent Equilibrium Exchange Rates

2006-19

Institutions and Bilateral Asset Holdings

2006-18

Vertical Production Networks: Evidence from France

2006-17

Import Prices, Variety and the Extensive Margin of Trade

2006-16

The Long Term Growth Prospects of the World Economy: Horizon 2050

2006-15

Economic Integration in Asia: Bilateral Free Trade Agreements Versus Asian Single Market

M. Fleurbaey & G. Gaulier

J. Sgard V. Borgy & V. Mignon A. Bénassy-Quéré & J. Cimadomo L. Hering & S. Poncet N. Madariaga & S. Poncet

V. Borgy & V. Mignon A. Bénassy-Quéré, A. Lahrèche-Révil & V. Mignon V. Salins & A. Bénassy-Quéré M. Fouquin, L. Nayman & L. Wagner G. Gaulier & I. Méjean S. Poncet M. H. Bchir & M. Fouquin

CEPII, Working Paper No 2007 - 16

2006-14

Foreign Direct Investment in China: Reward or Remedy?

2006-13

Short-Term Fiscal Spillovers in a Monetary Union

2006-12

Can Firms’ Location Decisions Counteract the Balassa-Samuelson Effect?

2006-11

Who’s Afraid of Tax Competition? Harmless Tax Competition from the New European Member States

2006-10

A Quantitative Assessment of the Outcome of the Doha Development Agenda

2006-09

Disparities in Pension Financing in Europe: Economic and Financial Consequences

2006-08

Base de données CHELEM-BAL du CEPII

2006-07

Deindustrialisation and the Fear of Relocations in the Industry

H. Boulhol & L. Fontagné

2006-06

A Dynamic Perspective for the Reform of the Stability and Gowth Pact

C. Deubner

2006-05

China’s Emergence and the Reorganisation of Trade Flows in Asia

2006-04

Who Pays China's Bank Restructuring Bill?

O. Havrylchyk & S. Poncet A. Bénassy-Quéré I. Méjean A. Lahrèche-Révil Y. Decreux & L. Fontagné J. Château & X. Chojnicki H. Boumellassa & D. Ünal-Kesenci

G. Gaulier, F. Lemoine & D. Ünal-Kesenci G. Ma

Titre

CEPII DOCUMENTS DE TRAVAIL / WORKING PAPERS

Si vous souhaitez recevoir des Documents de travail, merci de remplir le coupon-réponse ci-joint et de le retourner à : Should you wish to receive copies of the CEPII’s Working papers, just fill the reply card and return it to:

Sylvie HURION – Publications CEPII – 9, rue Georges-Pitard – 75740 Paris – Fax : (33) 1.53.68.55.04 [email protected] M./Mme / Mr./Mrs .................................................................................................................. Nom-Prénom / Name-First name ............................................................................................. Titre / Title ............................................................................................................................... Service / Department ................................................................................................................ Organisme / Organisation......................................................................................................... Adresse / Address ..................................................................................................................... Ville & CP / City & post code.................................................................................................. Pays / Country .............................................................. Tél. ..................................................... Your e-mail .............................................................................................................................. Désire recevoir les Document de travail du CEPII n° : Wish to receive the CEPII’s Working Papers No: .................................................................. .................................................................................................................................................. .................................................................................................................................................. .................................................................................................................................................. .................................................................................................................................................. .................................................................................................................................................. .................................................................................................................................................. ..................................................................................................................................................

F

Souhaite être placé sur la liste de diffusion permanente (pour les bibliothèques) Wish to be placed on the standing mailing list (for Libraries).

Location Decisions and Minimum Wages

DÉCISIONS DE LOCALISATION ET SALAIRES MINIMUMS. RÉSUMÉ NON-TECHNIQUE. L'impact des règles de fonctionnement du marché du travail sur les ...

326KB Sizes 0 Downloads 491 Views

Recommend Documents

Firms' location decisions and Minimum Wages
Tel: (+33 1) 34 25 61 71, Email: [email protected] ..... benchmark a framework in which both wages equalize labor demand and supply. When sim- ulating the ...

Firms' location decisions and Minimum Wages
Keywords: Minimum wage, Home Market Effect, Firms' location decisions ...... loose Capital Model, in `Economic Geography and Public Choice', Princeton ...

Minimum Wages Notification.pdf
la- 173] ubZ fnYyh] c`gLifrokj] tuojh 19] 2017@ikS"k 29] 1938. No. 173] NEW DELHI, THURSDAY, JANUARY 19, 2017/PAUSA 29, 1938. ᮰म और रोजगार मᮢं ...

minimum wages, market inflexibilities and female ...
Neumark and Wascher (2004), I show that there is evidence that minimum wages reduce female employment in OECD countries in the data. Moreover, employment effects are more significant in countries with strict employment protection laws. Effect on part

Base decisions on customer location
longitude, street address, business name, current traffic conditions, or live transit ... Call ​startActivityForResult()​, passing it the intent and a pre-defined request.

Minimum wages and taxation in competitive labor ...
heterogeneous workers with either continuous skill types as in Mirrlees (1971) or, more often, two skill types ..... ings translate into large changes in Θ. For later ...

MINIMUM WAGES AND PRODUCTIVITY IN OECD ...
country data on minimum wages for 12 OECD countries over the period 1979-2003, we ... wage relativities between skilled and unskilled jobs and preventing ...

Plant location with minimum inventory - Springer Link
fractional solution we were able to derive integer solutions within 4% of optimality. ... F. Barahona, D. Jensen / Mathematical Programming 83 (1998) 101-111.

Minimum Wages and Hours of Work
Apr 18, 2018 - small employment response can be explained by a quantitatively large expansion in hours. This fact comes from equation (2.13), which shows that w. Θ (w). Θ(w) is less ..... 5They assert: If the wage bill elasticity is negative, teens

MINIMUM WAGES AND PRODUCTIVITY IN OECD ...
country data on minimum wages for 12 OECD countries over the period 1979-2003, ... Minimum wages; Industry-level data; Cross-country analysis; Difference-in- ... the difference between productivity and wage growth after training (see e.g. ...

Minimum wages Act 1948 MCQ with Answers.pdf
5. Loading… Page 1 of 5. Page 1 of 5. Page 2 of 5. Page 2 of 5. Page 3 of 5. Page 3 of 5. Main menu. Displaying Minimum wages Act 1948 MCQ with Answers.pdf.

Social Interactions and Location Decisions: Evidence ...
Apr 13, 2017 - Social networks, consisting primarily of family, friends, and church members, ... restrict the sample to birth towns with at least ten migrants and, ...

Employment Effects of Minimum Wages in Inflexible ...
Jul 13, 2009 - ‡I am grateful for the valuable feedback provided by John Kennan, James ... John Gordanier, Insan Tunali, Seokjin Woo, Sudip Gupta, Jeremy ...

Revision of minimum rates of wages (1).PDF
Page 2 of 12. 1.) Using. named “N. Your file w. The line w. set to nich. “03,03,03. 2) Change. Save the f. 3) Back to. NCSexpert, re. NETTODAT.PR. will look like t.

negative employment effects of minimum wages in ...
Oct 11, 2006 - 3 Respectfully referring to Freeman and Eccles's 1982 paper. 3 .... productivity−w (slope of the line CEG) which is higher than the minimum.

Social Interactions and Location Decisions: Evidence ...
Dec 12, 2016 - Social networks, consisting primarily of family, friends, and church members, ... birth towns with at least ten migrants and group together all ...

Wages
for his master. All the slave's labour appears as unpaid labour. [8] In wage labour, on the contrary, even surplus-labour, or unpaid labour, appears as paid.

Minimum wages strike back: the effects on capital and labor demands ...
Sep 7, 2012 - Keywords: Minimum wage; Employment; Capital; Search; Large firm; Hold ... “large-firm” framework in which labor markets are characterized by ...

minimum
May 30, 1997 - Webster's II NeW College Dictionary, Houghton Mif?in,. 1995, p. .... U.S. Patent. Oct. 28,2003. Sheet 10 0f 25. US RE38,292 E. Fl 6. I4. 200. 220.