Matching and Price Competition: Comment By FUHITO KOJIMA* The theory of two-sided matching markets has interested researchers for its theoretical appeal and relevance to real-life applications. The matching of medical residents and hospitals in the United States has been studied extensively by Alvin E. Roth (1984) and others. The National Resident Matching Program (NRMP), the matching authority in the US hospital-resident matching market, runs a centralized matching mechanism that is a variant of the deferred acceptance algorithm of David Gale and Lloyd S. Shapley (1962), redesigned by Roth and Elliott Peranson (1999). A recent antitrust case against the NRMP charged that the centralized matching mechanism suppressed wages of residents. Although the lawsuit itself was dismissed, it sparked discussion about the effect of centralized matching on wages and efficiency.1 Jeremy Bulow and Jonathan Levin (2006, BL henceforth) investigate a matching market with price competition where each firm can hire only one worker and show that (a) the average wage is lower, (b) profit of each firm is higher, (c) wages are more compressed, and (d) the resulting matching is slightly less efficient in the presence of the matching mechanism than in any competitive equilibrium.2 Although BL declare “we have chosen our assumptions for analytical simplicity and transparency, not as the most realistic possible model of the residency match” (654), these results were often interpreted as an argu-

ment against the NRMP and led to discussion about potential changes of the matching mechanism. Vincent P. Crawford (forthcoming), for instance, proposes the “Flexible-Salary Match,” in which hospitals are allowed to indicate several levels of possible wages, and medical students are allowed to express preferences over pairs of hospitals and wages.3 We show that conclusions (a) and (b) above do not necessarily hold when firms may hire more than one worker and the number of workers in different firms are different.4 More specifically, we present an example with multiple positions in which the average worker wage is higher in the equilibrium with the matching mechanism than in a competitive equilibrium; and profit of each firm is lower in the equilibrium with the matching mechanism than in a competitive equilibrium. Our findings may explain why some of the results of BL disagree with empirical findings of Muriel Niederle and Roth (2003, 2004), who find little or no effect of the centralized matching on wages in some medical matching markets in the United States. Note that different firms hire different numbers of workers in many labor markets like the NRMP.5 There are other reasons why the conclusions and policy implications of BL may not be applicable to markets like the NRMP. For example, a competitive equilibrium may not be a 3 Georgy Artemov (forthcoming) discusses implications of introducing such a mechanism with flexible wages for wage volatility. 4 Our example does not imply that other conclusions of BL do not generalize. See discussion presented later. 5 Program descriptions are posted in the Fellowship and Residency Electronic Interactive Database (FREIDA), http://www.ama-assn.org/ama/pub/category/2007.html. For example, among the total of 13 residency programs in internal medicine in Massachusetts that posted program sizes on that Web site (the data were collected on October 17, 2006), program sizes (sum of the numbers of first-, second-, and third-year resident positions) ranged between 20 and 164. Median was 43, mean was 62.8, and the standard deviation was 47.6. Variation in program sizes is observed in other specialties and regions as well.

* Department of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138 (e-mail: [email protected]). I am grateful to anonymous referees, Georgy Artemov, Eric Budish, Aytek Erdil, Hideo Konishi, Jonathan Levin, Gregor Matvos, Muriel Niederle, Parag Pathak, Alvin Roth, Yuki ¨ nver, and Yosuke Yasuda for comments and Takagi, Utku U discussion. 1 As footnote 2 of BL notes, the antitrust case was dismissed in 2004 after Congress intervened on the side of the defendants. The appellate court upheld the dismissal in June 2006. A brief account of the antitrust case is found at http://kuznets.fas.harvard.edu/⬃aroth/alroth.html#Antitrust. 2 Regarding point (d), more precisely Proposition 5 of BL shows that inefficiency per firm is of the order of the reciprocal of the number of firms in their model. 1027

1028

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

good model of the decentralized market without the matching mechanism, for such reasons as unraveling and congestion (Roth 1984; Roth and Xiaolin Xing 1994). Motivated by this idea, Hideo Konishi and Margarita Sapozhnikov (2006) and Siva Anantham and Jennifer Stack (2006) show that worker wages may be lower than those in a competitive equilibrium in their models of decentralized markets without the matching mechanism. Niederle (forthcoming) notes that the NRMP has a feature she calls ordered contracts: hospital programs can offer more than one term of contract. She finds that there is an equilibrium with the matching mechanism that coincides with the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium when hospitals can offer ordered contracts. I. An Example with Multiple Positions

Consider the following market. There are two firms, 1 and 2. Firms hire different numbers of workers: firm 1 has one position to fill with a worker, whereas firm 2 has two positions. There are three workers 1, 2, and 3. Let ⌬m be worker m’s parameter of quality. Surplus of firm 1 from hiring worker m is v(1; m) ⫽ ⌬m. Firm 2’s surplus from hiring workers m and m⬘ is v(2; m, m⬘) ⫽ 2(⌬m ⫹ ⌬m⬘). A vacant position is identified as a worker of quality zero hired at wage zero. Let ⌬1 ⫽ 1, ⌬3 ⫽ 3, and ⌬2 僆 (1, 3).6 The payoff to a firm is the surplus minus the wages it pays to the worker(s) it hires, and the payoff of a worker is the wage she obtains. A competitive equilibrium is a wage for each worker and an allocation of workers to firms such that (a) wages are individually rational, that is, each firm and each worker gets a nonnegative payoff; and (b) at the going worker wages, no firm has a strict incentive to change the set of workers it hires. There are a range of competitive equilibria with the same matching of workers and firms at different wages. There exists a competitive equilibrium, called the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium, which is preferred to any 6 Note that we consider a case where surplus functions are multiplicative and firm 2’s surplus is additive in worker quality in order to be as close to BL as possible. In particular, these surplus functions are increasing in worker quality and have increasing differences in firm quality and worker quality, which are crucial for BL’s result, Proposition 4.

JUNE 2007

competitive equilibrium by every firm. Following BL, we focus on the firm-preferred competitive equilibrium. In the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium, firm 1 hires worker 1 at the lowest individually rational wage pF1 ⫽ 0. Given that, firm 2 hires workers 2 and 3 at wages pF2 ⫽ ⌬2 ⫺ 1 and pF3 ⫽ 2. Next we consider a simple game of matching with impersonal wages. Each firm simultaneously makes a nonnegative wage offer which applies to any worker(s) it hires. The offers are observed by the workers. Then matching follows. Firms rank workers from the highest-quality worker to the lowest-quality worker: 3, 2, and 1 in this order. Workers rank firms from the one with the higher wage. So assortative matching occurs and wages are paid as announced: worker 3 is matched to the firm with the highest wage offer, worker 2 is always matched to firm 2, and worker 1 is matched to the firm with the lowest wage. Now we compute the Nash equilibrium, called the pricing equilibrium, of the matching game. By a logic analogous to cases with one position per firm in BL, two firms take mixed strategies over some common interval [0, p៮ ] with p៮ ⱖ 0. Moreover, there is no atom in the distributions of wage offers except possibly for one firm at p ⫽ 0.7 Let gn(p) be the probability density that firm n makes an offer of wage p. In order for firm 1 to randomize over the support [0, p៮ ] of the mixed strategy, the following should hold at p 僆 [0, p៮ ]: g 2 共p兲 ⫻ 共3 ⫺ 1兲 ⫽ 1. The left-hand side is the expected benefit of raising the wage offer by a unit amount, thus hiring worker 3 instead of 1. The equation requires that this benefit be equal to the cost (the additional wage it pays to a worker) that appears on the right-hand side. Similarly, firm 2’s incentive condition requires g 1 共p兲 ⫻ 2 ⫻ 共3 ⫺ 1兲 ⫽ 2. The benefit of raising the wage offer by a unit amount is twice the expected improvement of the worker quality, since firm 2 is of higher

7 It turns out that neither firm has an atom in this particular example.

VOL. 97 NO. 3

KOJIMA: MATCHING AND PRICE COMPETITION: COMMENT

quality, 2. On the other hand, the cost appearing on the right-hand side is 2 instead of 1, since firm 2 must pay the same wages to each of the two workers it hires. The equations above imply g1(p) ⫽ g2(p) ⫽ 1⁄2 for every p 僆 [0, p ៮ ]. Therefore, p៮ ⫽ 2, and both firms randomize uniformly between 0 and 2. Now we compare average wages in the firmoptimal competitive equilibrium and the pricing equilibrium. The average wage in the firmoptimal competitive equilibrium is [0 ⫹ (⌬2 ⫺ 1) ⫹ 2]/3 ⫽ (⌬2 ⫹ 1)/3. The average wage in the pricing equilibrium is 1, since both firms uniformly randomize between 0 and 2 and these firms hire the entire set of workers. Therefore, if ⌬2 ⬍ 2, the average wage in the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium is lower than in the pricing equilibrium. Next we consider firm profits. The payoff of firm 1 is 1 in the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium, as it hires worker 1 at wage zero. Firm 1’s profit is 1 in the pricing equilibrium as well, since paying zero is one of firm 1’s best responses in the pricing equilibrium, and it results in hiring worker 1 with certainty. Firm 2’s profit in the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium is 2 ⫻ 共⌬ 2 ⫹ 3兲 ⫺ 关共⌬ 2 ⫺ 1兲 ⫹ 2兴 ⫽ ⌬ 2 ⫹ 5. In the pricing equilibrium, paying zero is one of firm 2’s best responses. Hence, profit of firm 2 in the pricing equilibrium is 2 ⫻ 共1 ⫹ ⌬ 2 兲 ⫽ 2⌬ 2 ⫹ 2. Therefore, firm 2’s profit is lower in the pricing equilibrium than in the competitive equilibrium for every ⌬2 ⬍ 3. The intuition for the example above is as follows. In the pricing equilibrium, worker 2 is hired by firm 2 whether firm 2 offers a higher wage than firm 1 or not. On the other hand, firm 2 has to offer the same wages to both workers it hires. The expected wage for worker 2 is thus made higher because of the competition for worker 3. This positive effect on worker 2 is so large that the average worker wage is higher in the pricing equilibrium than in the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium. On the other hand, firm 2 is made worse off in the pricing equilib-

1029

rium than in the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium since it should pay high wages not only to worker 3 but also to worker 2 in order to compete for worker 3, even though firm 2 ends up hiring worker 2 irrespective of the wage it offers. We summarize our finding as follows. The “nondiscrimination” feature of wage offers plays an important role for wage suppression and increase in firm profits when one firm hires one worker. The same feature, however, may raise worker wages and reduce firm profits through a different channel when a firm may hire more than one worker. II. Discussion and Conclusion

Our analysis relied crucially on the assumption that a firm offers the same wage to all workers it hires. While in principle wages can be different across workers within a firm, this assumption seems to be satisfied in many labor markets, such as the NRMP. In the NRMP, most hospitals indicate one term of contract such as wage level for all the potential workers prior to the execution of matching.8 The survey study by Niederle, Deborah D. Proctor, and Roth (2006) also suggests that each hospital program often offers the same wages and terms of contracts to all its workers. More specifically, in the market of gastroenterology fellows, all but 4 out of 63 programs offered the same wage to all their fellows; all but 4 offered the same hours on call; all but 18 offered the same amount of time for research. These pieces of evidence suggest that, as BL eloquently put it, “[a hospital] cannot offer 5x for the obstetrical Barry Bonds, but only x for the obstetrical Mario Mendoza” (653). Another notable feature of our example is that different firms hire different numbers of workers. In that example, the less efficient firm 1 makes an aggressive offer because it is also small, which makes the cost of a high wage offer relatively small in comparison to the larger firm 2. To see this point clearly, consider the market in which all N firms have identical k ⱖ 2 positions and there are kN workers. Then a 8 Hospitals in the NRMP can in principle offer more than one wage level by using ordered contracts (Niederle 2006). However, only about 7 percent of hospitals use ordered contracts.

1030

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

firm with the highest wage offers is matched to the k best workers, the firm with the second highest wage offer to the (k ⫹ 1)st, ... , (2k)th best workers, and so forth. Therefore the problem is equivalent to the one in which each firm hires only one worker and there are N workers, where the quality of the mth most efficient worker is the average of those of the [k(m ⫺ 1) ⫹ 1]st, ... , (km)th most efficient workers in the original problem. Hence, the analysis of pricing equilibria of BL can be applied without modification if all the firms hire multiple but equal numbers of workers. Before finishing the paper, we discuss possible directions of future research. In addition to wage depression and rise in firm profits, BL discover wage compression and slight inefficiency of a centralized matching (conclusions (c) and (d) mentioned above). Whether these results hold with multiple positions is an open question, as our example does not contradict them.9 Analyzing these issues would be interesting, since some reform proposals of the NRMP mechanism such as the Flexible-Salary Match (Crawford forthcoming) may not only raise the average wage, but also alleviate wage compression and especially improve efficiency of the matching. Another issue of interest is whether the firmoptimal competitive equilibrium is a natural model of a decentralized market. While the question is raised by several authors (cited in an introductory paragraph), BL give some justification in their original environment. More specifically, they observe that, when each firm hires one worker, the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium results in the same allocation as in a form of Vickrey auction, which may be another natural benchmark. This equivalence does not hold, however, when firms are allowed to hire more than one worker, and the Vickrey outcome may be preferred by firms to the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium. It would be interesting to investigate relationships among competitive

9

In our example workers 1 and 2 are made better off and worker 3 worse off in the pricing equilibrium than in the firm-optimal competitive equilibrium. In particular, wage compression occurs in this market. The issue of efficiency in large markets as formulated by BL is beyond the scope of our analysis, as we focus on a simple example of a small market.

JUNE 2007

equilibria, pricing equilibria, and other models such as Vickrey auctions when firms hire multiple workers. Our findings also await empirical study. While the effect identified in this paper may partially explain why wages do not appear to depend much on whether centralized matching is present (Niederle and Roth 2003, 2004), other explanations are proposed in the literature.10 Finally, multiple positions may have other important consequences in the labor market. For example, if a firm raises wages of its new workers, there may be pressure to raise wages of existing workers. Given such pressure, a firm may want to keep wage offers to its new workers low.11 Analyzing a richer model of this kind would be an interesting research topic. REFERENCES Anantham, Siva, and Jennifer Stack. 2006.

“Wage Formation under Early Contracting.” Unpublished. Artemov, Georgy. Forthcoming. “Matching and Price Competition: Would Personalized Prices Help?” International Journal of Game Theory. Bulow, Jeremy, and Jonathan Levin. 2006. “Matching and Price Competition.” American Economic Review, 96(3): 652– 68. Crawford, Vincent P. Forthcoming. “The Flexible-Salary Match: A Proposal to Increase the Salary Flexibility of the National Resident Matching Program,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. Gale, David, and Lloyd S. Shapley. 1962. “College Admissions and the Stability of Marriage.” American Mathematical Monthly, 69(1): 9 –15. Konishi, Hideo, and Margarita Sapozhnikov.

2006. “Decentralized Matching Markets with Endogeneous Salaries.” http://www2.bc.edu/ konishih/dcmatch4.pdf. Niederle, Muriel. Forthcoming. “Competitive Wages in a Match with Ordered Contracts.” American Economic Review. Niederle, Muriel, and Alvin E. Roth. 2003. “Relationship between Wages and Presence 10 See papers cited in the introductory paragraphs, for example. 11 We are grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting this possibility.

VOL. 97 NO. 3

KOJIMA: MATCHING AND PRICE COMPETITION: COMMENT

of a Match in Medical Fellowships.” Journal of the American Medical Association, 290(9): 1153–54. Niederle, Muriel, and Alvin E. Roth. 2004. “The Gastroenterology Fellowship Match: How It Failed and Why It Could Succeed Once Again.” Gastroenterology, 127(2): 658 – 66. Niederle, Muriel, Deborah D. Proctor, and Alvin E. Roth. 2006. “What Will Be Needed for the

New Gastroenterology Fellowship Match to Succeed?” Gastroenterology, 130(1): 218 – 24.

1031

Roth, Alvin E. 1984. “The Evolution of the Labor

Market for Medical Interns and Residents: A Case Study in Game Theory.” Journal of Political Economy, 92(6): 991–1016. Roth, Alvin E., and Elliott Peranson. 1999. “The Redesign of the Matching Market for American Physicians: Some Engineering Aspects of Economic Design.” American Economic Review, 89(4): 748 – 80. Roth, Alvin E., and Xiaolin Xing. 1994. “Jumping the Gun: Imperfections and Institutions Related to the Timing of Market Transactions.” American Economic Review, 84(4): 992–1044.

Matching and Price Competition: Comment

where each firm can hire only one worker and ... sizes on that Web site (the data were collected on October .... Our analysis relied crucially on the assumption.

57KB Sizes 6 Downloads 369 Views

Recommend Documents

Matching and Price Competition with an Outside Market
May 15, 2014 - Bulow and Levin (2006) develop a model of matching with salaries in which equilibrium salaries, relative to their competitive levels, are compressed and, on average, lower. This paper expands their model by allowing for a competitive o

Matching with Contracts: Comment
Jun 2, 2008 - preference profile of other hospitals with single job openings and doctors such that there exists no stable allocation. We show that this last claim ...

Matching with Contracts: Comment
with contracts, which includes the two-sided matching and package auction models as well as a .... The following condition plays a major role in our analysis.

Consumer Search and Price Competition
Nov 6, 2016 - Keywords : Consumer search; price advertisements; online shopping; Bertrand competition; product differentiation. 1 Introduction. We consider ...

Consumer Search and Price Competition
37Integrate equation (2) by parts and differentiate with respect to w, then h(w) = ∫. ¯v w−z∗ g(w − vi)dF(vi)+. (1 − G(z∗))f(w − z∗). The second term vanishes as z∗ → ¯z. 38If ¯z = ∞, then ∫. ¯v+z∗ w f(w − z∗)dH(w)nâ

Competition in Matching Technologies
Keywords: employment agencies, matching technologies, market differentiation. ∗I am grateful ... (Source: ComScore) The Internet has also changed the job search and recruiting strategies of ..... A couple of things are worth noticing here. First ..

Tax incidence under imperfect competition: Comment
Delipalla and O'Donnell (2001) contains a formula for the incidence of specific and ad valorem taxes in a con- jectural variation oligopoly model with potentially asymmetric firms. The formula is incorrect. We derive the correct formula and provide a

Relaxing Price Competition Through Product ...
have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a .... income ti, is indifferent between good fc at price pk and good Ic —- I at price p, ... being a measure of the relative qualities of goods 1 and 2, and the residual good

India's Caste System Vocabulary Matching Competition (1).pdf ...
Page 1 of 1. Name: India's Caste System Vocabulary Matching. Competition. Write the letter of the correct match next to each word. 1. Caste System a. lacking ...

Price Discrimination in Many-to-Many Matching Markets
Sep 26, 2011 - This paper studies second-degree price discrimination in markets where the ... followed by online employment agencies and business directories. ...... 2009, When Is Price Discrimination Profitable?, Management Science,.

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
Jul 21, 2017 - Email: [email protected]. ... since, in our model, consumers purchase in volume and they may choose to purchase more than ... 1The approaches proposed in the marketing literature (e.g. Dikson and .... between product varieties is hi

Does Competition Reduce Price Dispersion? New ...
including advance-purchase requirements, nonrefundable tickets, and. Saturday night .... Section III includes our own fixed-effects panel analysis. Section IV .... The data also show a large amount of variation in competition over time within the ...

Price Competition with Decreasing Returns#to#Scale ...
Dec 10, 2014 - Key words: Price competition, Demand rationing, Convex costs, .... Let si (pi) denote the quantity that solves this optimization problem.9 The ...

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
(2017) who consider a competitive facility location problem on a network in which consumers located on vertices wish to connect to the nearest facility and each competitor locates a facility on a vertex trying to maximize her market share. This liter

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
Email: [email protected]. ... At the same time, the marketing ... 1The approaches proposed in the marketing literature (e.g. Dikson and ...... This is exactly the result for the benchmark monopolistic competition model without network (see.

Simultaneous vs. sequential price competition with ...
Aug 22, 2011 - assume that firm 2 wins the competition if there is a tie.7 The equilibrium behavior of firm 2 in the sequential game is easy to establish. Given b1, firm 2 has to match that bid to win. It will want to do so whenever b1 ≥ c2, and wi

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
Mar 19, 2018 - settings, where prices are typically strategic complements (Vives, 1999). Furthermore, we ... we provide examples obtained via simulations. 4 ...

draft for comment and review -
establish easier access to scientific research data on the Internet, .... in producing the data, or the ..... A person involved in analyzing data or the results of an.

Experimental Design: Review and Comment
Technometrics is the design of response surface experi- ments. Response surface ... neering, in particular how to improve the performance of systems by ..... We call these designs .... the center of the design region when compared with.

Experimental Design: Review and Comment
In practice, this optimization problem may be difficult or impossible to solve ana- ...... existence of good software for experimental design would be a great step ...

Pairwise kidney exchange: Comment
and others. The key requirement is that the choice mechanism be consistent, i.e., if an allocation is chosen from some set of feasible allocations, it is also chosen ...

Comment on “The market price of fiscal uncertainty” by ...
The decision maker is averse to model ambiguity and forms worst-case .... first-best and will play an important role at the second-best problem, i.e. in an ...

pdf comment and markup toolbar
pdf comment and markup toolbar. pdf comment and markup toolbar. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying pdf comment and markup toolbar.

Observation Checklist and Comment Form.pdf
Page 1 of 1. Observation Checklist and Comment Form. DoDEA Grant Peer Observations, 2012-13. Teacher Date Class School. What did you observe? Rate 1-5 (1 is low,. 5 is high). 1. Students asking questions. 2. Students making predictions and/or testing