Online Appendix "Why did the US unemployment rate used to be so low?" Regis Barnichon and Andrew Figura Not for Publication

1

Data

1.1

Correction for the 1994 CPS redesign

As found by Abraham and Shimer (2002), the 1994 redesign of the CPS (see e.g., Polivka and Miller, 1998) caused a discontinuity in some the transition probabilities in the …rst month of 1994. To adjust the series for the redesign, we proceed as follows. We start from the monthly transition probabilities obtained from matched data for each demographic group. We remove the 94m1 value for each transition probability (since its value corresponds to the redesigned survey, not the pre-94 survey), and instead estimate a value consistent with the pre-94 survey. To do so, we use the transition probability average value over 1993m6-1993m12 (the monthly probabilities can be very noisy so we average them over 6 months to smooth them out) that we multiply by the average growth rate of the transition probability over 1994m1-2010m12. That way, we capture the long-run trend in the transition probability. Over 1994m2-2010m12, we simply adjust the transition probability by the di¤erence between the average of the original values over 94m1-94m6 (to control for the in‡uence of noise or seasonality) and the inferred 94m1 value. By eliminating the jumps in the transition probabilities in 1994m1, we are assuming that these discontinuities were solely caused by the CPS redesign. Thus, the validity of our approach rests on the fact that 1994m1 was not a month with large "true" movements in transition probabilities. We think that this is unlikely because there is no such large movements in the aggregate job …nding rate and aggregate job separation rate obtained from duration data (Shimer, 2012 and Elsby, Michaels and Solon, 2009) that do not su¤er from these discontinuities. Indeed, these authors treat the 1994 discontinuity by using data from the …rst and …fth rotation group, for which the unemployment duration measure (and thus their transition probability measures) was una¤ected by the redesign. Moreover, Abraham and Shimer (2002) used independent data from the Census Employment Survey to evaluate the e¤ect of the CPS redesign on the average transition probabilities from matched data. They found that only 1

UI

and

IU

were signi…cantly a¤ected, and that, after correction of these discontinuities (using

the CES employment-population ratio), none of the transition probabilities displayed large movements in 1994. Finally, we checked ex-post that our procedure had little e¤ect on the stocks, i.e. on the measure of the aggregate unemployment rate and on the unemployment rate of each demographic group, consistent with Polivka and Miller’s conclusion (1998) that the redesign did not a¤ect the measure of unemployment.

2

Approximations

2.1

Approximation 1:

Approximation 1 states that movements in workers’ layo¤ and quit rate to unemployment, EU l t

and

EU q , t

are proportional to the layo¤ rate lt and quit rate qt . The two concepts are

related through

with

EU l jl t

EU q jq t quit.1

and

a layo¤ or a

(

EU l t EU q t

EU l jl t EU q jq qt t

= lt =

the (conditional) hazard rates of ‡owing into unemployment following

Approximation 1 states that

EU l jl t

and

EU q jq t

are approximately constant. To verify that

claim, we use data from the JOLTS. The JOLTS allows us to measure the aggregate layo¤ rate and quit rate over 2000-2010 while matched micro data on workers transitions from the CPS allow us to measure

EU l t

and

EU q . t

Formally, we regress

ln lt = ln

EU l t

+ al + "lt

ln qt = ln

EU q t

+ aq + "qt

over 2000-2010. Figures 1 and 2 plot the predicted values ^lt and q^t along with the actual values. Over the 10-year overlap between the CPS and the JOLTS, the layo¤ and quit rate to unemployment do a very good job capturing movements in the layo¤ and quit rate. In other words, the (conditional) hazard rates of ‡owing into unemployment following a layo¤ or a quit are roughly constant over time, as con…rmed by Figure 3. Thus, in our approximate decomposition, we interpret movements in the layo¤ rate and quit rate to unemployment as capturing movements in the layo¤ rate and quit rate. 1 With a slight abuse of language given that we are talking in terms of hazard rates, rather than probabilities. Probabilities and hazard rates can be used interchangeably, because of the small values of the transition l q rates/probabilities EU and EU .

2

Note also that, as Figure 3 shows, almost all layo¤s end up in the unemployment pool, i.e., EU l jl

' 1. A corollary is thus that all EI transitions originate in quits, and can therefore be

interpreted as a decision of the worker. We can then interpret movements in individuals’decisions to leave the labor

2.2

EI

as capturing

force.2

Approximation 2

In this subsection, we provide support for Approximation 2 from two angles. First, we show empirically that the approximation is reasonable. Second, we prove that Approximation 2 holds (Proposition 1 below) under empirically veri…ed assumptions. First, Figure 4 plots the

IEjILF i;t

series and the approximated values implied by Approxi-

mation 2 for the 8 demographic groups: younger than 25, above 55, male 25-35, male 35-45, male 45-55, female 25-35, female 35-45, female 45-55. We can see that the approximation does a good job at capturing movements in

IEjILF : i;t

Second, we prove the proposition supporting Approximation 2. We …rst state 3 assumptions: Assumption A1: The average UE rate and average UI rate of each demographic group i depends (i) on the unemployment duration distribution, (ii) on the reasons for unemployment (labor force entrant, job loser, job leaver), and (iii) in the case of labor force entrants, on their status during inactivity (whether marginally-attached or not). Assumption A2: Duration dependence in the UE and UI transition rates are of the form ( with

UE t (d)

and

duration d and, 1,8d > 0;

0 (d) E

UI t (d) E (d)

< 0,

UE t (d) = UI t (d) =

UE t (0) E (d) UI t (0) I (d)

(1)

the UE and UI transition rates of an individual with unemployment

and 0 (d) I

I (d)

functions (independent of time) satisfying

< 0 and

E (d)

and

I (d)

E (0)

= 1,

I (0)

=

not necessarily continuous at d = 0:

Assumption A3: The duration distribution of the unemployed is close to its steady-state distribution. Note that Assumptions A1-A2 are well supported by the data: Barnichon and Figura (2011) show that an aggregate matching function and the characteristics listed in A1 do a very good job at explaining ‡uctuations in job …nding rates. In the next section, we show that duration dependence relations of the form (1) are well supported by the data. Regarding Assumption A3, in an extended proof available upon request, we prove a more general proposition which 2

There are also theoretical reasons to think EI transitions do not generally originate in layo¤s. Employed workers subject to a layo¤ are eligible for unemployment bene…ts (unlike workers who quit) and have therefore a strong interest in staying in the labor force (as unemployed) to collect the bene…t.

3

does not rely on assuming a steady-state distribution assumption (Assumption A3). We show that, without the steady-state assumption, movements in h U lf E t

values of the hazard rates (in addition to

tion that movements in

IEjI LF t

and

E (d)it are also a function of past U lf I ). Supporting our initial assumpt

are well approximated using the steady-state distribution of

unemployment spells, we …nd that lagged values of the hazard rates explain little additional variance (i.e., in addition to

U lf E t

and

U lf I ) t

IEjI LF . t

of

Proposition 1: Under Assumptions A1–A3, for each demographic group i, there exist E UI I constants aU i ; ai ; and ai such that

d ln

with

U Ii;t Ii;t

IEjI LF i;t

'

E aU i d ln

U lf E it

+

I aU i d ln

U lf I i;t

+

U Ii;t I ai d ln Ii;t

the fraction of marginally attached in the inactivity pool and

U lf E it

(2)

and

U lf I it

the UE

and UI transition rates of labor force entrants. We now describe the proof of Proposition 1. Proof: Our proof goes in 3 steps. Step 1: We …rst show the simpler Proposition 1b where Assumption A1 is replaced by the stronger assumption A1b: Assumption A1b: The average UE rate and average UI rate of each demographic group i depends (i) on the unemployment duration distribution, and (ii) on the reasons for unemployment (labor force entrant, job loser, job leaver). Proposition 1b: Under Assumptions A1b, A2-A3, for each demographic group i, there exist constants aU i

lf E

and aU i

lf I

d ln with

U lf E it

and

U lf I it

such that IEjI LF it

' aiU

lf E

d ln

U lf E it

+ aU i

lf I

d ln

U lf I it

(3)

the UE and UI transition rates of labor force entrants.

Proof: For clarity of exposition, we omit the subscript i. The starting point of the proof is to realize that

IEjI LF

, the job …nding rate of an individual who just started searching, is the

job …nding rate of labor force entrant immediately upon entering unemployment, i.e., the job …nding rate of a labor force entrant with zero unemployment duration. Denoting

4

U lf E (d) t

the

time t unemployment exit rate of a labor force entrant conditional on having been unemployed for a duration d, we then have U lf E (0) t

=

IEjI LF t

or U lf E (d) t

IEjI LF t

=

E (d):

(4) lf

By de…nition, the average job …nding rate of labor force entrants at time t, tU E , satis…es E D U lf E U lf E (d) , with hXit the cross-sectional mean of X across unemployment duration = t t

at instant t, so that

t

U lf E t

=

IEjI LF t

h

E (d)it :

(5)

The cross-sectional mean depends on the distribution of unemployed workers by unemployment duration. Using Assumption A3, the cross-sectional means h well approximated by h

ss E (d)it

and h

ss I (d)it ,

E (d)it

and h

I (d)it

are

the cross-sectional means calculated with the

duration distribution in steady-state, i.e., with the duration distribution characterized by the cdf Ft (d) Ft (d) = 1

e

= 1

e

U lf E (d) t IEjI t

LF

U lf I (d) t E (d)

UI t (0)

I (d)

:

We can then write that U lf I t

' '

U lf I (0) h I (d)iss t t Z1

U lf I (0) t

I (d)dFt (d)

0

'

U lf I (0) t

Z1

I (d)

IEjI LF t

0 E (d)

+

U lf I (0) 0I (d) t

e

IEjI t

LF

E (d)

U lf I (0) t

I (d)

d(d)

0

which after log-linearizing implies there exist constants a and b such that d ln

U lf I t

' a d ln

IEjI LF t

or that (provided a 6= 0) there exist constants d ln

U lf I (0) t

' d ln

+ b d ln

and IEjI LF t

5

U lf I (0) t

(6)

such that + d ln

U lf I . t

(7)

Proceeding similarly with h

ss E (d)it ,

IEjI LF t

d ln

we have that there exist constants U lf I (0) t

' d ln

+ d ln

which combined with (7) gives that there exist constants aU d ln

IEjI LF t

' aU

lf E

d ln

U lf E t

+ aU

lf E

lf I

and

such that

U lf E t

and aU

d ln

(8) lf I

such that

U lf I t

(9)

which completes the proof of Proposition 1b. Step 2: We now relax Assumption A1b and, as in Assumption A1, allow inactive individuals to di¤er according to their marginal attachment status. Denote ItU the number of inactive individuals who are marginally attached to the labor force at time t, and ItI the number of non-marginallyattached individuals with ItU + ItI = It : Marginally attached individuals have conditional job …nding rate I I EjI I LF : t

I U EjI U LF t

and non-marginally attached have conditional job …nding rate

Using Proposition 1b for the marginally and non-marginally attached, we get that for each E , aU I , aU E , aU I such that demographic group i, there exist constants aU IU IU II II

( where and

I U EjI U LF i;t U lf I the UE i;t

d ln d ln

I U EjI U LF E d ln U lf E + aU I d ln U lf I ' aU t t i;t IU IU I I EjI I LF U lf E U lf I U E U I ' aI I d ln t + aI I d ln t i;t

(10)

is the conditional job …nding rate of a marginally-attached inactive,

U lf E i;t

and UI transition rate of a labor force entrant who, when inactive, was

marginally attached. Similar notations apply to non-marginally attached. Step 3: The …nal step is to note that the average conditional job …nding probability of an inactive over dt is a weighted average of the probabilities of the marginal-attached and the non-marginally-attached so that IEjI LF dt it

U Ii;t = Ii;t

I U EjI U LF dt it

+

1

U Ii;t Ii;t

With the existence of a matching function, we have d ln and similarly for

U lf I , it

U lf E it

and

U lf I , it

!

I I EjI I LF dt: i;t

U lf E it

' d ln

U lf E it

(11)

to a …rst-order,

so that combining with (10), we get that there exist

6

E UI I constants aU i ; ai ; and ai such that IEjI LF i;t

d ln

U lf E it

E ' aU i d ln

U lf I i;t

I + aU i d ln

+ aIi d ln

U Ii;t Ii;t

(12)

which completes the proof.

3

Modeling duration dependence

As stated in Assumption A2, we assume that duration dependence is of the form ( with

U lf E (d) t

and

U lf I (d) t

U lf E (d) = t U lf I (d) = t

U lf E (0) E (d) t U lf I (0) I (d) t

the UE and UI transition rates of a labor force entrant with

unemployment duration d and

E (d)

and

I (d)

To estimate these relations, we posit that i.e.,

with

8 < E

,

I

,

E;0

and

I;0

(13)

functions (independent of time): E (d)

and

E (d)

=

E;0 e

e

I (d)

=

I;0 e

e

:

I (d)

are bi-exponential functions,

Ed

(14)

Id

some constants.

Table A1 reports the estimated coe¢ cients, and Figures (5) and (6) plot the estimated duration dependence relation for

U lf E (d) t

U lf I (d). t

and

In the cross-section, the bi-exponential

does a very good job at capturing the e¤ect of duration on the exit probability. To verify that the assumed relation (13) also does a good job at capturing variations in the lf E lf E \ time-series dimension as well, Figure 7 plots aggregate U along U , the value implied t t \ IEjILF IEjILF U lf E by (13) and given by t = t h E (d)it , –the cross-sectional mean of t E (d) at instant t–, and Figure 8 plots a similar picture for job at capturing the movements in

4

U lf E ; t

UI t :

We can see that (13) does a very good

and that a similar conclusion holds for

U lf I . t

Unemployment decomposition

Our unemployment decomposition begins with dut =

N X i=1

i

d

it

+

N X i=1

7

l i dlit

+

N X i=1

! i duit :

(15)

We then decompose the unemployment rate and labor force participation rate of each demographic group using the steady-state expressions sit sit + fit sit + fit sit + fit + oit

uit = lit = with

8 > > < fit = sit = > > : oit =

UE it EU it 1

+ +

I LF it

(16) (17)

U I IEjI LF it it IEjI LF EI ) it (1 it EU U I U E EI it it + it it

: +

EU it ;

We take a Taylor expansion of (16) around the mean of I LF . it

(18)

U I EI it it UE it ;

EI it ,

UI it ,

IEjI LF it

and

While all our quantitative results are obtained using a second-order Taylor expansion,

for clarity of exposition, we only report the …rst-order coe¢ cients and we present the mechanics behind our decomposition using only the …rst-order coe¢ cients.3 The mechanics of the secondorder approximation is identical to what we present here, except that we split the cross-order terms equally between components. The …rst-order coe¢ cients for u are UE

EU

EI

UI

IEjI LF I LF

with

IU jI LF

El

=

(

El

Eq

+

UE

+

Eq

+

(

El

Eq

+

UE

+

+

UI

+

IU jI LF

UI

IU jI LF

+

IEjI LF

= =

(

EI

El

+

Eq

+

IU jI LF

(

El

Eq

+

+

UI

=

(

EI

El

+

+

(

Eq

El

(

(

UE

+

UE

EI IEjI LF

IU jI LF

UE

=

+

+

+

+

IU jI LF

+

IU jI LF

+

UI

+

El

Eq

EI

(

UE

+

)+

+

UI

)

UI

EI IU jI LF 2 )

EI IEjI LF

IU jI LF

+

EI IEjI LF 2 )

IU jI LF

)

EI IEjI LF 2 ) UE

+

UI

UI

))

EI IU jI LF 2 )

= 0 =1

IEjI LF

, so that duit =

X

AB AB i d it

+

u it

A6=B

with AB 2 fU E; EU; U I; EI; IEjI 3

+

UE

Eq

+

UI

) EI IEjI LF 2 )

LF g for each group i:

All coe¢ cients are available upon requests.

8

(19)

EU it ;

Similarly, taking a Taylor expansion of (17) around the mean of IEjI LF it

I LF it

and

AB

gives us the …rst–order terms

have

X

dlit =

AB AB i d it

UE it ;

EI it ,

UI it ,

(available upon request), so that we l it

+

(20)

A6=B

for each group i: Using (19) and (20) in (15), we get the unemployment decomposition dut = d

t

+

N XX x

with x 2 fU E; EU; EI; U I; I

LF; IEjI

x x i d it

+

(21)

t

i=1

x i

LF g ; and

= !i

x i

+

l x i i

.

The …nal step involves our interpretation of the ‡ows which gives our …nal decomposition f 0 dut = dudemog + duhiring + dulayof + dum t t t t

+duquit t

IU

+ dU lf + dU lf + dut +

(22)

t

with dudemog =d t duhiring t

t;

= (1

)

d

t t

N X (

UE UE i i

E + aU i

IEjI LF i

IEjI LF ) i

i=1

where the second term comes from Approx. 2 and captures the contribution of movements in the average conditional job …nding rate of the inactives ( f dulayof t

=

N X

l EU l d EU i it

and

duquit t

=

i=1

dU LF exit

=

N X

N X

IEjI LF

to

),

q EU q d EU i it ,

i=1

EI EI i d it

+

UI UI i d it

I + aU i

IEjI LF i

IEjI LF i

UI d i

U LF I it U LF I

i=1

U lf I

where the third term comes from Approx. 2 and captures the contribution of movements in the average conditional job …nding rate of the inactives ( U duIt

=

N X

aIi

IEjI LF i

IEjI LF d i

I U =I

it

+

I LF i

I U LF i

I I LF i

IEjI LF

to

),

d I U =I

it

i=1

where the …rst term comes from Approx. 2 and captures the contribution of

IU I

to

movements in the inactives conditional job …nding rate, and the second term captures

9

the contribution of (

IjI LF

duLF t

IU I

to movements in the inactives’ average labor force entry rate

),

entry

=

N X

I LF i

d

I U LF i

I LF it

I I LF i

d I U =I

it

i=1

where the second term removes the composition e¤ect (on

IjI LF

) coming from the

composition of the inactivity pool and the share of marginally attached, 0 dum t

=

N X

UE UE i i

dm0t m0

+

i=1

with sU it

UE it UE t

U lf E it UE t

and slf it

dsU it sU i

E + aU i

IEjI LF i

IEjI LF i

dm0t m0

+

dslf it slf i

.and where the last two terms come from Approx. 2 and

capture the contribution of matching e¢ ciency to movements in the average conditional job …nding rate of the inactives (

5

IEjI LF

A ‡ow decomposition of

)

IU I

Figure 9 plots aggregate movements in I U =I over 1994-2010 along with the movements in I U =I generated solely by movements in

IU II

account for virtually all of the movements in con…rms it and shows that variance of

6

ItU It

IU II

and

II IU

and ItU It

II IU

and shows that these two hazard rates

since 1994. A variance decomposition exercise

account for, respectively, 73% and 30% of the

(Table A2).

Extended discussion of the unemployment decomposition

6.1

The three components of unemployment’s trend

In this section, we look more closely at the three factors behind unemployment’s trend: demographics, attachment to the labor force and the fraction of marginally-attached. First, we show that the contribution of demographics owes to the aging of the population and the decline fraction of young workers. Figure 10 decomposes the movements in dudemog t plotted in the main text into the contributions of four demographic groups: Prime-age male, Prime-age female, Younger than 25 and Older than 55. We can see that the aging of the baby boom is behind the contribution of demographics, and that the decline in the share of young workers (male and female) in the working-age population is behind the contribution of demographics. Indeed, younger workers have higher turnover and a much higher unemployment rate than prime-age or old workers, and a decline in the youth share mechanically reduces the aggregate unemployment rate.

10

Second, Figures 11 and 12 show that the contribution of labor force attachment until the early 90s owes to women stronger labor force attachment and in particular to a decrease in their EI rate: employed prime-age females displayed a declining tendency to leave their job and the labor force (as previously emphasized in Abraham and Shimer, 2002). A lower EI rate lowers the unemployment rate, because employed individuals are much less likely to enter the unemployment pool than inactive individuals. Third, Figure 14 shows that the contribution of the declining fraction of marginally attached to unemployment comes from the younger than 25 and prime-age females. Although, as shown in the main text, the decline in the mid-90s is roughly similar across all groups (except for older workers), the younger than 25 and the prime-age females have much larger e¤ects on IU

dut I (in ppt of unemployment), because they have the highest average unemployment rate (as well as lower than average activity rates). As a result, while young workers represent only about 20% of the labor force, they account for about half of the movements in unemployment coming from composition of the inactivity pool.

6.2

Implications for labor supply explanations of unemployment’s trend

While, in the main text, our discussion of popular theories of secular unemployment movements has focused on labor demand explanations, our decomposition can also inform labor supply explanations. In particular, two labor supply changes are suspected to have a¤ected the unemployment rate: (i) a signi…cant decline in the labor force participation of prime-age males and (ii) a signi…cant increase in disability rolls. First, our decomposition shows that the decline in prime-age men’s labor force participation has had little e¤ect on the aggregate unemployment rate. The decline in prime-age men labor force participation rate (Juhn, Murphy and Topel 1991, 2002) can be traced to increases in the Employment-Inactivity and Unemployment-Inactivity transition rates of prime-age men (Figure 11). However, these secular changes have had no discernible e¤ect on the unemployment rate: Figure 13 plots the total contribution of labor force exit to the unemployment rate and shows that there is no trend in the component of unemployment from labor force exit among-prime age males. The reason is simple: a higher UI rate lowers the unemployment rate, but a higher EI rate raises the unemployment rate, because employed individuals are much less likely to enter the unemployment pool than inactive individuals. The increases in both UI and EI rates cancel each other, and the net e¤ect on the unemployment rate is small. Second, it has been suggested that the increase in disability rolls after the mid 80s contributed to lower unemployment. In particular, Autor and Duggan (2003) argue that reduced screening stringency for disability bene…ts and higher earnings replacement ratio lowered the

11

unemployment rate by driving people out of the labor force. This phenomenon is visible in the higher labor force exit rates of prime-age males after the mid-80s (Figure 11). However, again because both UI and EI rates increased, the two changes canceled each other out and the net e¤ect of labor force exit on unemployment (shown in Figure 13) was small or nil.

12

References [1] Abraham, K. and R. Shimer. “Changes in Unemployment Duration and Labor-Force Attachment.” in The Roaring Nineties, Russell Sage Foundation, 2002. [2] Autor, D. and M. Duggan, “The Rise in the Disability Roll and the Decline in Unemployment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118:157-206, 2003. [3] Barnichon, R. and A. Figura. “Labor Market Heterogeneities, and the Aggregate Matching Function,” mimeo, 2011. [4] Elsby, M. R. Michaels and G. Solon. “The Ins and Outs of Cyclical Unemployment,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2009. [5] Juhn, C., K. Murphy and R. Topel. “Why has the Natural Rate Increased over Time,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, (2) pp75-142, 1991. [6] Juhn, C., K. Murphy, R. Topel. “Current Unemployment, Historically Contemplated.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 79-116, 2002. [7] Polivka, A. and S. Miller. “The CPS After the Redesign: Refocusing the Economic Lens.” in Labor Statistics and Measurement Issues, edited by John Haltiwanger, Marilyn Manser, and Robert Topel. University of Chicago Press, 1998 [8] Shimer, R. "Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment," Review of Economic Dynamics, vol. 15(2), pages 127-148, April, 2012.

13

Figure 1: Layo¤ rate from JOLTS and layo¤ rate inferred from matched CPS micro data, 2000-2010.

Figure 2: Quit rate from JOLTS and quit rate inferred from matched CPS micro data, 20002010.

14

Figure 3: Probability of Employment-Unemployment transition following a layo¤ (red line) or a quit (blue line). 2000-2010.

15

16-25 0.55 0.5 0.45 0.4 1976

Data

w25-35 0.7

Fitted value

0.6 0.5 1981

1986

1991 1996 w35-45

2001

2006

2011

1981

1986

1991 1996 w45-55

2001

2006

2011

1981

1986

1991 1996 m25-35

2001

2006

2011

1981

1986

1991 1996 m45-55

2001

2006

2011

1981

1986

1991

2001

2006

2011

0.7

0.6 0.55 0.5 0.45 1976

1976

0.6 0.5 1981

1986

1991 1996 55-85

2001

2006

2011

1976 0.6

0.8 0.4

0.7 0.6 1976

1981

1986

1991 1996 m35-45

2001

2006

2011

1976

0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 1976

1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

2006

2011

1976

1996

Figure 4: The conditional job …nding rate of inactives ( IEjILF ) for the 8 demographic groups and the …tted value implied by Approximation 2. The plotted series are 4-quarter moving averages.

16

.7 Employment probability .2 .3 .4

.5

.6

IE|I-LF

0

.1

UE (dur=10)

0

10 20 30 Unemployment duration (in months)

40

50

60

0

Labor force exit probability .1 .2 .3 .4

.5

.6

.7

Figure 5: Duration dependence in employment probability for labor force entrants. The blue dots denote actual data points over 1976-2010, and the green line is the …tted value from the duration dependence model estimated over 1976-2010. The red point is the conditional job …nding rate of inactives IEjI LF :

0

10 20 30 Unemployment duration (in months)

40

50

60

Figure 6: Duration depedence in labor force exit probability for labor force entrants. The blue dots denote actual data points over 1976-2010, and the green line is the …tted value from the duration dependence model estimated over 1976-2010. 17

.3 .25 Employment probability .15 .2 .1

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

Data: Ag gregate UE Data: UE for labor force entrants

2004

2008

Fitted value

.2

Labor force exit probability .3 .4

.5

Figure 7: Average UE transition rate, average UE transition rate for labor force entrants, and …tted value from duration dependence relation, 1976-2010.

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

Data: UI for labor force entrants

2000

2004

2008

Fitted value

Figure 8: Average UI transition rate for labor force entrants, and …tted value from duration dependence relation, 1976-2010.

18

0.3 U

I /I U

I /I from λ

Fraction of Marginally Attached

0.28

U

I -I

I



I

I -I

U

only

0.26

0.24

0.22

0.2 1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

Figure 9: The fraction of marginally attached in the Inactivity pool, I U =I, along with the U I I U movements in I U =I generated solely by movements in I I and I I , 1994-2011.

w25-55 0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2 ppt of U

ppt of U

m25-55 0.4

0.1 0 -0.1

0 -0.1

-0.2 1976

0.1

-0.2 1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

2006

1976

1981

1986

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1 0 -0.1

2001

2006

1996

2001

2006

0.1 0 -0.1

-0.2 1976

1996

55-85

0.4

ppt of U

ppt of U

16-25

1991

-0.2 1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

2006

1976

1981

1986

1991

Figure 10: Decomposition of the e¤ect of demographics (due to changes in labor force shares) on unemployment (dudemog ) for four demographic groups (male 25-55, female 25-55, younger it than 25, and older than 55). The dashed lines represent the total e¤ect of demographics on unemployment, 1976-2010. The plotted series are 4-quarter moving averages.

19

λEI

Hazard rate

0.05

male female

0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 1976

1981

1986

1991

0.5 Hazard rate

1996

2001

2006

1996

2001

2006

λ UI

0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1976

1981

1986

1991

Figure 11: EI and UI hazard rates for prime-age (25-55) male and female, 1976-2010. The plotted series are 4-quarter moving averages.

w25-55

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1 ppt of U

ppt of U

m25-55

0 -0.1

0 -0.1

-0.2

-0.2

-0.3

-0.3

-0.4 1976

1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

-0.4 1976

2006

1981

1986

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0 -0.1

-0.2 -0.3 1986

1991

2006

1996

2001

2006

0

-0.3 1981

2001

-0.1

-0.2

-0.4 1976

1996

55-85

ppt of U

ppt of U

16-25

1991

1996

2001

-0.4 1976

2006

1981

1986

1991

Figure 12: Decomposition of the e¤ect of labor force exit (from employment only) on unemployment for four demographic groups (male 25-55, female 25-55, younger than 25, and older than 55). The dashed lines represent the total e¤ect of labor force attachment on unemployment, 1976-2010. The plotted series are 4-quarter moving averages.

20

w25-55 0.6

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

ppt of U

ppt of U

m25-55 0.6

0 -0.2 -0.4 1976

0 -0.2

1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

-0.4 1976

2006

1981

1986

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0 -0.2 -0.4 1976

1996

2001

2006

1996

2001

2006

55-85

0.6

ppt of U

ppt of U

16-25

1991

0 -0.2

1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

-0.4 1976

2006

1981

1986

1991

exit (from employment and Figure 13: Decomposition of the e¤ect of labor force exit duLF t from unemployment) on unemployment for four demographic groups (male 25-55, female 25-55, younger than 25, and older than 55). The dashed lines represent the total e¤ect of labor force attachment on unemployment, 1976-2010. The plotted series are 4-quarter moving averages. w25-55

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

ppt of U

ppt of U

m25-55

0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 1976

0 -0.1 -0.2

1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

-0.3 1976

2006

1981

1986

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0

-0.1

-0.2

-0.2 1981

1986

1991

2001

2006

1996

2001

2006

0

-0.1

-0.3 1976

1996

55-85

ppt of U

ppt of U

16-25

1991

1996

2001

-0.3 1976

2006

1981

1986

1991

Figure 14: Decomposition of the e¤ect of the fraction of marginally attached on unemployment U (duIt ), in units of ppt of unemployment, for four demographic groups (male 25-55, female 25U 55, younger than 25, and older than 55). The sum of the four lines yields the total e¤ect duIt , 1976-2010. The plotted series are 4-quarter moving averages. 21

Table A1: Estimation of duration dependence Dependent variable:

λUE (d )

λUE (d )

Sample (monthly frequency)

1976-2010

1976-2010

(1) NLS -0.20*** (0.03) 0.23*** (0.01)

(2) NLS -0.009*** (0.001) 0.98*** (0.02)

Regression Estimation β Ф0

Note: Standard-errors are reported in parentheses. *** denotes significance at the 99% confidence interval

Table A2 : Variance decomposition of steady-state fraction of marginally attached, 1994:Q1-2010:Q4

λI U

I /U

I U

I

0.73

λI

U I

I

0.30

λI

E

λI U

λEI

-0.13

0.08

0.01

I

I

U

λI

U

E

0.02

λI

U

U

-0.01

other 0.00

Online Appendix "Why did the US unemployment rate ...

transition probabilities obtained from matched data for each demographic group. ..... rate than prime-age or old workers, and a decline in the youth share ...

395KB Sizes 1 Downloads 201 Views

Recommend Documents

Why did the U.S. unemployment rate used to be so low?∗ (and why it ...
or education groups, suggesting a common driving factor behind this trend. ...... in the online Appendix, we combine information from the CPS and the JOLTS and find ..... less, Some college or associated degree, Bachelors or higher degree.

Why did the U.S. unemployment rate used to be so low?∗ (and why it ...
In May 1979, a business cycle peak, the unemployment rate bottomed at 5.6%. ..... or in two steps by first leaving the labor force (U-I) and then by finding a job directly from ... available (i.e., the level of hiring) or how many inactive individual

Why Did the Average Duration of Unemployment ...
Figure 2 indicates that the increase in the average duration occurred around 1980.5 .... The relatively small value in recent years reflects the coexistence of a low ..... model, the job finding rate does not vary sufficiently in the business cycle .

Technical Appendix ìInvoluntary Unemployment and the Business Cycleî
ìInvoluntary Unemployment and the Business Cycleî by. Lawrence J. Christiano, Mathias ... Equation numbers refer to equation numbers in the text of the paper.

The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of ...
we should expect employers to bid wage rates up quite rapidly, each firm and each ... bidding for labour. Assuming .... f- Curve fitted to 1861 -1913 data ul. W. 3.

The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of ...
of change of money wage rates, which are the price of labour services. When the demand for ..... f- Curve fitted to 1861 -1913 data ul. W. 3. =-. 0. E. W m. Jz. V. - I.

Online Appendix
Aug 13, 2013 - Online Appendix Figures 3a-4e present further evidence from the survey .... Control variables include age, gender, occupation, education, and ...

Foreclosure Delay and US Unemployment
Mar 19, 2012 - Redefaults, Self-Cures and Securitization.' NBER Working Paper, 2009. [2] Ambrose, B., R. Buttimer, and C. Capone. 1997. “Pricing Mortgage Default and Fore- closure Delay.” Journal of Money Credit and Banking. [3] Benjamin, D. and

Online Appendix for: Who Migrates and Why? Evidence ...
better idea for the intuition behind this restriction note that vit. = uitn − uits − ... it = yits), i.e. if the individual was observed working in the source country last period. Then the outcome equations conditional on actually being observed

Why did chicken cross road.pdf
Henry David Thoreau: To live deliberately ... and suck all the marrow out of life. Darth Vader: (Whshhhhhhhhsh) Because it could not resist the power of the.

Did the US Tobacco Industry become more collusive ...
Jul 26, 2010 - This fear was lifted as approximately 41 non-settling companies were forced to join the MSA and did not have to pay damages unless they increased ... copied and distributed anonymously before posted on the web in July 1995 by Universit

Online Appendix
Power Capital Variables adds up all ranking positions by terms (excluding the above top 4 positions). 2 ever held by native officials connected to a commune (in.

Online Appendix
Aug 13, 2013 - Online Appendix Figures 3a-4e present further evidence from the survey responses on the .... Notes: Data from a survey of 70 individuals in 9 villages. ...... You will stay in the assigned room for 20 minutes listening to a.

Online Appendix
Length of business registration in days. 2. Land access sub-score ..... Trends. Province trends. Cluster. Commune. Commune. Commune. Commune. Province.

Online Appendix
When γ = 1, Equation 3 becomes α(p – c) = 1 + exp(δ – αp). The left-hand ... We averaged daily five-year maturity credit default swap (CDS) spreads on GM debt.

California's unemployment rate decreases to 6.7 percent ... - EDD
Mar 20, 2015 - SACRAMENTO – California's unemployment rate decreased to 6.7 percent in ... Three categories (information; other services; and government) ...

California's unemployment rate decreases to 10.9 percent - EDD
Mar 9, 2012 - SACRAMENTO – California's unemployment rate decreased to 10.9 percent ... Information posted the largest decrease over the month, down ...

California's unemployment rate decreases to 6.2 percent ... - EDD
Aug 21, 2015 - SACRAMENTO – California's unemployment rate decreased to 6.2 ... information; financial activities; professional and business services; ...

California's unemployment rate falls to 5.3 percent in November - EDD
Dec 16, 2016 - With November's job gains, the state has gained a total of 2,417,100 ... Three industry sectors (information; educational and health services; ...

California's unemployment rate decreases to 6.7 percent - EDD
Mar 20, 2015 - SAN DIEGO. 1,551,600. 1,468,600. 83,000. 5.3%. SAN FRANCISCO. 540,900. 520,500. 20,400. 3.8%. SAN LUIS OBISPO. 141,100. 134,100.

California's unemployment rate falls to 5.2 percent in December - EDD
Jan 20, 2017 - businesses measures jobs in the economy. The year-over ... It estimates the number of Californians holding jobs in December was. 18,377,000 ...

California's unemployment rate falls to 5.1 percent in January - EDD
Mar 3, 2017 - The survey of 58,000 California businesses ... the number of Californians holding jobs in January was 18,176,000, an increase of 11,000 from.