Mathematical Finance, Vol. 18, No. 3 (July 2008), 445–472

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM WITH CES UTILITY KYOUNG JIN CHOI Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin-Madison GYOOCHEOL SHIM School of Business Administration, Myongji University YONG HYUN SHIN Financial Engineering Research Center, KAIST

We study optimal portfolio, consumption-leisure and retirement choice of an infinitely lived economic agent whose instantaneous preference is characterized by a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function of consumption and leisure. We integrate in one model the optimal consumption-leisure-work choice, the optimal portfolio selection, and the optimal stopping problem in which the agent chooses her retirement time. The economic agent derives utility from both consumption and leisure, and is able to adjust her supply of labor flexibly above a certain minimum work-hour, and also has a retirement option. We solve the problem analytically by considering a variational inequality arising from the dual functions of the optimal stopping problem. The optimal retirement time is characterized as the first time when her wealth exceeds a certain critical level. We provide the critical wealth level for retirement and characterize the optimal consumption-leisure and portfolio policies before and after retirement in closed forms. We also derive properties of the optimal policies. In particular, we show that consumption in general jumps around retirement. KEY WORDS: consumption, leisure, portfolio selection, retirement, CES utility, labor income

1. INTRODUCTION We study optimal portfolio, consumption-leisure and retirement choice of an infinitely lived economic agent whose instantaneous preference is characterized by a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function of consumption and leisure. The problem is formulated mathematically as a mixture of portfolio and consumption-leisure choice and an optimal stopping time problem. In the consumption-leisure and portfolio choice problem the agent chooses optimally consumption, leisure and portfolio (c, l, π ) and in the optimal stopping problem she chooses the time of retirement τ .

We are grateful to two anonymous referees and an associate editor for helpful comments and advice. We also appreciate Hyeng Keun Koo for helpful comments. Manuscript received May 2006; final revision received April 2007. Address correspondence to Yong Hyun Shin, Financial Engineering Research Center, Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology (KAIST), Seoul 130722, Republic of Korea; e-mail: [email protected].  C 2008 The Authors. Journal compilation  C 2008 Blackwell Publishing Inc., 350 Main St., Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK.

445

446

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

The economic agent in this paper derives utility from both consumption and leisure, and is able to adjust her supply of labor flexibly above a certain minimum work-hour, and also has a retirement option. Namely, the agent chooses her hours of work every day and eventually a retirement time considering the trade-off between the utility effect of leisure and the wealth effect of labor. Before retirement the agent receives income at a rate proportional to her hours of work. We assume that she has to work minimum hours in order to keep her employment, but is free to choose her hours of work above this minimum level. Retirement is an irreversible decision that allows the agent to enjoy leisure full-time at the cost of foregone wage income. We solve the problem analytically by considering a variational inequality arising from the dual functions of the optimal stopping problem. A general property of the solution is that the optimal retirement time is the first time when her wealth exceeds a certain critical level. We provide the critical wealth level for retirement and characterize the optimal consumption-leisure and portfolio policies before and after retirement in closed forms. We can derive a few results concerning the behavior of the optimal policies. We first compare the optimal strategies in our model with those in a different model where the agent does not have a retirement option and is always forced to work at least for minimum hours (for instance, under slavery) and show that the agent consumes less and invests more in the risky asset in our model where she has a retirement option than she does when there is no such option (see Figures 5.1 and 5.2). Intuitively, with a retirement option at hand the agent tries to accumulate her wealth fast enough to reach the critical level. After attaining the wealth level, she is able to enjoy leisure full-time; this incentive lets her save more and take more risk. Consistent with this intuitive explanation, it can be shown that typically as the agent’s wealth approaches the critical level she tends to invest in the risky asset more aggressively. We also show that generally there is a consumption jump at the critical wealth level; the hours of leisure jumps around retirement and consumption jumps as well. Some numerical examples are provided. And we also consider the liquidity constraints. To model the liquidity constraints for the future income arises another free boundary in a variational inequality problem, which eventually requires massive algebraic calculation, especially in the case of CES utility, but it is still tractable in a reasonable condition. Bodie et al. (1992) have studied an optimal consumption and investment problem of an economic agent who has flexibility in labor supply and shown that flexibility in labor supply tends to increase the agent’s risk taking in market securities. Bodie et al. (2004) have studied a similar problem in the context of retirement planning, i.e., there is a fixed time of retirement and the agent chooses consumption and investment in preparation for a scheduled retirement. However, they have not solved for the agent’s optimal choice of retirement time, as we have done in this paper. Karatzas and Wang (2000) first studied a discretionary stopping problem by using the martingale method. They have introduced the family of stopping time problems to reduce the problems into easy forms. Choi and Koo (2005) have studied the effect of a preference change around a discretionary stopping time. Jeanblanc et al. (2004) have solved a problem of an agent under obligation to pay a debt at a fixed rate who can declare bankruptcy by using the dynamic programming method. Choi and Shim (2006) have studied a problem in which a wage earner can choose consumption/investment policies, and the time to retire considering a trade-off between income and disutility from labor by using the dynamic programming method. But they have not considered the consumption-leisure choice problem as we have done in this paper. He and Pag`es (1993) have studied the optimal consumption and portfolio problem in which the agent is subject to the liquidity constraints (see also Dybvig and Liu 2005).

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

447

Farhi and Panageas (2007) have independently studied a model similar to ours. They have considered the optimal consumption and portfolio problem with retirement time. They have solved this problem with Cobb–Douglas utility and a binomial choice of leisure (l1 = 1 or l¯ when retired) with the liquidity constraints and the finite horizon problem with retirement. The main difference between our paper and theirs consists of two aspects. First, in this paper we employ a general CES utility to model choice between consumption and leisure, whereas they have confined their attention to the Cobb–Douglas utility function, which is a special case of the CES function. Second, we allow a continuum of choice between labor and leisure, while they have considered a binomial choice, to work or to retire. Whether labor supply is flexible or not is largely an empirical question. However, consideration of flexible labor supply has contributed greatly to the understanding of macroeconomic labor supply, consumption and asset prices (see, e.g., Mankiw et al. 1985; Eichenbaum et al. 1988; Kennan 1988; Basak 1999). Furthermore, the general CES specification allows the elasticity of substitution between labor and leisure to take any positive real numbers, and therefore, becomes an essential feature when labor supply flexibility is introduced in the model (see Basak 1999). The rest of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides the financial market model and Section 3 describes the optimization problem. In Section 4, we introduce the results of the duality approach. Section 5 provides a value function by solving a free boundary value problem and characterizes the optimal policies for an agent with general CES utility. Some numerical examples are also provided. In Section 6, we consider the case in which the agent is subject to the liquidity constraints. Section 7 concludes. All detailed proofs in this paper are given in the appendices.

2. THE FINANCIAL MARKET MODEL 2.1. The Economy We consider a continuous-time financial market with an infinite-time horizon. Assume that there are N + 1 assets. One asset is a riskless asset with a constant interest rate r > 0 and the others are N risky assets (or stocks) whose price processes are governed by the stochastic differential equation (SDE) with constant parameters, the column vector b = (bj ) of mean rates of return and a volatility N σ j k dBk (t)], where B(t) = matrix σ = (σ j k ) j , k = 1, . . . , N, dS j (t) = Sj (t)[b j dt + k=1 (B1 (t), B2 (t), . . . , BN (t)) is an N-dimensional standard Brownian motion on a probability space (, F, P), where the superscript  denotes the transpose of a matrix or a vector. {Ft }∞ t=0 is the augmentation under P of the natural filtration generated by B(t). We assume that the matrix σ is nonsingular. We now define the market price of risk, the discount process, the exponential martingale, and the state-price-density process (or pricing kernel), respectively, by θ  σ −1 (b − r 1 N ), ζ (t)  exp{−r t}, Z0 (t)  exp{−θ  B(t) − 12 ||θ ||2 t}, and H(t)  ζ (t)Z0 (t) = exp{−(r + 12 ||θ||2 )t − θ  B(t)}, where 1N = (1, . . . , 1) denotes the column vector of N ones. For each given fixed T > 0, we define the equivalent martingale measure P˜ (A)  ˜ E[Z0 (T)1 A], forA ∈ FT . By Girsanov’s Theorem, we obtain the new process B(t) = ˜ B(t) + θ t, 0 ≤ t ≤ T, which is a standard Brownian motion under P. Let Xt be the wealth of an agent at time t and let πj (t) be the amount invested  in the risky asset Sj (t) at time t, then Xt − Nj=1 π j (t) can be invested in the riskless t asset. πt  (π1 (t), π2 (t), . . . , πN (t)) is Ft -measurable adapted such that 0 ||πs ||2 ds <

448

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

∞, for all t ≥ 0, almost surely (a.s.). Let ct ≥ 0 be the agent’s consumption rate at time t; it is progressively measurable with respect to Ft and nonnegative a.s. A novel feature of our model is that the agent chooses between labor and leisure. The ¯ Therefore, if we let sum of rates of labor and leisure is assumed to be a constant L. lt ≥ 0 be the rate of leisure at time t, which is progressively measurable with respect to Ft , ¯ − lt is the rate of work at time t, so that the (effective) total hours of work between then L s ¯ − lu ) du. t and s is given by t ( L We assume that the wage rate is a constant w. Therefore, if the agent works at the ¯ − lt ) at time t. We also assume ¯ − lt , then she receives labor income at the rate w( L rate L t that ct satisfies 0 cs ds < ∞, for all t ≥ 0, a.s. The agent chooses her retirement time τ , which is assumed to be an Ft -stopping time. ¯ − L > 0 in order to keep her We assume that the agent should work at least at the rate L employment before retirement. That is, L > 0 is the maximum rate of leisure the agent can choose before retirement. Furthermore, we assume that retirement is a once-and-for-all decision, i.e., the agent cannot come back to work after retirement.1 The assumptions can be summarized as (2.1)

¯ 0 ≤ lt ≤ L < L,

for 0 ≤ t < τ

and

¯ lt = L,

for t ≥ τ.

In particular, the agent cannot enjoy leisure full-time before retirement. (c,l,π,x) A consumption-leisure-portfolio plan of the agent is a triple (c, l, π ). Let Xt = Xt be the agent’s wealth process corresponding to a given consumption-leisure-portfolio plan (c, l, π ) with an initial wealth X0 = x. Therefore the agent’s wealth process Xt evolves according as   ¯ − lt ) dt + πt σ dB(t). (2.2) dX t = rX t + πt (b − r 1 N ) − ct + w( L The consumption-leisure-portfolio plan (c, l, π ) is called admissible until the stopping ¯ (c,l,π,x) (c,l,π,x) time τ if Xτ ≥ 0 and X t > − wrL for 0 ≤ t < τ .2 After retirement the agent faces the liquidity constraints Xt ≥ 0 for all t ≥ τ a.s.3 Under P˜ the wealth process (2.2) is rewritten as (2.3)

¯ − lt )] dt + πt σ dB(t). ˜ dX t = [rX t − ct + w( L

ˆ formula, we have By Ito’s   t ¯  t ¯ wL wL ˜ + + (2.4) ζ (t) Xt + ζ (s)(cs + wls ) ds = x + ζ (s)πs σ dB(s). r r 0 0 For an admissible plan (c, l, π ) until a stopping time τ , the third term on the right-hand side of equation (2.4) is a continuous P˜ -local martingale bounded below and therefore a supermartingale by Fatou’s Lemma. Thus the optional sampling theorem implies   τ ¯ ¯ 

wL wL (2.5) ≤ x+ , E H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt + H(τ ) Xτ + r r 0 for all τ ∈ S where S denotes the set of all F-stopping time τ ’s. 1

The assumption that there is a positive minimum for the rate of labor is necessary in order to guarantee the existence of a finite retirement time. If we allow the agent to voluntarily choose a zero labor rate before retirement, then she will never retire. Choosing a zero labor rate is a better option than retirement, because the agent has an option to work alive by choosing the former. An obvious shortcoming of the assumption is that we cannot deal with involuntary unemployment in our model. ¯ 2 We consider w L r as the present value of the future income of the agent. So she is able to consume and ¯

invest as long as her wealth level does not fall below − wrL . 3 We will consider the case in which the agent has the liquidity constraints for all t ≥ 0 in Section 6.

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

449

2.2. The Utility Function The agent has the following von Neumann–Morgenstern utility function:  ∞ U e−βt u(ct , lt ) dt, 0

where β > 0 is the subjective discount rate and a CES utility function is defined by {αcρ + (1 − α)l ρ } (2.6) u(c, l)  1−γ

1−γ ρ

,

ρ < 1,

ρ = 0,

0 < α < 1, γ > 0 and γ = 1.

Stiglitz (1969) studied behavior toward risk with multiple commodities and defined coefficient of relative (or absolute) risk aversion as that of the indirect utility function of income when the relative prices of the commodities are fixed. In (2.6) γ is the Stiglitz coefficient of relative risk aversion when we think of consumption and leisure as two different commodities, 1/(1 − ρ) is the elasticity of substitution between consumption and leisure and α is a parameter that measures the share of consumption’s contribution to agent’s period utility.  We introduce a convex dual function u(·) ˜ of a concave function u(·, ·) by u(y) ˜ sup{c≥0,L≥l≥0} [u(c, l) − (c + wl)y]. Let I1,c (·) be the inverse function of ∂u (·, L), then we ∂c obtain u(y) ˜ = A1 y−

1−γ γ

1{y≥ y˜ } + [u(I1,c (y), L) − {I1,c (y) + w L}y]1{0
where 1−γ γ α ργ A1  1−γ



 1+w

αw 1−α

(1−ρ)(1−γ ) 1  ρ−1 ργ

and y˜  α

1−γ ρ



αw 1−α

γ  1−ρ

 1+w

αw 1−α

1−ρ−γ 1  ρ−1 ρ

L−γ .

It can be easily shown that u(·) ˜ is strictly decreasing and strictly convex.

3. THE OPTIMIZATION PROBLEM The following assumption is a standard assumption to make the optimization problem well-defined and holds throughout the paper without further comments. ASSUMPTION 3.1. K r+

γ −1 β −r + ||θ ||2 > 0. γ 2γ 2

Now the agent’s problem is to maximize her expected utility:

 ∞ e−βt u(ct , lt ) dt J(x; c, l, π, τ )  E 0

450

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

subject to the budget constraint (2.5) and the leisure constraint (2.1). We rewrite J(x; c, l, π, τ ) as  τ

 ∞ −βt −βt ¯ (3.1) e u(ct , lt ) dt + e u(ct , L) dt J(x; c, l, π, τ ) = E τ

0



τ

=E 0



. e−βt u(ct , lt ) dt + e−βτ U X (c,l,π,x) τ

Then the value function is defined by V(x) 

sup

J(x; c, l, π, τ ),

(c,l,π,τ )∈A(x)

where A(x) is the set of all admissible plans (c, l, π, τ ) such that

 τ

(c,l,π,x)  −βt − −βτ − E e u (ct , lt ) dt + e U X τ < ∞, 0



where u  max(−u, 0). REMARK 3.1. We see that the optimal policies after retirement are obtained using the solution of the Merton problem (see a similar result in proposition 2.4 of Jeanblanc et al. [2004]). That is, for any τ ∈ S and Fτ -measurable random variable η there exists a consumption-portfolio plan {(ˆct , πˆ t ) : t ≥ τ } such that  ∞

 −βτ  −βt ¯ E e U(η)1{τ <∞} = E e u(ˆct , L) dt , τ

where the wealth dynamics is governed by   dX t = rX t + πˆ t (b − r 1 N ) − cˆ t dt + πˆ t σ dB(t), t ≥ τ, Xτ = η. We can also develop U(·) according to the framework of Karatzas et al. (1986). ¯ For notational simplicity, we let u L¯ (c)  u(c, L). LEMMA 3.1. U(·) in (3.1) is given by U(x) = J0 (C(x, 0)), where C(·, 0) is the inverse function of X0 (·),     (u L¯ (c))m− ∞ (u L¯ (c))m+ c dz dz c 2 + , X0 (c) = − m+ r ||θ ||2 (m+ − m− ) m+ m− (u L¯ (z))m− 0 (u L c ¯ (z))   1 1 ||θ||2 m2 − r − β − ||θ||2 m − r = 0, 2 2 where there are two real roots, m− < −1 and m+ > 0, and     (u L¯ (c))n − ∞ (u L¯ (c))n + c u L¯ (c) 2 dz dz + − J0 (c) = m+ β ||θ||2 (n + − n − ) n+ n− (u L¯ (z))m− 0 (u L c ¯ (z)) with n+ = m+ + 1 and n− = m− + 1. Moreover the optimal portfolio and consumption are πˆ t = −σ −1 θ

U (Xt ) U (Xt )

and

cˆ t = c∗∗ ,

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

451

where c∗∗ is the solution to the following algebraic equation   1−γ −ρ ¯ ρ ρ = U (Xt ). α(c∗∗ )ρ−1 α(c∗∗ )ρ + (1 − α) L Proof . In the case of ρ < 0 and γ > 1, we have u L¯ (0) = −∞. The proof is done by theorem 11.4 of Karatzas et al. (1986). In the other case, we have u L¯ (0) < ∞. Then, we  apply theorem 10.1 of Karatzas et al. (1986). ˜ of a concave function U(·) by U(y) ˜ Now we introduce a convex dual function U(·)  ¯ sup{x≥0} [U(x) − (x + wrL )y]. Let I2 (·) be the inverse function of U (·), then we obtain  ¯ wL ˜ y. U(y)  U(I2 (y)) − I2 (y) + r ˜ is also strictly decreasing and strictly convex. The dual function U(·)

4. THE MARTINGALE METHOD We now proceed to solve the optimization problem using a martingale approach. For any fixed stopping time τ ∈ S, τ (x) is denoted by the set of consumption-leisure-portfolio plan (c, l, π ) for which (c, l, π, τ ) ∈ A(x). Define the following utility maximization problem Vτ (x) 

sup

J(x; c, l, π, τ ).

(c,l,π )∈τ (x)

For a Lagrange multiplier λ > 0, we define a dual value function (4.1) ˜ τ) V(λ;    τ ¯   wL (c,l,π,x) .  sup(c,l,π)∈τ (x) × J(x; c, l, π, τ ) − λE H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt + H(τ ) X τ + r 0 Then



τ

˜ τ) = E V(λ;

e

−βt

βt

u(λe ˜ H(t)) dt + e

−βτ

βτ ˜ U(λe H(τ )) .

0

For a fixed τ we can determine optimal policies (cλ , lλ , πλ ) to problem (4.1). We consider the first order conditions, for 0 ≤ t < τ (4.2)

∂u ∂u (cλ (t), lλ (t)) = λeβt H(t) and (cλ (t), lλ (t)) = wλeβt H(t), on {0 ≤ lλ (t) ≤ L}, ∂c ∂l

∂u (cλ (t), L) = λeβt H(t) and lλ (t) = L, otherwise. ∂c By the duality argument, we also have (4.3)

(4.4)

cλ (t) + wlλ (t) = −u˜ (λeβt H(t)), 0 ≤ t < τ.

The optimal replicating portfolio πλ , satisfying the wealth process (4.5)

X τ(cλ ,lλ ,πλ ,x) = −

¯ wL − U˜ (λeβτ H(τ )), r

452

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

exists by the following lemma, that is, there exists the optimal portfolio πλ corresponding to (cλ , lλ , Xτ ) in (4.2), (4.3), (4.4), and (4.5). LEMMA 4.1. For any τ ∈ S, any Fτ -measurable random variable B with P[B > 0] = 1, any progressively measurable process ct ≥ 0 and lt ≥ 0 that satisfy  τ  ¯ 

¯ wL wL E H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt + H(τ ) B + = x+ , r r 0 there exists portfolio π (·) such that, a.s. (c,l,π,x)

Xt

>−

¯ wL , 0 ≤ t < τ and X (c,l,π,x) = B. τ r

Proof . This lemma is similar to lemma 6.3 of Karatzas and Wang (2000).



Now for a fixed τ , let (cλ , lλ , πλ ) be the policies that provide the supremum value in ˜ τ) (4.1). We have from the definition of Vτ (x) and V(λ; ¯

˜ τ ) + λx + λw L . V(x) = sup Vτ (x) = sup inf V(λ; r τ ∈S τ ∈S λ>0 For a given Lagrange multiplier λ, we define ˜ τ ). ˜ V(λ)  sup V(λ; τ ∈S

Then the following proposition provides the value function V (·), which is an analogue to Karatzas and Wang (2000). ˜ exists and is differentiable for λ > 0, then PROPOSITION 4.1. If V(λ) ¯

λw L ˜ + λx + V(x) = inf V(λ) (4.6) λ>0 r ¯

for any x ∈ (− wrL , ∞). In particular, the optimal policies are represented by (4.2), (4.3), (4.4), and (4.5) with λ attaining the minimum value at (4.6). Proof . See Section 8, especially theorem 8.5 and consequently corollary 8.7 of  Karatzas and Wang (2000).

5. A SOLUTION TO THE FREE BOUNDARY VALUE PROBLEM  ˜ τ ) is rewritten as V(λ; ˜ τ ) = E[ τ e−βt u(y We define yλt  λeβt H(t). Then V(λ; ˜ tλ ) dt + 0 ˜ τλ )]. Let yt = λ exp{(β − r − 1 ||θ||2 )t − θ  B(t)}. By Ito’s ˆ formula, we have e−βτ U(y 2 (5.1)

dyt = yt {(β − r ) dt − θ  dB(t)}.

It can be easily seen that yλt is a unique strong solution to (5.1) with an initial value yλ0 = λ. We consider the following optimal stopping problem

 τ yt =y −βs −βτ ˜ (5.2) e u(y ˜ s ) ds + e U(yτ ) , φ(t, y) = sup E τ >t

t

where we denote E yt =y = E y for simplicity. We consider the differential operator L = 2 ∂ + (β − r )y ∂∂y + 12 ||θ||2 y2 ∂∂y2 acting on a mapping ψ : (0, ∞) × R+ −→ R+ . A solution ∂t

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

453

to the following free boundary value problem is a solution to the optimal stopping problem (5.2). ˜ ·) ∈ VARIATIONAL INEQUALITY 1. Find a free boundary y¯ > 0 and a function φ(·, C 1 ((0, ∞) × R+ ) ∩ C 2 ((0, ∞) × (R+ \{ y¯ })) satisfying (1) Lφ˜ + e−βt u(y) ˜ = 0, y¯ < y (2) Lφ˜ + e−βt u(y) ˜ ≤ 0, 0 < y ≤ y¯ ˜ ˜ y) ≥ e−βt U(y), (3) φ(t, y¯ ≤ y ˜ ˜ y) = e−βt U(y), 0 < y ≤ y¯ (4) φ(t, for all t > 0. We consider the quadratic equation   1 1 (5.3) ||θ||2 n 2 + β − r − ||θ ||2 n − β = 0 2 2 with two roots n+ > 1 and n− < 0, for the next proposition. The next proposition provides a solution to Variational Inequality 1. PROPOSITION 5.1. We consider the function ⎧ A1 − 1−γ ⎪ ⎪ C2 yn − + y γ if y ≥ y˜ ⎪ ⎪ K ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ wL 2yn + ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ y+ D1 yn + + D2 yn − − ⎪ ⎪ r

θ ||2 (n + − n − ) ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  ⎪ y ⎨ zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) × dz v(y) = zn + +1 y ˜ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  y ⎪ ⎪ zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) 2yn − ⎪ ⎪ dz if y¯ < y ≤ y˜ − ⎪ ⎪ 2 (n − n )

θ zn − +1 ⎪ + − y ˜ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  ⎪ ¯ ⎪ wL ⎪ ⎪ y if 0 < y ≤ y¯ , ⎩U(I2 (y)) − I2 (y) + r where y¯ , C2 , D1 , and D2 are determined by the following algebraic equations   1 1 − n − w L 1−n + 1−γ A1 − 1−γ , + n− y˜ γ −n + + y˜ D1 = − n+ − n− γ K n+ − n− r  y¯ zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) 2 y¯ n + D1 y¯ n + + dz ||θ||2 (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1 +

1 − n− n− U(I2 ( y¯ )) + n+ − n− n+ − n−

 I2 ( y¯ ) +

¯ − L) w( L r

 y¯ = 0,

from which y¯ is derived, D2 =

 ¯ − L)  1−n n+ n+ − 1 w( L y¯ −n − U(I2 ( y¯ )) − I2 ( y¯ ) + y¯ − n+ − n− n+ − n− r  y¯ zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) 2 + dz, 2 ||θ|| (n + − n − ) y˜ zn − +1

454

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

and C2 = −

1 n+ − n−



1−γ + n+ γ



A1 − 1−γ n + − 1 w L 1−n − + D2 . y˜ γ −n − − y˜ K n+ − n− r

˜ y) = e−βt v(y) is a solution to Variational Inequality 1 provided that Then φ(t, 1 ¯ − L)y ≤ 0, (5.4) −βU(I2 (y)) + r yI2 (y) − ||θ||2 y2 I2 (y) + u(I1,c (y), L) − yI1,c (y) + w( L 2 for 0 < y ≤ y¯ ,

(5.5)

 y ¯ − L) w( L 2yn + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz y+ D1 y + D2 y + r

θ 2 (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1  y 2yn − zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) − dz − U(I2 (y)) + yI2 (y) ≥ 0,

θ 2 (n + − n − ) y˜ zn − +1 n+

n−

for y¯ < y ≤ y˜ , and

(5.6)

C2 yn − +

¯ A1 − 1−γ wL y γ − U(I2 (y)) + yI2 (y) + y ≥ 0, K r

for y ≥ y˜ . Proof . See Appendix A. ˜ y)) is a solution to Variational Inequality 1, then φ(t, ˜ y) THEOREM 5.1. If the pair ( y¯ , φ(t, coincides with φ(t, y) of (5.2) and an optimal stopping time is given by τ y = inf {s > t|ys ≤ y¯ } < ∞, a.s.

Proof . We directly obtain this result from theorem 10.4.1 of Øksendal (1998).



By the results of Theorem 5.1 and Proposition 4.1, we obtain the value function V (x). ˜ ˜ Since V(λ) is obtained from φ(t, y) at t = 0, y = λ and consequently V(λ) = v(λ). The optimal stopping time corresponding to λ is characterized as τλ = inf{t > 0 | ytλ ≤ y¯ }. So we obtain the value function V (x) using the following theorem. THEOREM 5.2. Let

(5.7)

x˜ = −n − C2 y˜ n − −1 +

¯ 1 − γ A1 − γ1 wL y˜ − γ K r

and

x¯ = I2 ( y¯ ).

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

Then, the value function is ⎧ ¯ 1−γ A1 wL ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ C2 (λ∗∗ )n − + (λ∗∗ )− γ + (λ∗∗ )x + (λ∗∗ ) ⎪ ⎪ K r ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ¯ − L) ∗∗ ⎪ w( L ⎪ ⎪ D1 (λ∗∗ )n + + D2 (λ∗∗ )n − + (λ ) + (λ∗∗ )x ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ r ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎨  λ∗∗ 2(λ∗∗ )n + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) V(x) = + dz ⎪ 2 ⎪ ||θ|| (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1 ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  λ∗∗ ⎪ ⎪ 2(λ∗∗ )n − zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ − dz ⎪ 2 (n − n ) ⎪ ||θ|| zn − +1 ⎪ + − y˜ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩ U(x)

if −

¯ wL r

455

< x ≤ x˜

if x˜ ≤ x < x¯ if x ≥ x¯ ,

where λ∗∗ and λ∗∗ are determined from the following algebraic equations (5.8)

−n − C2 (λ∗∗ )n − −1 +

¯ 1 1 − γ A1 wL (λ∗∗ )− γ − = x, γ K r

for −

¯ wL < x ≤ x˜ r

and (5.9) −n + D1 (λ∗∗ )n + −1 − n − D2 (λ∗∗ )n − −1 − +

2n − (λ∗∗ )n − −1 ||θ ||2 (n + − n − )



λ∗∗ y˜

2n + (λ∗∗ )n + −1 ||θ||2 (n + − n − )



λ∗∗ y˜

zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz zn + +1

¯ − L) zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) w( L = x, dz − n +1 − z r

for x˜ ≤ x < x¯ .

REMARK 5.1. It is easily seen the one-to-one correspondences between λ∗∗ ∈ ( y ˜ , ∞) ¯ and x ∈ (− wrL , x˜ ) at (5.8) and λ∗∗ ∈ ( y¯ , y˜ ) and x ∈ (x˜ , x¯ ) at (5.9) using decreasing property of (5.8) and (5.9) with respect to λ∗∗ and λ∗∗ , respectively.

The optimal stopping times τ ∗ are determined by means of (5.9) such that  ∗∗   (5.10) τ ∗ = τλ∗∗ = inf t > 0  ytλ ≤ y¯ . We now assume that there is 1 risky asset to represent the optimal solution without ∗∗ notational complexity. Let ytλ∗∗ and ytλ be solutions of SDE (5.1) with initial values ∗∗ y0 = λ∗∗ and y0 = λ , respectively. In order to find an optimal portfolio we consider the ∗∗ optimal wealth process. In order to obtain the optimal wealth process we substitute ytλ for λ∗∗ into (5.9). Then (5.11)

¯ − L)

∗∗ n −1

∗∗ n −1 w( L X∗∗ (t) = −n + D1 ytλ + − n − D2 ytλ − − r

λ∗∗ n + −1  yλ∗∗ t 2n + y zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) − 2 t dz θ (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1

∗∗ n −1  yλ∗∗ t 2n − ytλ − zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz. + 2 θ (n + − n − ) y˜ zn − +1

456

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

Similarly we substitute ytλ∗∗ for λ∗∗ into (5.8). Then ¯

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 wL X∗∗ (t) = −n − C2 ytλ∗∗ − + − yt . γ K r

(5.12)

THEOREM 5.3. The optimal policies are given by (c∗ , l ∗ , π ∗ , τ ∗ ) such that ⎧ 1−ρ−γ 1 ργ   ρ−1 ⎪ ⎪

λ∗∗ − γ1 1−γ αw ⎪ ργ ¯ ⎪ ⎪ if − wrL < Xt ≤ x˜ yt 1+w α ⎪ ⎪ 1−α ⎨ , ct∗ = ⎪I yλ∗∗  ⎪ if x ˜ ≤ X < x ¯ ⎪ 1,c t t ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩ c∗∗ if Xt ≥ x¯ ⎧ 1−ρ−γ 1 1 ργ  ρ−1  ρ−1   ⎪ ⎪

λ∗∗ − γ1 1−γ αw αw ⎪ ¯ ⎪ ⎪ α ργ if − wrL < Xt ≤ x˜ yt 1+w ⎪ ⎪ 1−α 1−α ⎨ lt∗ = , ⎪ ⎪ L if x ˜ ≤ X < x ¯ ⎪ t ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩¯ L if Xt ≥ x¯ and

πt∗ =

⎧ θ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ σ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ θ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ σ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎨



n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 n − (n − − 1)C2 ytλ∗∗ − + y γ2 K t

 if −

¯ wL < Xt ≤ x˜ r



∗∗ n −1

∗∗ n −1 n + (n + − 1)D1 ytλ + + n − (n − − 1)D2 ytλ −

∗∗ n −1  yλ∗∗ t 2n + (n + − 1) ytλ + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) + dz 2 θ (n + − n − ) zn + +1 y˜

∗∗ n −1  yλ∗∗ ⎪ t ⎪ 2n − (n − − 1) ytλ − zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) ⎪ ⎪ dz − ⎪ 2 ⎪ θ (n + − n − ) zn − +1 ⎪ y˜ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  ⎪

∗∗ 

∗∗  ∗∗ ⎪ ⎪ 2 ytλ I1,c ytλ − u(I1,c ytλ , L) ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ + 2 if x˜ ≤ Xt < x¯ ∗∗ ⎪ ⎪ θ ytλ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ θ U (Xt ) ⎪ ⎩− if Xt ≥ x¯ σ U (Xt )

with τ ∗ = inf{t > 0 | X∗∗ (t) ≥ x¯ }. In this case c∗∗ is a solution to the following algebraic equation   1−γ −ρ α(c∗∗ )ρ−1 α(c∗∗ )ρ + (1 − α) L¯ ρ ρ = U (Xt ).

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

457

Proof . See Appendix B. Now we will compare the optimal policies in our model with those when the agent does not have a retirement option, i.e., τ is forced to be infinite. This is an optimization problem of an agent who chooses 0 ≤ lt ≤ L. In the case of no retirement option, the optimal consumption and portfolio are given as follows: ⎧   1 1−ρ−γ ργ ⎪ ⎪

λ∗∗ − γ1 1−γ αw ρ−1 ¯ ⎪ ⎨α ργ 1 + w if − wrL < Xt ≤ x˜ N yt,N ∗ 1−α ct,N = ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩ λ∗∗  I1,c yt,N if Xt ≥ x˜ N and

∗ πt,N =

⎧   n − −1 1 − γ A  − γ1  θ 1 λ∗∗ λ∗∗ ⎪ ⎪ n y (n − 1)(C − D ) y + 2 2 t,N ⎪ ⎪σ − − γ 2 K t,N ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎧ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎨  ∗∗ n + −1 ⎪ θ ⎪ λ ⎪ n + (n + − 1)D1 yt,N ⎪ ⎪ σ⎩ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  ∗∗ n+ −1 ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ λ  yλ∗∗ ⎨ 2n + (n + − 1) yt,N t,N zI (z) − u(I (z), L) 1,c

+

⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩

θ 2 (n + − n − )  ∗∗ n− −1 λ  2n − (n − − 1) yt,N

1,c

zn + +1



if −

< Xt ≤ x˜ N

,

dz

∗∗

λ yt,N

zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz zn − +1 + − n−) y˜  ∗∗   ∗∗  ⎫ λ∗∗ λ λ 2 yt,N I1,c yt,N − u(I1,c yt,N , L) ⎬ + 2 λ∗∗ ⎭ θ yt,N



¯ wL r

θ 2 (n

if Xt ≥ x˜ N

where the wealth level corresponding to y˜ is given by x˜ N = −n − (C2 − D2 ) y˜ n − −1 +

(5.13)

¯ 1 − γ A1 − γ1 wL y˜ − γ K r

and the optimal wealth processes are given by (5.14) X∗∗ N (t)

=

 λ∗∗ n + −1 −n + D1 yt,N

+

λ∗∗ n + −1  λ∗∗ yt,N ¯ − L) 2n + yt,N zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) w( L − 2 − dz r θ (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1

λ∗∗ n − −1  2n − yt,N θ 2 (n + − n − )

∗∗

λ yt,N



zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz zn − +1

and (5.15)

¯

λ∗∗ n − −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 wL X∗∗,N (t) = −n − (C2 − D2 ) yt,N + − yt,N . γ K r

REMARK 5.2. It can be easily seen that x ˜ > x˜ N from comparing (5.7) with (5.13) provided that D2 > 0. (Here we assume that D2 > 0.)

458

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

60

Consumption

50

40

30

20

10

0 -400

-200

0

200

400

Wealth Level

FIGURE 5.1. Optimal consumption (β = 0.1, r = 0.02, b = 0.07, σ = 0.2, γ = 2, α = ¯ = 1, L = 0.75, w = 10, and ρ → 0). Dotted line gives optimal consumption for 0.2, L the case where the agent does not have a retirement option, i.e., τ is forced to be infinite, and the solid line gives optimal consumption for the case in our model where retirement time τ is chosen optimality. PROPOSITION 5.2. Suppose that the agent has a CES period utility function, then the agent in our model consumes less and invests more before retirement than she does when there is no retirement option. In other words, ∗ > ct∗ ct,N

for −

¯ wL < Xt < x¯ r

∗ πt,N < πt∗

for −

¯ wL < Xt < x¯ . r

and

Proof . See Appendix C. Figures 5.1 and 5.2 provide illustrations of results concerning the optimal policies in Proposition 5.2. The agent consumes less and takes risk more before the wealth of the agent reaches the critical level, because she has an incentive to reach the level and retire fast enough. This tendency becomes more apparent as the wealth level becomes closer to the critical level. A notable feature of the consumption behavior is its discontinuity at the critical wealth level. This is because the leisure rate is discontinuous at the level. Several numerical examples are given. Figure 5.3 shows that the critical wealth level ¯ fixed). It is clear that if is an increasing function of the maximum leisure rate L (with L the difference between the maximum rate of leisure during employment and the rate of leisure after retirement is smaller, then the agent will choose to retire with higher wealth. Figure 5.4 illustrates that as the wage rate w becomes higher, the critical wealth level becomes higher (it exhibits an approximately linear relationship); the higher the wage rate, the higher the agent’s income while she works, so she tends to retire at a higher

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

459

1400

1200

Portfolio

1000

800

600

400

200

0 -400

-200

0

200

400

600

Wealth Level

FIGURE 5.2. Optimal investment in the risky asset (β = 0.1, r = 0.02, b = 0.07, σ = ¯ = 1, L = 0.75, w = 10, and ρ → 0). Dotted line gives optimal 0.2, γ = 2, α = 0.2, L investment in the risky asset for the case where the agent does not have a retirement option, i.e., τ is forced to be infinite, and the solid line gives optimal investment in the risky asset for the case in our model where retirement time τ is chosen optimality. 1000

Critical Wealth Level

800

600

400

200

0 0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

Maximum Leisure Rate

FIGURE 5.3. The critical wealth level x¯ as a function of the maximum leisure rate ¯ = 1, w = 10, and ρ → 0). L (β = 0.1, r = 0.02, b = 0.07, σ = 0.2, γ = 2, α = 0.2, L

wealth level. Figure 5.5 shows that the critical wealth level is an increasing function of α, which is a weight for consumption in the period utility function. With a higher α, consumption contributes more to the agent’s utility, therefore, the agent tends to retire at a higher wealth level.

460

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

500

Critical Wealth Level

400

300

200

100

0 5

0

15

10

20

Wage Rate w

FIGURE 5.4. The critical wealth level x¯ as a function of the wage rate w (β = 0.1, r = ¯ = 1, L = 0.75, and ρ → 0). 0.02, b = 0.07, σ = 0.2, γ = 2, α = 0.2, L

3,500

Critical Wealth Level

3,000 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

α

FIGURE 5.5. The critical wealth level x¯ as a function of α (β = 0.1, r = 0.02, b = ¯ = 1, L = 0.75, w = 10, and ρ → 0). 0.07, σ = 0.2, γ = 2, L 6. LIQUIDITY CONSTRAINTS 6.1. Introduction In this section, we will consider the optimization problem in which the agent faces liquidity constraints, Xt ≥ 0 for all 0 ≤ t ≤ τ .4 From (2.3) we obtain  τ  τ ¯ − ls )) ds + ˜ ζ (s)(−cs + w( L ζ (s)πs σ dB(s). ζ (τ )Xτ − x = 0

4

0

Since the character of the problem under liquidity constraints is now well-understood, here we sketch derivation of a solution. For a detailed explanation the reader is referred to He and Pag`es (1993), Dybvig and Liu (2005), and Farhi and Panageas (2007).

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

461

Consequently, we have the following budget constraint (cf. (2.5))  τ

¯ dt + H(τ )Xτ ≤ x E H(t)((ct + wlt ) − w L) 0

and the liquidity constraint, Xt ≥ 0 for all 0 ≤ t ≤ τ , takes the form  τ

H(s) H(τ ) ¯ ((cs + wls ) − w L) ds + Xτ , for all 0 ≤ t ≤ τ. (6.1) 0 ≤ Et H(t) H(t) t (See He and Pag`es 1993; Farhi and Panageas 2007.) Similar to He and Pag`es (1993) and Farhi and Panageas (2007), we consider Dt > 0 which is nonincreasing with D0 = 1.5 For any real number λ > 0, we have J(x; c, l, π, τ )

 τ     =E e−βt u(ct , lt ) − λDt eβt H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt + e−βτ U(Xτ ) − λDτ eβτ H(τ )Xτ 0



τ

+ λE 0



τ

≤E 0





τ 0

τ

=E 0

Dt H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt + Dτ H(τ )Xτ

  e−βt u˜ λDt eβt H(t) dt + e−βτ U˜ 1 λDτ eβτ H(τ )

+ λE 



Dt H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt + Dτ H(τ )Xτ



  e−βt u˜ λDt eβt H(t) dt + e−βτ U˜ 1 λDτ eβτ H(τ )



τ

+ λE



0



τ

=E 0

 



τ

0



0

τ

¯ t H(t) dt w LD

0

0



τ 0



τ

H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt −

¯ w LH(t) dt

0



H(s) ¯ H(s) ds dDt wL (cs + wls ) ds − H(t) H(t) 0 t t  τ



  −βt βt −βτ ˜ βτ ¯ e u˜ λDt e H(t) dt + e U 1 λDτ e H(τ ) + λE w LDt H(t) dt + λx τ

H(τ ) Xτ + H(t)



τ



τ

0

τ

=E



 ¯ t H(t) dt + H(τ )Xτ + w LD H(t)E t

τ

≤E

0

 ¯ t H(t) dt + Dτ H(τ )Xτ + w LD

  e−βt u˜ λDt eβt H(t) dt + e−βτ U˜ 1 λDτ eβτ H(τ )

+ λE + λE

τ

Dt H(t)(ct + wlt ) dt −





   βt −βτ ˜ ¯ e−βt u˜ λDt eβt H(t) + w LλD U 1 λDτ eβτ H(τ ) + λx t e H(t) dt + e

˜  V(λ, Dt ; τ ) + λx,

where U˜ 1 (y)  sup [U(x) − xy] = U(I2 (y)) − yI2 (y). {x≥0}

5

Dt has an intuitive interpretation as the integral of shadow prices of the liquidity constraints. See He and Pag`es (1993).

462

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

The second inequality is obtained from constraint (6.1) and dDt ≤ 0. In the last equality, ˜ ˜ Dt ; τ ) + λx] we have defined V(λ, Dt ; τ ). For a fixed τ ∈ S, Vτ (x) ≤ inf{λ>0,Dt >0} [V(λ, and the equality holds if for 0 ≤ t < τ ∂u (ct , lt ) = λDt eβt H(t) ∂c

and

∂u (ct , L) = λDt eβt H(t) ∂c

and lt = L, otherwise,

∂u (ct , lt ) = wλDt eβt H(t), on {0 ≤ lt ≤ L}, ∂l

 Xτ = I2 λDτ eβτ H(τ ) , E and



τ

Et t



τ 0

¯ dt + H(τ )Xτ = x H(t)((ct + wlt ) − w L)

H(s) ¯ ds + H(τ ) Xτ = 0 ((cs + wls ) − w L) H(t) H(t)

for all 0 ≤ t ≤ τ where dDt is nonzero, i.e., D· is not a constant over a neighborhood of ˜ Dt ; τ ) + λx]. Therefore the value function V (·) t. So we obtain Vτ (x) = inf{λ>0,Dt >0} [V(λ, is obtained by V(x) = sup Vτ (x) = sup

inf

˜ [V(λ, Dt ; τ ) + λx].

τ ∈S {λ>0,Dt >0}

τ ∈S

Similar to Karatzas and Wang (2000) we redefine ˜ ˜ ˜ V(λ)  sup inf V(λ, Dt ; τ ) = inf sup V(λ, Dt ; τ ) τ ∈S Dt >0

Dt >0 τ ∈S

and we obtain the value function

  ˜ V(x) = inf V(λ) + λx λ>0

(cf. Proposition 4.1).

6.2. The Optimization Problem For simplicity we again assume that there is only one risky asset, i.e., N = 1. In order ˜ to obtain V(λ) we define  τ

zt =z −βs −βτ ˜ ¯ e {u(z ˜ s ) + w Lzs } ds + e U1 (zτ ) , φ(t, z) = sup inf E τ >t Dt >0

t

βt

t ˆ formula implies dz where zt = λDt e Ht , z0 = λ > 0. Ito’s = dDDt t + (β − r ) dt − θ dBt . zt Then we obtain the following Bellman equation   ∂φ ¯ ˜ + w Lz}, − (6.2) = 0, min Lφ(t, z) + e−βt {u(z) ∂z

where the differential operator is given by L=

∂ 1 ∂2 ∂ + (β − r )z + θ 2 z2 2 . ∂t ∂z 2 ∂z

(For a more detailed derivation of a similar equation, see Section 5 of He and Pag`es [1993]).

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

463

Now let D∗t be the optimal solution of the Bellman equation (6.2), then the optimal stopping time problem can be derived by the following changed variational inequality. VARIATIONAL INEQUALITY 2. Find a free boundary z¯ > 0, zˆ which makes zero wealth ˜ ·) ∈ C 1 ((0, ∞) × R+ ) ∩ C 2 ((0, ∞) × (R+ \{¯z})) satisfying level and a function φ(·,

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

∂ φ˜ (t, z) = 0, z ∂z ∂ φ˜ (t, z) ≤ 0, 0 ∂z −βt ˜

≥ zˆ

< z ≤ zˆ ¯ = 0, z¯ < z ≤ zˆ Lφ + e (u(z) ˜ + w Lz) −βt ¯ ≤ 0, 0 < z ≤ z¯ ˜ ˜ + w Lz) Lφ + e (u(z) −βt ˜ ˜ φ(t, z) ≥ e U 1 (z), z > z¯ ˜ z) = e−βt U˜ 1 (z), 0 < z ≤ z¯ , φ(t,

for all t > 0, with the boundary conditions ∂ φ˜ (t, zˆ ) = 0 ∂z

(6.3)

∂ 2 φ˜ (t, zˆ ) = 0.6 ∂z2

and

Now we need to divide the problem into two cases: one is the case where 0 < z¯ < y˜ < zˆ and the other is the case where 0 < z¯ < zˆ (< y˜ ). The following proposition gives the optimal policies for each case. PROPOSITION 6.1.

(1) (The Case Where 0 < z¯ < y˜ < zˆ ) The optimal policies are given by (c∗ , l ∗ , π ∗ , τ ∗ ) such that ⎧ 1−ρ−γ 1 ργ   ρ−1 ⎪ ⎪

λ∗ − γ1 1−γ αw ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ if 0 ≤ Xt ≤ x˜ 1 yt α ργ 1 + w ⎪ ⎪ 1−α ⎨ , ct∗ =

λ∗  ⎪ ⎪ y if x ˜ I ≤ X < x ¯ ⎪ 1,c 1 t 1 t ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩ c∗∗ if Xt ≥ x¯ 1 ⎧ 1−ρ−γ 1 1 ργ    ρ−1  ρ−1 ⎪ ⎪

λ∗ − γ1 1−γ αw αw ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ α ργ yt 1+w if 0 ≤ Xt ≤ x˜ 1 ⎪ ⎪ 1−α 1−α ⎨ lt∗ = ⎪ ⎪ L if x˜ 1 ≤ Xt < x¯ 1 ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩¯ L if Xt ≥ x¯ 1

6

Equation (1) of Variational Inequality 2 implies that

∂ 2 φ˜ (t, z) ∂z2

∂ 2 φ˜

= 0 for all z > zˆ . By the smooth-pasting,

˜ ·), we obtain ∂ φ˜ (t, zˆ ) = 0 and 2 (t, zˆ ) = 0 at z = zˆ . of φ(t, i.e., ∂z ∂z 7 This case converges to that of Farhi and Panageas (2007) as ρ approaches 0. C 2 -condition

464

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

and ⎧ " ⎪

n + −1

n − −1 θ ⎪ ⎪ n + (n + − 1)c1 ytλ∗ + n − (n − − 1)c2 ytλ∗ ⎪ ⎪ σ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  ⎪ ⎪ ⎪

λ∗ − γ1 A 1 − γ ⎪ 1 ⎪ y if + ⎪ ⎪ γ2 K t ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ " ⎪ ⎪ ⎪

∗ n + −1

∗ n − −1 θ ⎪ ⎪ n + (n + − 1) d1 ytλ + n − (n − − 1) d2 ytλ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪σ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎨

∗ n + −1  yλ∗ ∗ t 2n + (n + − 1) ytλ zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) πt = + dz ⎪ ⎪ 2 (n − n ) ⎪ θ zn + +1 + − y˜ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪

∗ n − −1  yλ∗ ⎪ ⎪ t ⎪ 2n − (n − − 1) ytλ zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) ⎪ ⎪ − dz ⎪ 2 ⎪ θ (n + − n − ) zn − +1 ⎪ y˜ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ 

∗

∗ ⎪ ∗ ⎪ ⎪ 2 ytλ I1,c ytλ − u(I1,c ytλ , L) ⎪ ⎪ + 2 if ⎪ ∗ ⎪ θ ytλ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ θ U (Xt ) ⎪ ⎩− if

0 ≤ Xt ≤ x˜ 1

x˜ 1 ≤ Xt < x¯ 1

σ U (Xt )

with

Xt ≥ x¯ 1

   τ ∗ = inf t > 0  X ∗ (t) ≥ x¯ 1 .

In this case the optimal wealth processes are given by ¯

n −1

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗ − γ1 wL X∗ (t) = −n + c1 ytλ∗ + − n − c2 ytλ∗ − + − yt γ K r and ¯ − L)

∗ n −1

∗ n −1 w( L X∗ (t) = −n + d1 ytλ + − n − d2 ytλ − − r

∗ n −1  yλ∗ t 2n + ytλ + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz − 2 θ (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1

∗ n −1  yλ∗ t 2n − ytλ − zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) + 2 dz. θ (n + − n − ) y˜ zn − +1 (2) (The Case Where 0 < z¯ < zˆ (< y˜ )) The optimal policies are given by (c∗ , l ∗ , π ∗ , τ ∗ ) such that " λ∗  I1,c yt if 0 ≤ Xt < x¯ 1 , ct∗ = c∗∗ if Xt ≥ x¯ 1 " L if 0 ≤ Xt < x¯ 1 lt∗ = ¯ if Xt ≥ x¯ 1 L

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

and ⎧ ⎧  ∗ n + −1  ∗ n − −1 ⎪ θ⎨ ⎪ ⎪ + n − (n − − 1) d2 ytλ n + (n + − 1) d1 ytλ ⎪ σ⎩ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪  ∗ n + −1 ⎪ ⎪  ytλ∗ ⎪ 2n + (n + − 1) ytλ ¯ − L)z + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) ⎪ −w( L ⎪ dz ⎪ + ⎪ 2 (n − n ) θ zn + +1 ⎪ + − z ˆ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎨  ∗ n − −1  ytλ∗ 2n − (n − − 1) ytλ πt∗ = ¯ − L)z + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) −w( L ⎪ − dz ⎪ 2 (n − n ) ⎪ θ zn − +1 + − zˆ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪     ⎫ ⎪ ⎪ ¯ − L)ytλ∗ + ytλ∗ I1,c ytλ∗ − u(I1,c ytλ∗ , L) ⎬ ⎪ −w( L ⎪ 2 ⎪ if ⎪ + 2 ∗ ⎪ ⎭ θ ⎪ ytλ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎩− θ U (Xt ) if σ U (Xt )

with

465

0 ≤ Xt < x¯ 1

Xt ≥ x¯ 1

  τ ∗ = inf t > 0 | X∗ (t) ≥ x¯ 1 .

In this case the optimal wealth process is given by

∗ n −1

∗ n −1 X∗ (t) = −n + d1 ytλ + − n − d2 ytλ −

∗ n −1  yλ∗ ¯ − L)z + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) t 2n + ytλ + −w( L − 2 dz θ (n + − n − ) zˆ zn + +1

∗ n −1  yλ∗ ¯ − L)z + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) t 2n − ytλ − −w( L + 2 dz. θ (n + − n − ) zˆ zn − +1 (Other coefficients are given in Appendix D.)

7. CONCLUSION We have solved an optimal portfolio and consumption-leisure and retirement choice problem of an agent who has a period utility function with a CES between consumption and leisure and a constant Stiglitz relative risk aversion coefficient. We have obtained a closed form solution by solving a free boundary value problem by using a martingale approach. We have provided the optimal policies in closed forms and characterized properties of the optimal policies. The optimal retirement time is characterized by the first hitting time of a threshold wealth level. Generally consumption jumps around retirement due to discontinuity in leisure rates. We have also considered the case with liquidity constraints, i.e., the case where the agent cannot borrow against her future labor income.

APPENDIX A: PROOF OF PROPOSITION 5.1 We consider the PDE (1) of Variational Inequality 1 (A.1)

Lφ + e−βt u(y) ˜ = 0,

y > y¯ ,

466

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

˜ y¯ ). First we consider the equation (A.1) with a boundary condition φ(t, y¯ ) = e−βt U( for y ≥ y˜ . That is, 1−γ ∂ 2φ ∂φ 1 ∂φ + (β − r )y + ||θ||2 y2 2 + e−βt A1 y− γ = 0, ∂t ∂y 2 ∂y

y ≥ y˜ .

Guessing a solution form φ(t, y) = e−βt v(y), then we derive v(y) = C2 yn − +

A1 − 1−γ y γ , K

y ≥ y˜ ,

by solving the second order ordinary differential equation (ODE), where   1 1 2 2 2 ||θ|| n + β − r − ||θ || n − β = 0 2 2 with two roots n+ > 1 and n− < 0. Similarly, for y¯ < y ≤ y˜ , we also derive  y wL 2yn + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz y+ v(y) = D1 yn + + D2 yn − − 2 r ||θ|| (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1  y 2yn − zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) − dz. ||θ ||2 (n + − n − ) y˜ zn − +1 From the principle of the C 1 -condition at y = y˜ and y = y¯ , we derive the coefficients C2 , D1 , D2 and the free boundary y¯ as follows:   1 1 − n − w L 1−n + 1−γ A1 − 1−γ + n− y˜ γ −n + + y˜ , D1 = − n+ − n− γ K n+ − n− r  y¯ zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) 2 y¯ n + D1 y¯ n + + dz 2 ||θ|| (n + − n − ) y˜ zn + +1 1 − n− n− U(I2 ( y¯ )) + + n+ − n− n+ − n−



¯ − L) w( L I2 ( y¯ ) + r

 y¯ = 0,

from which y¯ is derived, D2 =

 ¯ − L)  1−n n+ n+ − 1 w( L I2 ( y¯ ) + y¯ −n − U(I2 ( y¯ )) − y¯ − n+ − n− n+ − n− r  y¯ 2 zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) + dz, 2 ||θ|| (n + − n − ) y˜ zn − +1

and 1 C2 = − n+ − n−



1−γ + n+ γ



n + − 1 w L 1−n − A1 − 1−γ y˜ γ −n − − y˜ + D2 . K n+ − n− r

Now we will show that v (·) is continuous at y = y˜ . It is sufficient to show that n+ (n + − 1)D1 y˜ n + + n − (n − − 1)(D2 − C2 ) y˜ n − − +

2 {−u(I1,c ( y˜ ), L) + I1,c ( y˜ ) y˜ } = 0, ||θ||2

1 − γ A1 − 1−γ y˜ γ γ2 K

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

467

with C2 , D1 and D2 obtained from the previous processes. Now we show the statement as follows:      1−γ 1−γ A1 − 1−γ 1 n + (n + − 1) + n − − n − (n − − 1) + n+ y˜ γ (LHS) = − n+ − n− γ γ K 1 − γ A1 − 1−γ wL 2 y˜ − y˜ γ + {−u(I1,c ( y˜ ), L) + I1,c ( y˜ ) y˜ } r γ2 K ||θ ||2   1−γ 1 − γ A1 − 1−γ + n+n− + y˜ γ = − (n + + n − − 1) γ γ2 K − (n + − 1)(n − − 1)

+

 2 2  − 1−γ γ w L˜ y − y ˜ + w L˜ y =0 A 1 ||θ||2 ||θ||2

since −

1−γ 1−γ 2 + n+n− + K = (n + + n − − 1) 2 ||θ|| γ γ2

and A1 y˜ −

1−γ γ

+ w L˜y = u(I1,c ( y˜ ), L) − I1,c ( y˜ ) y˜

by definition of u(·). ˜ The inequality of (2) of Variational Inequality 1 is equivalent to (5.4) and the inequality  of (3) of Variational Inequality 1 is equivalent to (5.5) and (5.6).

APPENDIX B: PROOF OF THEOREM 5.3 Note that the optimal stopping time τ ∗ is a rewriting of (5.10) by using the optimal wealth process X ∗∗ (t) of (5.11). Also we can easily see the optimal consumption and leisure from Lemma 3.1 and (4.2), (4.3), (4.4), and (4.5). So it is enough to show that the given consumption, leisure and portfolio processes8 generate the optimal wealth processes X∗∗ (t) and X ∗∗ (t) of (5.12) and (5.11), respectively. ¯ ˆ formula to (5.12), then we have For − wrL < Xt ≤ x˜ , applying Ito’s



λ∗∗ n − −2 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − 1+γ γ y dytλ∗∗ − dX ∗∗ (t) = −n − (n − − 1)C2 yt γ2 K t



λ∗∗ n − −3 1 − γ 2 A1 λ∗∗ − 1+2γ

λ∗∗ 2 1 γ dyt + + −n − (n − − 1)(n − − 2)C2 yt yt 3 2 γ K

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 = −n − (n − − 1)C2 ytλ∗∗ − − [(β − r ) dt − θ dB(t)] y γ2 K t



n −1 1 − γ 2 A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 2 1 + θ dt −n − (n − − 1)(n − − 2)C2 ytλ∗∗ − + y 2 γ3 K t ¯

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 wL yt dt − = r −n − C2 ytλ∗∗ − + γ K r 8 For 0 ≤ t < τ , the optimal portfolio is unknown yet. We will compare the coefficients of the wealth ˆ formula to (5.11) and (5.12). Then we can dynamics with those of the SDEs obtained from applying Ito’s determine the optimal portfolio for each case.

468

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN



n − (n − −

2

−α

1−γ ργ

n −1 1)C2 ytλ∗∗ − 

1+w

⎡ ¯ −α + w ⎣L

1−γ ργ

αw 1−α



1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 + y γ2 K t

1−ρ−γ 1 ργ  ρ−1

αw 1−α

1  ρ−1

ytλ∗∗ 

1+w

− γ1

dt

dt

αw 1−α

1−ρ−γ 1 ργ  ρ−1

− 1 ytλ∗∗ γ

⎤ ⎦ dt

A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 β −r γ −1 2 θ −K dt +r + y γ 2γ 2 K t  

n −1 1 2 2 1 − n − C2 θ n − + β − r − θ 2 n − − β ytλ∗∗ − dt 2 2

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 + θ n − (n − − 1)C2 ytλ∗∗ − + dB(t). y γ2 K t

1−γ − γ

Here we can see that the fifth and the sixth terms of the right hand side of the last equality are equal to zero by definitions of K and n’s. (See equation (5.3).) For the last term, if we correspond

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 y , πt∗ σ = θ n − (n − − 1)C2 ytλ∗∗ − + γ2 K t then we obtain   ¯ − lt∗ ) dt + πt∗ σ dB(t). dX ∗∗ (t) = rX ∗∗ (t) + πt∗ (b − r ) − ct∗ + w( L ¯

So the optimal wealth is induced from the strategies (c∗ , l ∗ , π ∗ ) for − wrL < Xt ≤ x˜ . Similarly, for x˜ ≤ Xt < x¯ , we also obtain the optimal portfolio 

πt∗ σ

∗∗ n −1

∗∗ n −1 = θ n + (n + − 1)D1 ytλ + + n − (n − − 1)D2 ytλ −

∗∗ n −1  yλ∗∗ t 2n + (n + − 1) ytλ + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) + dz θ 2 (n + − n − ) zn + +1 y˜

∗∗ n −1  yλ∗∗ t 2n − (n − − 1) ytλ − zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz − 2 θ (n + − n − ) zn − +1 y˜

∗∗ 

∗∗    ∗∗ 2 ytλ I1,c ytλ − u I1,c ytλ , L + 2 . ∗∗ θ ytλ

Thus we obtain  

¯ − lt∗ dt + πt∗ σ dB(t). dX ∗∗ (t) = rX ∗∗ (t) + πt∗ (b − r ) − ct∗ + w L So the optimal wealth is induced from the strategies (c∗ , l ∗ , π ∗ ) for x˜ ≤ Xt < x¯ .



OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

469

APPENDIX C: PROOF OF PROPOSITION 5.2 ∗∗

We see that X ∗∗ (t) and X∗∗ (t) in (5.11) and (5.12) are decreasing with respect to ytλ and ytλ∗∗ , respectively. (We can see from Remark 5.1.) For fixed Xt , so we can see that ∗∗

∗∗

λ ytλ > yt,N

and

λ∗∗ ytλ∗∗ > yt,N

by comparing (5.11) with (5.14) and (5.12) with (5.15), and by the assumption D2 > 0 in Remark 5.2. Thus we obtain from comparing c∗t with c∗t,N ∗ ct,N > ct∗

¯ wL < Xt < x¯ .9 r

for − ¯

∗ Next, we compare πt∗ with πt,N . For − wrL < Xt ≤ x˜ and fixed, we obtain the following equality from (5.12) and (5.15),

¯

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 wL − yt Xt = −n − C2 ytλ∗∗ − + γ K r ¯

λ∗∗ n − −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 wL = −n − (C2 − D2 ) yt,N yt,N . + − γ K r We multiply both sides of the above equality by n− − 1, then we obtain

n −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 y −n − (n − − 1)C2 ytλ∗∗ − + (n − − 1) γ K t

λ∗∗ n − −1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 y = −n − (n − − 1)(C2 − D2 ) yt,N + (n − − 1) γ K t,N and we rewrite the equality as 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 σ yt y + − πt∗ + (n − − 1) θ γ K γ2 K t σ ∗ 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 1 − γ A1 λ∗∗ − γ1 yt,N y = − πt,N + (n − − 1) + . θ γ K γ 2 K t,N Sequentially,

  σ 1 1 − γ A1  λ∗∗ − γ1 λ∗∗ − γ1 ' σ ∗ − yt . πt,N = πt∗ + n − − 1 + yt,N θ θ γ γ K

If we substitute

γ −1 γ

1 2 θ 2



for n into (5.3), then γ −1 γ

So we obtain n − − 1 +

1 γ

2



1 + β − r − θ2 2



γ −1 γ

 − β = −K < 0.

λ∗∗ < 0. Since ytλ∗∗ > yt,N , we obtain ∗ πt,N < πt∗

for − ¯

¯ wL < Xt ≤ x˜ N . r ¯

In fact, we need to divide the interval − wrL < Xt < x¯ into three cases: − wrL < Xt < x˜ N , x˜ N < Xt < x˜ and x˜ < Xt < x¯ . The first and the third cases are obvious. The second case is also trivial since y˜ (= y˜ N ) correspond to x˜ and x˜ N , respectively, and the optimal consumption process is increasing with respect to the wealth process. 9

470

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

Similarly we obtain ∗ πt,N < πt∗

for x˜ N ≤ Xt < x¯ .



APPENDIX D: COEFFICIENTS IN PROPOSITION 6.1 D.1. The Case Where 0 < z¯ < y˜ < zˆ in Proposition 6.1 If we can determine the values of z¯ and zˆ from the following two equations:     ¯ 1−n 1 − γ 1 − γ A1 − n − + 1−γ n+ − 1 w L 1 γ zˆ zˆ − n+ + − n− γ γ K n− r  z¯ ¯ − L) zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) w( L 2 =− dz (n + − 1)¯z1−n − + 2 r θ y˜ zn − +1 + n + z¯ −n − U(I2 (¯z)) − (n + − 1)¯z1−n − I2 (¯z)     1 − γ A1 − n − + 1−γ wL γ y˜ (n + − 1) y˜ 1−n − − − n+ + γ K r and 1 − n+ =



1−γ n− + γ





1 − γ A1 − zˆ γ K

n + + 1−γ γ

¯ − L) w( L 2 (n − − 1)¯z1−n + − 2 r θ



z¯ y˜



+

¯ 1−n n− − 1 w L zˆ + n+ r

zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) dz zn + +1

− n − z¯ −n + U(I2 (¯z)) + (n − − 1)¯z1−n + I2 (¯z)     1 − γ A1 − n + + 1−γ wL γ y˜ (n − − 1) y˜ 1−n + , + + n− + γ K r then we have

    ¯ 1−n 1 1 − γ 1 − γ A1 − n + + 1−γ n− − 1 w L γ + n− + zˆ zˆ + c1 = − n + (n + − n − ) γ γ K n + (n + − n − ) r

and

    ¯ 1−n 1 1 − γ 1 − γ A1 − n − + 1−γ n+ − 1 w L γ n+ + zˆ zˆ − . − c2 = n − (n + − n − ) γ γ K n − (n + − n − ) r

Moreover we can also obtain     1 1 − γ A1 − n + + 1−γ n − − 1 w L 1−n + γ d1 = c 1 − n− + − y˜ y˜ n+ − n− γ K n+ − n− r and 1 d2 = c2 + n+ − n−



1−γ n+ + γ



  n − + 1−γ γ

A1 − y˜ K

+

n + − 1 w L 1−n − y˜ . n+ − n− r

Critical wealth levels are given by x¯ 1 = I2 (¯z) and x˜ 1 = −n + c1 y˜ n + −1 − n − c2 y˜ n − −1 + ¯ 1 − γ A1 − γ1 y˜ − wrL . γ K

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO, CONSUMPTION-LEISURE AND RETIREMENT CHOICE PROBLEM

471

D.2. The Case Where 0 < z¯ < zˆ (< y˜ ) in Proposition 6.1 If we can determine the values of z¯ and zˆ from the following two equations:  1 2 ¯ − L)ˆz + zˆ I1,c (ˆz) − u(I1,c (ˆz), L) zˆ −n − −w( L n− θ 2  z¯ ¯ − L)z + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) −w( L 2 = 2 dz θ zˆ zn − +1 + n + z¯ −n − U(I2 (¯z)) − (n + − 1)¯z1−n − I2 (¯z) and −

 1 2 ¯ − L)ˆz + zˆ I1,c (ˆz) − u(I1,c (ˆz), L) zˆ −n + −w( L 2 n+ θ  z¯ ¯ − L)z + zI1,c (z) − u(I1,c (z), L) −w( L 2 =− 2 dz θ zˆ zn + +1 − n − z¯ −n + U(I2 (¯z)) + (n − − 1)¯z1−n + I2 (¯z),

then we have d1 = −

 2 1 ¯ − L)ˆz + zˆ I1,c (ˆz) − u(I1,c (ˆz), L) zˆ −n + −w( L n + (n + − n − ) θ 2

and d2 =

 1 2 ¯ − L)ˆz + zˆ I1,c (ˆz) − u(I1,c (ˆz), L) zˆ −n − . −w( L 2 n − (n + − n − ) θ

Critical wealth level is given by x¯ 1 = I2 (¯z).

REFERENCES

BASAK, S. (1999): On the Fluctuations in Consumption and Market Returns in the Presence of Labor and Human Capital: An Equilibrium Analysis, J. Econ. Dyn. Control 23, 1029–1064. BODIE, Z., J. B. DETEMPLE, S. OTRUBA, and S. WALTER (2004): Optimal Consumption Portfolio Choices and Retirement Planning, J. Econ. Dyn. Control 28, 1115–1148. BODIE, Z., R. C. MERTON, and W. F. SAMUELSON (1992): Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice in a Life Cycle Model, J. Econ. Dyn. Control 16, 427–449. CHOI, K. J., and H. K. KOO (2005): A Preference Change and Discretionary Stopping in a Consumption and Portfolio Selection Problem, Math. Method Oper. Res. 61, 419–435. CHOI, K. J., and G. SHIM (2006): Disutility, Optimal Retirement, and Portfolio Selection, Math. Finance 16, 443–467. COX, J. C., and C.-F. HUANG (1989): Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Policies When Asset Prices Follow a Diffusion Process, J. Econ. Theory 49, 33–83. DYBVIG, P. H., and H. LIU (2005): Lifetime Consumption and Investment: Retirement and Constrained Borrowing. Working Paper, Washinton University in St. Louis. EICHENBAUM, M. S., L. P. HANSEN, and K. J. SINGLETON (1988): A Time Series Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption and Leisure Choice under Uncertainty, Q. J. Econ. 103, 51–78.

472

K. J. CHOI, G. SHIM, AND Y. H. SHIN

FARHI, E., and S. PANAGEAS (2007): Saving and Investing for Early Retirement: A Theoretical Analysis, J. Financ. Econ. 83, 87–121. HE, H., and H. F. PAGE` S (1993): Labor Income, Borrowing Constraints, and Equilibrium Asset Prices, Econ. Theory 3, 663–696. JEANBLANC, M., P. LAKNER, and A. KADAM (2004): Optimal Bankruptcy and Consumption/Investment Policies on an Infinite Horizon with a Continuous Debt Repayment Until Bankruptcy, Math. Oper. Res. 29, 649–671. KARATZAS, I., J. P. LEHOCZKY, S. P. SETHI, and S. E. SHREVE (1986): Explicit Solution of a General Consumption/Investment Problem, Math. Oper. Res. 11, 261–294. KARATZAS, I., J. P. LEHOCZKY, and S. E. SHREVE (1987): Optimal Portfolio and Consumption Decisions for a “Small Investor” on a Finite Horizon, SIAM J. Control Optim. 25, 1557–1586. KARATZAS, I., and H. WANG (2000): Utility Maximization with Discretionary Stopping, SIAM J. Control Optim. 39, 306–329. KENNAN, J. (1988): An Econometric Analysis of Fluctuations in Aggregate Labor Supply and Demand, Econometrica 56, 317–333. MANKIW, N. G., J. J. ROTEMBERG, and L. H. SUMMERS (1985): Intertemporal Substitution in Macroeconomics, Q. J. Econ. 100, 225–251. MERTON, R. C. (1969): Lifetime Portfolio Selection under Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Case, Rev. Econ. Stat. 51, 247–257. MERTON, R. C. (1971): Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model, J. Econ. Theory 3, 373–413. ØKSENDAL, B. (1998): Stochastic Differential Equations: An Introduction with Applications. New York: Springer. STIGLITZ, J. E. (1969): Behavior Toward Risk with Many Commodities, Econometrica 37, 660– 667.

optimal portfolio, consumption-leisure and retirement ...

School of Business Administration, Myongji University ... grate in one model the optimal consumption-leisure-work choice, the optimal portfolio selection, and the .... Furthermore, we assume that retirement is a once-and-for-all .... the solution of the Merton problem (see a similar result in proposition 2.4 of Jeanblanc et al.

250KB Sizes 0 Downloads 118 Views

Recommend Documents

disutility, optimal retirement, and portfolio selection
DISUTILITY, OPTIMAL RETIREMENT, AND PORTFOLIO SELECTION. KYOUNG JIN CHOI. School of Computational Sciences, Korea Institute for Advanced Study,. Seoul, Korea. GYOOCHEOL SHIM. Graduate School of Management, Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Tech

Time-optimal Active Portfolio Selection
Time-optimal Active Portfolio Selection. Thomas Balzer [email protected]. November 27, 2001. Abstract. In a complete financial market model where the prices of the assets are modeled as Ito diffusion processes, we consider portfolio problems wh

Optimal portfolio and consumption with habit ...
the RRA coefficient is obtained and the numerical experiment indicates our model with .... Another contribution of this literature is numerical experiment in this ...... 717. [28] X. Sun, J. Duan, Fokker–Planck equations for nonlinear dynamical sys

Retirement and Financial Wellbeing - Employee Benefit Research ...
Jan 11, 2018 - 2. Employee Benefit Research Institute: EBRI Policy Forum #82 – Retirement and Financial Wellbeing, January 11, 2018 reactions to such a program were largely positive. After learning additional details about the proposed program, suc

Social Security, Endogenous Retirement and ...
Sep 16, 2013 - pension or spent part of his/her career in federal employment. Pensions often have built-in Social Security offset rules that nullify much of the ...

Measuring America's Retirement Deficit
Feb 17, 2015 - WASHINGTON—How big is the retirement savings gap that most Americans are ... EBRI's new analysis is based on results from its proprietary ...

Retirement Status.pdf
Page 1 of 1. Retirement Status.pdf. Retirement Status.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Retirement Status.pdf. Page 1 of 1.

retirement age.pdf
... see CWP-19770-2014. 3 of 114. ::: Downloaded on - 17-08-2016 19:01:50 ::: WWW.LIVELAW.IN. Page 3 of 114. Main menu. Displaying retirement age.pdf.

retirement age.pdf
There was a problem loading more pages. retirement age.pdf. retirement age.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying retirement age.pdf.

Household Bargaining and Portfolio Choice - Acrobat Planet
We thank Anna Paulson, Robert Pollak, Silvia Prina, Mich`ele Tertilt and participants at the 2009 American Economic Association, Society of Labor Economists, and Midwest. Economic Association meetings for numerous helpful comments. All remaining erro

sales promotion and portfolio presentation.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. sales promotion ...