Applied Economics Letters, 2006, 13, 1–5

Strategic union delegation and incentives for merger Ana Mauleona and Vincent J. Vannetelboschb,* a

FNRS and CEREC, Faculte´s Universitaires Saint-Louis, Brussels, Belgium FNRS and CORE, Universite´ Catholique de Louvain, 34 Voie du Roman Pays, B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium

b

A unionized duopoly model to analyse how unions affect the incentives for merger is considered. It is found that both firms will merge if and only if unions are weak. However, once surplus-maximizing unions have the option to delegate the wage bargaining to wage-maximizing delegates (such as senior union members), both firms may have incentives to merge even if the union bargaining power is strong. Moreover, the option of strategic delegation may harm both the unions and the firms.

I. Introduction Labour market organization plays an important role in determining wage levels and product market structure (see e.g. Horn and Wolinsky, 1988). In this note the option for unions to delegate the wage bargaining is incorporated and how it affects the incentives for merger analysed. Up to now the literature has mainly focused on strategic delegation on behalf of shareholders. Fershtman and Judd (1987) have addressed the issue of strategic managerial delegation in the context of oligopolistic industries with Cournot competition (see also Sklivas, 1987). More recently, Gonza´lezMaestre and Lo´pez-Cun~ at (2001) have considered the interactions between the use of strategic managerial delegation and mergers. They have shown that the incentives for merger, under managerial delegation, are considerably increased with respect to the setting without delegation. Regarding strategic union delegation, Jones (1989) has shown that a divergence between the objectives of union leaders

and union members will naturally arise in a democratic union as part of a rational bargaining strategy. Essentially, the reason is that in many bargaining situations, commitment can be valuable, and the union members can credibly commit to a bargaining stance, which they could not otherwise sustain, by delegating authority to a negotiator whose objectives make this stance an optimal one. More recently, Conlin and Furusawa (2000) have provided an explanation of why senior union members may represent the union in contract negotiations with a monopolist. By strategically delegating contract negotiations to wage-maximizing individuals, the surplus-maximizing union may be better off than if surplus-maximizing individuals negotiate the contract.1 This note goes further by dealing with the interactions between the strategic use of union delegation and the incentives for merger in duopolistic markets. In what follows it is shown that unionization does not always reduce the incentives for merger as advocated in Horn and Wolinsky (1988). Indeed, it is found

*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected] 1 Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2005) have developed a model of wage determination with private information, in which the union has the option to delegate the wage bargaining. They have found that the maximum delay in reaching an agreement (or maximum strike activity) is greater whenever the union chooses wage-maximizing delegates instead of surplus-maximizing delegates and remains finite even when the length of the bargaining period shrinks to zero. Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350–4851 print/ISSN 1466–4291 online # 2006 Taylor & Francis http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals DOI: 10.1080/13504850500392206

1

A. Mauleon and V. J. Vannetelbosch

2 that, once the surplus-maximizing union has the option to delegate the wage bargaining to wagemaximizing delegates, both firms may have incentives to merge even if the union bargaining power is strong. Precisely, both firms may find it profitable to merge and negotiate the wage with surplusmaximizing delegates in order to avoid having to bargain with wage-maximizing delegates. Moreover, it is shown that in such equilibrium the option of strategic delegation harms both the unions and the firms. An important consequence of those findings is that the wisdom that unionization decreases incentives for merger and that strategic union delegation increases benefits for the union should be questioned.

II. The Model Consider a duopolistic market for a single homogenous product, where the demand is linear and is given by P ¼ a  b  Q, P is the market price, and Q is the aggregate quantity demanded. There are two firms indexed by i, i ¼ 1, 2. Let Qi denote the quantity produced by firm i, and let i denote the profit level of each firm i. The only variable input is labour. Technology exhibits constant returns to scale and is normalized in such a way that Qi ¼ Li , where Li is labour input, and the unit production cost of each firm is the wage Wi. Thus, the profit of each firm is given by

union members) who will negotiate the wage with the employer. The objective of a wage-maximizing delegate is simply Vi ¼ Wi  W . In stage three, the wage bargaining occurs. Finally, in stage four the employer chooses the output level. The model is solved backwards. In the last stage of the game, two cases have to be distinguished. First, the case in which the firms have not merged is considered, i.e. the duopoly case. Then, knowing that the wage levels (W1 and W2) have already been determined, the employers of the two firms compete by choosing simultaneously their outputs to maximize their profits. The Nash equilibrium of this stage game yields: Q1D ðW1 , W2 Þ ¼

a þ W2  2W1 3b

Q2D ðW1 , W2 Þ ¼

a þ W1  2W2 3b

PD ðW1 , W2 Þ ¼

a þ W1 þ W2 3

where the subscript ‘D’ identifies the duopoly. Second, the case in which the firms have merged to form a monopoly is considered. Then, knowing that the wage level (W ) has already been determined, the monopolist chooses: QM ðW Þ ¼

aW 2b

PM ðW Þ ¼

aþW 2

where the subscript ‘M’ identifies the monopoly.

i ¼ ða  bQÞQi  Wi  Qi Each firm belongs to and is controlled by one risk-neutral owner. The objective of each owner is to maximize profits. In addition, each firm is unionized, and enters into a closed-shop agreement with its risk-neutral union. The workforce for each firm is drawn from separate pools of labour, and the union objective is to maximize the union surplus, taking as given the wage obtained by the other union: Ui ¼ Li  ðWi  WÞ where W is the reservation wage. In this letter a four-stage game is studied. In stage one, the owners of the firms decide whether or not to merge both firms.2 In stage two, the surplusmaximizing union (of each firm simultaneously) chooses whether to use surplus-maximizing delegates or to use wage-maximizing delegates (such as senior

III. Duopoly In the third stage wage bargaining occurs. Inside each firm the employer and the union delegate negotiate the wage level foreseeing perfectly the effect of wages on output and employment levels. The two negotiations take place simultaneously and independently. That is, when negotiating the wage, the employer and the union delegate take the other firm’s wage as given. The outcomes of the bargaining are modelled by using the formula of an asymmetric Nash bargaining solution which is interpreted as the limit of the subgame perfect equilibrium of the Rubinstein (1982) bargaining model when the lag between offers converges to zero (see Binmore et al., 1986). First, the case is considered in which in both firms the union sends surplus-maximizing delegates whose

2 To keep the model as simple as possible it is assumed that once both firms merge both unions merge too. This can be derived endogenously by allowing both unions to choose whether or not to merge once both firms have already merged. Another interpretation is that a merger implies the concentration of all activities in a single plant.

Strategic union delegation and incentives for merger

3

interest is the same as the union’s objective. Then, the predicted wages are given by 8 W1 ¼ arg max½L1 ðW1 , W2 Þ  ðW1  WÞ > > > > > <  ½ðP  W1 Þ  Q1 ðW1 , W2 Þ1 > > W2 ¼ arg max½L2 ðW1 , W2 Þ  ðW2  WÞ > > > :  ½ðP  W2 Þ  Q2 ðW1 , W2 Þ1

delegates and the union of firm j chooses surplusmaximizing delegates. Then, the predicted wages are given by 8  1 > Wi ¼ arg max½ðWi  W Þ  ðP  Wi Þ  Qi ðWi , Wj Þ > > < Wj ¼ arg max½Lj ðWi , Wj Þ  ðWj  W Þ  > > >  1 :  ðP  Wj Þ  Qj ðWi , Wj Þ

where  2 ð0, 1Þ is the union bargaining power and the disagreement points of both firms and unions are zero. Solving these simultaneously yields the following solution for wages, outputs, profits and unions payoffs:  ss ss W1D ða  W Þ ¼ W2D ¼Wþ 4

Solving these simultaneously yields the following solution for wages and unions payoffs:

2ð2  Þða  W Þ 3bð4  Þ  2 1 2ð2  Þða  W Þ ¼ 9b ð4  Þ

ss Qss 1D ¼ Q2D ¼

ss ss 1D ¼ 2D

ss Uss 1D ¼ U2D ¼

2ð2  Þða  W Þ2 3bð4  Þ2

where the superscript ‘ss’ means that union 1 chooses surplus-maximizing delegates and union 2 chooses surplus-maximizing delegates. Second, the case is consider in which in both firms the union sends wage-maximizing delegates. Then, the predicted wages are given by 8 W1 ¼ arg max½ðW1  W Þ  ½ðP  W1 Þ > > > <  Q1 ðW1 , W2 Þ1  > > W2 ¼ arg max½ðW2  W Þ  ½ðP  W2 Þ > :  Q2 ðW1 , W2 Þ1 Solving these simultaneously yields the following solution for wages, outputs, profits and unions payoffs:  ww ww W1D ða  W Þ ¼ W2D ¼Wþ 4  3 4ð1  Þða  W Þ 3bð4  3Þ  2 1 4ð1  Þða  W Þ ¼ 9b ð4  3Þ

ww ww Q1D ¼ Q2D ¼

ww ww 1D ¼ 2D

ww ww U1D ¼ U2D ¼

4ð1  Þða  W Þ2 3bð4  3Þ2

where the superscript ‘ww’ means that union 1 chooses wage-maximizing delegates and union 2 chooses wage-maximizing delegates. Finally, the asymmetric cases are consider in which the union of firm i chooses wage-maximizing

ws sw W1D ¼ W2D ¼Wþ

ð4 þ Þ ða  W Þ 8ð2  Þ   2

ws sw ¼ W1D ¼Wþ W2D

ð4  Þ ða  W Þ 8ð2  Þ   2

ws sw ¼ U2D ¼ U1D

ð4 þ Þð16  12  4 2 Þða  W Þ2  2 3b 8ð2  Þ   2

ws sw U2D ¼ U1D ¼

ð4  Þð16  12 þ 2 2 Þða  W Þ2  2 3b 8ð2  Þ   2

where the superscript ‘ww’ (‘sw’) means that union 1 (2) chooses wage-maximizing delegates and union 2 (1) chooses surplus-maximizing delegates. Comparing the equilibrium wage expressions confirms expectations. Wage-maximizing delegates obtain higher wage levels than surplus-maximizing delegates do: ww ws sw ww sw W1D > W1D > W1D > Wss and W2D > W2D > 1D ws ss W2D > W2D . In the second stage, the unions simultaneously choose between surplus-maximizing delegates or wage-maximizing delegates to negotiate the wage with the employer. The profile in which both unions choose surplus-maximizing delegates is a Nash equilibrium of the stage game if and only if ss ws ss sw U1D  U1D and U2D  U2D . Hence, there is a  such that the profile in which both unions choose surplus-maximizing delegates is a Nash equilibrium if and only if    ’ 0:79. The profile in which both unions choose wage-maximizing delegates is a Nash equilibrium of the stage game if and only ww sw ww ws if U1D  U1D and U2D  U2D . Hence, there is a  D such that the profile in which both unions choose wage-maximizing delegates is a Nash equilibrium if and only if   D ’ 0:81. Two remarks have to be made. First, an asymmetric profile where one union chooses a surplusmaximizing delegate and the other union chooses a wage-maximizing delegate is never a Nash equilibrium. Second, for  2 ½, D  there are two Nash equilibria but only one seems to be a reasonable outcome. Indeed, it can easily be shown that the outcome where both unions send wage-maximizing

A. Mauleon and V. J. Vannetelbosch

4 delegates is the unique coalition-proof Nash equiliww brium outcome (because of UiD  Uss iD , i ¼ 1, 2). A Nash equilibrium strategy profile is a coalitionproof Nash equilibrium if no coalition of players could form a self-enforcing agreement to deviate from it. To summarize, the union in each firm will choose a wage-maximizing delegate if and only if the union bargaining power is not too strong,   D .

IV. Monopoly In the case where the union sends surplus-maximizing delegates, the predicted wage is given by 

1

W ¼ arg max½LðW Þ  ðW  W Þ  ½ðP  WÞ  QðW Þ which yields:

 ð2  Þða  W Þ s s WM ¼ W þ ða  W Þ QM ¼ 2 4b  2 1 ð2  Þða  W Þ ð2  Þða  W Þ2 s sM ¼ UM ¼ 4b 2 8b where the superscript ‘s’ means that the union sends surplus-maximizing delegates to negotiate with the monopolist. In the case where the union sends wage-maximizing delegates, the predicted wage is given by W ¼ arg max½ðW  W Þ  ½ðP  W Þ  QðWÞ1 which yields:  ð1  Þða  W Þ ða  W Þ QwM ¼ 2 ð2  Þb  2 1 ð1  Þða  W Þ ð1  Þða  W Þ2 ¼ UwM ¼ b ð2  Þ ð2  Þ2 b

w WM ¼Wþ

wM

where the superscript ‘w’ means that the union chooses wage-maximizing delegates. In the second stage, the union chooses whether to use surplus-maximizing delegates or wagemaximizing delegates to negotiate the wage with the monopolist. The union will choose wage-maximizing w s delegates if and only if UM  UM , that is, if 3 and only if 8ð1  Þ  ð2  Þ  0. Hence, there is a  M such that the outcome where the union chooses wage-maximizing delegates is an equilibrium outcome of the stage game if and only if   M ’ 0:76.

V. Incentives for Merger In this section how the option the union has to use strategic delegation will affect the incentives for

merger is investigated. Before answering this question the benchmark where unions do not have the option of strategic delegation is considered. It is said that both firms have incentives or it is profitable for them to merge if and only if M  1D þ 2D . Without the option of strategic delegation, both firms are going to merge if and only if sM  ss ss 1D þ 2D . Hence, a merger will take place if and only if unions are weak,   ðð12  8ð2Þ1=2 Þ=3Þ ’ 0:23. Indeed, when unions are strong enough, then firms have no incentives to merge because by merging the wage spillover effects which before were pushing down the wages would disappear. Proposition 1: If unions cannot use strategic delegation, then firms have incentives to merge if and only if unions have a weak bargaining power,   ð12  8ð2Þ1=2 Þ=3. It would be tempting to conclude that unionization or strong unions will decrease the incentives for merger. Then, by giving the option of strategic delegation to the union, it would be expected that the profitability of mergers would decrease even more. As is show next there is no clear answer. If   M then both under the duopoly and the monopoly situations wage-maximizing delegates are sent. Firms have incentives to merge if and only ww ww if wM  1D þ 2D . Hence, a merger will occur if and only if   ðð12  8ð2Þ1=2 Þ=ð9  4ð2Þ1=2 Þ ’ 0:205Þ. This result seems to suggest that strategic union delegation would reduce incentives for merger. But this is not always true. If  2 ½M , D  then a merger enables both firms to switch from a duopolistic equilibrium in which wage-maximizing delegates are sent to a monopolistic equilibrium in which surplus-maximizing delegates are sent. That is, a merger switches the equilibrium regime with respect to the choice of delegates. Since ww ww sM  1D þ 2D for  2 ½M , D , it is optimal for the firms to merge and negotiate the wage with surplus-maximizing delegates in order to avoid a duopoly where negotiations would take place with wage-maximizing delegates. Proposition 2: If unions can use strategic delegation, then firms are going to merge if and only if the union bargaining power is weak,   ðð12  8ð2Þ1=2 Þ= ð9  4ð2Þ1=2 ÞÞ, or the union bargaining power is strong but not too strong,  2 ½M , D . Finally, one should notice that the option of strategic delegation will harm both the firms and the unions when  2 ½M , D . Indeed, it is observed that the equilibrium outcome with strategic delegation is Pareto-dominated by the one without strategic ss s ss ss delegation: sM < ss 1D þ 2D and UM < U1D þ U2D .

Strategic union delegation and incentives for merger VI. Conclusion To summarize, strategic union delegation will decrease the incentives for merger when the union bargaining power is weak. However, if the union has a strong bargaining power, then strategic delegation might create incentives for the firms to merge. In terms of competition policy, care should be exercised when drawing conclusions with respect to unions and incentives for merger. Indeed, an increase in the union bargaining power will tend to diminish the incentives for merger. But, once strategic delegation is allowed for (for instance, by means of laws protecting union delegates from being dismissed), firms might be pushed to merge even if unions are strong, because a merger enables them to switch from bilateral negotiations with wage-maximizing delegates to a single negotiation with surplusmaximizing delegates. Moreover, they might end up in a situation where both the firms and the unions are worse off compared to the case without the possibility of delegation.

Acknowledgements Financial support from Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia y Tecnologı´ a under the project BEC 2003-02084, support from the CNRS under the project GW/SCSHS/SH/2003-41 and support from the Belgian French Community’s program Action de

5 Recherches Concerte´e 03/08-302 (UCL) are gratefully acknowledged. This paper presents research results of the Belgian Program on Interuniversity Poles of Attraction initiated by the Belgian State, Prime Minister’s Office, Science Policy Programming.

References Binmore, K. G., Rubinstein, A. and Wolinsky, A. (1986) The Nash bargaining solution in economic modelling, Rand Journal of Economics, 17, 176–88. Conlin, M. and Furusawa, T. (2000) Strategic delegation and delay in negotiations over the bargaining agenda, Journal of Labor Economics, 18(1), 55–73. Fershtman, C. and Judd, K. L. (1987) Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly, American Economic Review, 77(5), 927–40. Gonza´lez-Maestre, M. and Lo´pez-Cun~ at, J. (2001) Delegation and mergers in oligopoly, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19, 1263–79. Horn, H. and Wolinsky, A. (1988) Bilateral monopolies and incentives for merger, Rand Journal of Economics, 19, 409–19. Jones, S. R. G. (1989) The role of negotiators in union-firm bargaining, Canadian Journal of Economics, 22(3), 630–42. Mauleon, A. and Vannetelbosch, V. (2005) Strategic union delegation and strike activity, Canadian Journal of Economics, 38(1), 149–73. Rubinstein, A. (1982) Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model, Econometrica, 50, 97–109. Sklivas, S. (1987) The strategic choice of managerial incentives, Rand Journal of Economics, 18, 452–8.

Strategic union delegation and incentives for merger

A unionized duopoly model to analyse how unions affect the incentives for merger is considered. It is found that both firms will merge if and only if unions are weak. However, once surplus-maximizing unions have the option to delegate the wage bargaining to wage-maximizing delegates. (such as senior union members), ...

95KB Sizes 0 Downloads 113 Views

Recommend Documents

Strategic union delegation and strike activity
Ana Mauleon and Vincent Vannetelbosch are Chercheurs Qualifieґs at the Fonds National de la. Recherche Scientifigue ..... A natural question to ask at this point is whether union delegation reduces consumer surplus or social welfare. We denote by CS

Strategic union delegation and strike activity - Wiley Online Library
the incentives for strike activity. Up to now the literature has been mainly focused on strategic delegation on behalf of shareholders. Fershtman and Judd.

Driving the Gap: Tax Incentives and Incentives for ...
The size of the bandwidth invokes the classic tradeoff between efficiency and bias. In our context ... First, technical issues make it more difficult to achieve the.

Strategic delegation in a sequential model with multiple stages
Jul 16, 2011 - c(1 + n2n − 2−n). 2n−1h(n). (2). 7To see this, recall that quantities and market price, before the choices of (a1,a2, ..., an) are made, are given by ...

Strategic delegation in a sequential model with multiple stages
Jul 16, 2011 - We also compare the delegation outcome ... email: [email protected] ... in comparing the equilibrium of the sequential market with the ...

screening and merger activity
subsection thereafter, we relate the merging profits to the state of the ..... quasi-linear utility function. 9 .... tiple bidders prior to the public announcement of takeover bids. ..... Unilateral Effects,' Report for DG Competition, European Commi

Instability and the Incentives for Corruption
of two effects: A horizon effect, whereby greater instability leads the incumbent to ..... further illustration for the horizon and demand effects that we propose. ..... first time in modern Mexican history, the PRI was left with less than 50% of the

Instability and the Incentives for Corruption - Semantic Scholar
both crucial components of political stability, should be key in determining his willingness and ability to extract these .... stability also belongs on this list as a key proximate determinant of the incentives for corruption. While political ......

Screening and Merger Activity
8Some of the stylized facts come from the so-called “event-studies”, which measure the stock price changes after a merger (announcement). They are based on ...

Suppliers' Merger and Consumers' Welfare
by reducing tki so that the contract becomes acceptable for Rk. If "qk#,tk## and "qk$,tk$# are ... The comparison is all the more relevant as retailers keep all of.

Screening and Merger Activity
Key Words: Takeovers, Merger Waves, Defense Tactics, Screening ... on quarterly grouped U.S. data from the SDC Mergers and Acquisitions database of ...

US - Tax Incentives for Aircraft (PR) - WorldTradeLaw.net
Feb 13, 2015 - UNITED STATES – CONDITIONAL TAX INCENTIVES FOR LARGE CIVIL ... to the development, manufacture, and sale of large civil aircraft. ... In November 2013, the State of Washington, as part of its efforts to induce The Boeing Company ...

Incentives for Eliciting Confidence Intervals
Dec 3, 2012 - rule punishes the expert for specifying a larger interval width, and for the distance of ..... In sum, learning about the dispersion of beliefs is confounded. ... width gives information about their relative degrees of risk aversion.

Merger FailuresA
*Social Science Research Center Berlin (WZB), Reichpietschufer 50, 10785 Berlin, Germany. .... and multiple equilibria arise as in the complete information case. ..... of pairs that consider a merger, which we will call total probability of failure.

Merger FailuresA
individual efforts.4 As a consequence, post-merger efforts exhibit strategic complementarities. 3 Indeed, as ... interdependencies make it even more difficult to measure separate contributions (Simon [40]). Post-merger efforts towards ...... not want

US - Tax Incentives for Aircraft (PR) - WorldTradeLaw.net
Feb 13, 2015 - Business & Occupation tax rate with respect to the manufacture or sale of ... (sales tax exemption for computer hardware, software, and ...

Screening and Merger Activity
Seldeslachts gratefully acknowledges financial support from the EC 5th Framework Programme Research ..... the two companies (see also Houston et al., 2001).

Incentives for Quality in Friendly and Hostile Informational Environments
Feb 24, 2012 - In contrast, friendly environments create free riding among sellers, which ... tion is another illustration: prestigious journals (mostly) include good ...... Learning and Statistical Discrimination, American Economic Review (Papers.

Instability and the Incentives for Corruption - Semantic Scholar
the σ pro xy equals. 0. , when ev aluated at the median v alue of ln. “P arty. T en ure” in the regression sample. The turning p oin t for columns with these in teraction terms is ev a lua ted at the median v alue of the σ pro xy in the regress

Instability and the Incentives for Corruption - Singapore Management ...
for today” [p.464]. Conversely, autocratic regimes such as Mexico under the Institutional Revolutionary .... public goods spending that is valued by the masses, such as on education, healthcare or infrastructure; expenditures ..... Starting in 1929

Merger FailuresA
Our unique equilibrium allows us to make predictions on which mergers are more .... 8 One way to interpret the words of the CEO of Daimler in the Financial ..... indirect extra gains from both partners ..... Cutoff HHx rises therefore faster than ...

Mixed Incentives for Legislative Behaviors
Feb 19, 2009 - If extra-legislative ruling elites can define legislators' ..... First, the president has the enormous lawmaking powers defined by the constitution.

Incentives for Quality in Friendly and Hostile Informational Environments
Feb 24, 2012 - Email: [email protected] .... ity with a probability g if quality is high (”good news”) and probability b if quality is low ..... revision obtains from the fact that the fraction of self-regulating firms is F(c∗),

Guidelines on the Availment of Awards and Incentives for Overseas ...
2.0 Definition of Terms. 2.1. Cash incentive – the amount to be awarded by the city or municipality .... 5.2.7 Foreign driver's license. 5.2.8 Medical or health card.