Supplement to “A Critical Value Function Approach, with an Application to Persistent Time-Series” Marcelo J. Moreira, Rafael Mour˜ ao, and Humberto Moreira Escola de P´ os-Gradua¸ca ˜o em Economia e Finan¸cas (FGV/EPGE) Getulio Vargas Foundation - 11th floor Praia de Botafogo 190 Rio de Janeiro - RJ 22250-040 e-mail: [email protected]

1. Introduction This supplement consists of two parts. The first section includes additional graphs on the critical value function, size and power comparison. The second section provides additional proofs for the remaining theoretical results. 2. Numerical Results We provide additional numerical results. First, we allow for a time trend and compare the performance of commonly-used sampling methods to our CVF approach. We then consider flattening schemes to guarantee that the critical value function (CVF) converges to the usual standard normal quantiles. Finally, we make further power comparisons between our similar t-test and other similar tests for different values of the autoregressive parameter γ and degrees of endogeneity ρ. 2.1. Time Trend For now, we extend the model to allow for a time trend. The model is given by yt

= µ0y dt + βxt−1 + yt

xt

= γxt−1 + xt , 0

where µy is a two-dimensional vector and dt = (1, t) . We consider the group of translation transformations on the data g ◦ (y, x) = (y + Dg, x) , where g is a two-dimensional vector and D is a T × 2 matrix whose t-th line is given by d0t . This yields a transformation on the parameter space   g ◦ β, γ, µy = β, γ, µy + g . Any invariant test can be written as a function of the maximal invariant statistic. Let q = (q1 , q2 ) be an orthogonal T × T matrix where the first column is given by −1/2 q1 = D (D0 D) . Algebraic manipulations show that q2 q20 = MD , where MD = IT − −1 0 0 D (D D) D is the projection matrix to the space orthogonal to 1T . Let x−1 be the 1 imsart-generic ver. 2014/10/16 file: arXivSuppNearlyInteg6d.tex date: June 6, 2016

T -dimensional vector whose t-th entry is xt−1 , and define wµ = q20 w for a T -dimensional vector w. The maximal invariant statistic is given by r = (y µ , x). Its density function is given by ( ) T 1 X 2 − T2 µ exp − (xt − xt−1 γ) (2.1) fβ,γ (y , x) = (2πσ xx ) 2σ xx t=1 (  2 ) T  X 1 σ σ xy xy − T −2 × (2πσ yy.x ) 2 exp − y µ − xµt − xµt−1 β − γ , 2σ yy.x t=1 t σ xx σ xx where σ yy.x = σ yy − σ 2xy /σ xx is the variance of yt not explained by xt . Because of invariance, the density depends on β and γ, but not on µy . Furthermore, the formulae for the sufficient statistics and the log-likelihood ratio process are exactly the same as in the model with only an intercept, but replacing q2 in y µ and xµ . The asymptotic distribution of the new RT (γ) and KT (γ) statistics is, however, different when we allow for time trend. In particular, the model curvature increases in the sense of Efron [1, 2] when γ = 1. This yields larger departures from the nominal size by conventional sampling schemes. Fig S1: Size (intercept and time trend)

1

1 First Iteration Last Iteration Parametric Bootstrap Nonparametric Bootstrap Subsampling

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0

First Iteration Last Iteration Parametric Bootstrap Nonparametric Bootstrap Subsampling

0.9

0

0.5

1

1.5

γ

0

0

0.5

1

1.5

γ

(b) ρ = −0.95

(a) ρ = 0.95

Figure S1 plots null rejection probabilities when we allow for a time trend. Comparing this graph with Figure 1, it is evident that both bootstrap methods and subsampling have null rejection probabilities farther away from the 10% nominal size when we allow for a time trend. The CVF, however, is able to correct size distortions whether there is a time trend or not. As such, the CVF needs to provide more curvature when we allow for time trend. This can be seen by comparing Figure S2, which plots the CVF when the model has a time trend, to Figure 2. The range of values that the CVF can take is larger when we make inference in the presence of a time trend. For example, take the CVF plot when ρ = 0.95. The CVF can have values as low as -2.5 and as high as 1.5 in the presence of a time trend. On the other hand, the CVF ranges from -1 to 1.5 when we make inference knowing there is no time trend. 2

Fig S2: Critical Value Function (intercept and time trend)

(a) ρ = 0.95

(b) ρ = −0.95

2.2. Flattening Schemes We study the behavior of the critical value function (CVF) when the series is stationary and explosive. We focus on the main model in which there is only intercept and no time trend. We are able to analyze the behavior of Rγ /Kγγ and Kγγ when the series is stationary and explosive (to save space, we again use the notation Rγ and Kγγ for Rγ,T (1) and Kγγ,T (1), respectively). Figure S3 plots the critical values as a function of Rγ /Kγγ and Kγγ . It is convenient to re-scale the x-axis and y-axis in the figures to analyze the critical value under different asymptotic regimes. We choose the scale G (z) ≡ 2. (F (z) − 0.5) , −1

where F (z) = [1 + exp (−z)] is the logistic distribution. This scale is an increasing, symmetric transformation, which preserves zero and maps ∞ into 1; that is, G0 (z) > 0, G (−z) = −G (z), G (0) = 0, and limz→∞ G (z) = 1. When the series is stationary, Rγ /Kγγ converges to −∞ (under local alternatives) and Kγγ to 0. This convergence is represented by the point (−1, 0) in the domain for G (Rγ /Kγγ ) and G (Kγγ ). When the series is explosive, Rγ /Kγγ diverges to ∞ (under local alternatives) and Kγγ to ∞. This limit is indicated by the point (1, 1) in the new domain. In both situations, the critical value function takes values near 1.28, the 90% quantile of a standard normal distribution. Of course, those values are not exactly equal to 1.28. This suggests we can try to flatten the critical value function using the values of Rγ /Kγγ or Kγγ themselves. For example, we could consider setting the critical value function at 1.28 for (i) large values of |Rγ /Kγγ |, or (ii) small values and large values of Kγγ . The figures below consider flattening schemes when (i) |Rγ /Kγγ | > 102 and (ii) Kγγ < 10−2 or Kγγ > 106 . For these regions, the critical value function is forced to take the value 1.28. Figure S4 plots the null rejection probabilities from both flattening methods for ρ = 0.95 and −0.95. The tests’ sizes are sometimes sensitive to the choice of the thresholds for both flattening methods. When flattening slightly improves size, it does not yield a substantial effect on the power of the respective tests. Hence, we report power using the standard critical value function, without any auxiliary flattening method. 3

Fig S3: Critical Value Function

(a) ρ = 0.95

(b) ρ = −0.95

2.3. Additional Power Comparison Figures S5-S8 present power for different levels of γ and ρ. The results further support the similar t-test in terms of size and power. The behavior of the L2 test is sensitive to the values of c, sometimes behaving as a one-sided and other times as a two-sided test. At the value b = 0, the UMPCU test presents null rejection probabilities above the nominal level when c = 5, and close to zero when c = 30. This problem is possibly due to the inaccuracy of the algorithm used by Jansson and Moreira [3] for integral approximations. Although this problem can be conceivably fixed by using better numerical approximations for c > 0, the power of the UMPCU test is considerably below that found by the similar t-test for c ≤ 0. Overall, the similar t-test has correct size and better power than the competing tests. References [1] Efron, B. (1975). Defining the curvature of a statistical problem (with applications to second order efficiency). Annals of Statistics 3, 1189–1242. [2] Efron, B. (1978). The geometry of exponential families. Annals of Statistics 6, 362– 376. [3] Jansson, M. and M. J. Moreira (2006). Optimal inference in regression models with nearly integrated regressors. Econometrica 74, 681–715.

4

Fig S4: Size

0.2

0.2 Standard Flattened Rg/Kgg Flattened Kgg

0.16

0.16

0.14

0.14

0.12

0.1

0.08

0.12

0.1

0.08

0.06

0.06

0.04

0.04

0.02

0.02

0

0

Standard Flattened Rg/Kgg Flattened Kgg

0.18

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

0.18

0.5

1

1.5

γ

0

0

0.5

1

γ

(b) ρ = −0.95

(a) ρ = 0.95

5

1.5

Fig S5: Power (ρ = 0.5)

1

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

0.9

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0 -15

-10

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

-10

-5

b

(a) γ = 0

0.9

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.8

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.2

0.1

0.1

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

-10

-5

b

0

10

15

5

10

15

b

(c) γ = 0.85

(d) γ = 1.0

1

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

5

0.4

0.3

-10

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.5

0.2

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

b

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.3

0 -15

15

0.6

0.3

0.9

10

1

0.8

0 -15

5

(b) γ = 0.5

1

0.9

0

b

0 -15

-10

-5

0

b

(e) γ = 1.05

(f) γ = 1.3

6

Fig S6: Power (ρ = −0.5)

1

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

0.9

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0 -15

-10

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

-10

-5

b

(a) γ = 0

0.9

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.8

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.2

0.1

0.1

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

-10

-5

b

0

10

15

5

10

15

b

(c) γ = 0.85

(d) γ = 1.0

1

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

5

0.4

0.3

-10

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.5

0.2

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

b

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.3

0 -15

15

0.6

0.3

0.9

10

1

0.8

0 -15

5

(b) γ = 0.5

1

0.9

0

b

0 -15

-10

-5

0

b

(e) γ = 1.05

(f) γ = 1.3

7

Fig S7: Power (ρ = 0.95)

1

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

0.9

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0 -15

-10

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

-10

-5

b

(a) γ = 0

0.9

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.8

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.2

0.1

0.1

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

-10

-5

b

0

10

15

5

10

15

b

(c) γ = 0.85

(d) γ = 1.0

1

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

5

0.4

0.3

-10

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.5

0.2

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

b

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.3

0 -15

15

0.6

0.3

0.9

10

1

0.8

0 -15

5

(b) γ = 0.5

1

0.9

0

b

0 -15

-10

-5

0

b

(e) γ = 1.05

(f) γ = 1.3

8

Fig S8: Power (ρ = −0.95)

1

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

0.9

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0 -15

-10

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

-10

-5

b

(a) γ = 0

0.9

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.8

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.2

0.1

0.1

-5

0

5

10

0 -15

15

-10

-5

b

0

10

15

5

10

15

b

(c) γ = 0.85

(d) γ = 1.0

1

1 Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

Rejection Probability

Rejection Probability

5

0.4

0.3

-10

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.5

0.2

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

b

Similar t-test L2 UMPCU

0.6

0.3

0 -15

15

0.6

0.3

0.9

10

1

0.8

0 -15

5

(b) γ = 0.5

1

0.9

0

b

0 -15

-10

-5

0

b

(e) γ = 1.05

(f) γ = 1.3

9

Supplement to “A Critical Value Function Approach, with an ...

Jun 6, 2016 - transformations on the data g ◦ (y, x)=(y + Dg, x) , where g ... Fig S2: Critical Value Function (intercept and time trend). (a) ρ = 0.95. (b) ρ = −0.95.

2MB Sizes 0 Downloads 74 Views

Recommend Documents

Supplement to “A Critical Value Function Approach, with an ...
Jun 6, 2016 - this graph with Figure 1, it is evident that both bootstrap methods and subsampling have null rejection probabilities farther away from the 10% ...

A Critical Value Function Approach, with an Application ...
Jun 6, 2016 - Application to Persistent Time-Series. Marcelo J. ...... model. If the model has one lag, Hansen [9] suggests a “grid” bootstrap which delivers. 15 ...

2.4. Average Value of a Function (Mean Value Theorem) 2.4.1 ...
f(x)dx . 2.4.2. The Mean Value Theorem for Integrals. If f is con- tinuous on [a, b], then there exists a number c in [a, b] such that f(c) = fave = 1 b − a. ∫ b a f(x)dx ,.

An Expected Utility Approach to Active Feature-value ...
be represented by the matrix F, where Fi,j corresponds to the value of the j-th ..... Learning Tools and Techniques with Java Implementations. Morgan Kaufmann ...

Linked List Exclusion: An Approach to Critical Section ...
Florida International University. 09/16/09. Abstract. The current methods utilized in implementing mutual exclusion on critical sections require excessive.

On Default Correlation: A Copula Function Approach
of default over the time interval [0,n], plus the probability of survival to the end of nth year and ..... Figure 6: The Value of First-to-Default v. s. Asset Correlation. 0.1.

Supplement to: “The Value of Children: Inter ...
b/se n.obs. Good health. 0.0095. 8329. (0.034). Health problems -0.039. 8327. (0.037). Difficulty in ADL 0.026. 8335. (0.020). Physical disability 0.0062. 8326.

The Subjective Approach to Ambiguity: A Critical ... - Semantic Scholar
Oct 8, 2008 - Bayesian model along these lines. We will argue .... with a difference: one would expect the forces of learning, introspection and incentives to ...

The Subjective Approach to Ambiguity: A Critical ... - Semantic Scholar
Oct 8, 2008 - ¬I, investing here amounts to paying S dollars in exchange for improving ...... acterized by a stock of models, or analogies, who respond to strategic .... Why is this superior to other behavioral or ad hoc explanations that fit the.

the macroeconomic loss function: a critical note
from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com. • from the CESifo website: www. ..... 743 Robert Fenge, Silke Uebelmesser, and Martin Werding, Second-best ... Staying Together or Breaking Apart: Policy-makers' Endogenous Coalitions Formation.

the macroeconomic loss function: a critical note
ENDNOTES. 1. However, other loss functions are also used. See for instance the ones employed in Rudenbusch (2002). 2.. This assumes that policymakers are correct in their beliefs. REFERENCES. Cecchetti, Stephen (2000) "Making Monetary Policy: Objecti

Supplement to - GitHub
Supplemental Table S6. .... 6 inclusion or exclusion of certain genetic variants in a pharmacogenetic test ..... http://aidsinfo.nih.gov/contentfiles/AdultandAdolescentGL.pdf. .... 2.0 are expected to exhibit higher CYP2D6 enzyme activity versus ...

A Probabilistic Radial Basis Function Approach for ...
Interest in uncertainty quantification is rapidly increasing, since inherent physical variations cannot be neglected in ... parameters becomes large, a high dimensional response surface has to be computed. ..... The air properties are at 0m ISA.

A Gauss Function Based Approach for Unbalanced ...
to achieve interoperability, especially in web scale, becomes .... a concept ci in O1, we call the procedure to find the se- ...... Web Conference(WWW), 2007.

On Default Correlation: A Copula Function Approach
Existing literature tends to define default correlation based on discrete ... Then, we need to specify a joint distribution for the survival times such that the ...... [3] Cox, D. R. and Oakes, D. Analysis of Survival Data, Chapman and Hall, (1984).

Supplement to “Trading Dynamics with Private Buyer ...
such that q(x) < q but p(x) ≥ vL (so that trade occurs only at cH), which again ...... By the analysis in section C1, when the signal structure is given by Γd, there ...

Supplement to “Trading Dynamics with Private Buyer ...
Let n∗ be the unique integer such that λ(1 − ΓL(sn∗ )) < ρL < λ(1 − ΓL(sn∗−1)). (8). These inequalities mean that the low-type seller's reservation price p(t) falls short of vL when all subsequent buyers offer cH if and only if s > s

Supplement to "Agency Models With Frequent Actions"
PROOF: See Sannikov (2008). Q.E.D. ..... ters Sε in finite time with nonnegligible probabilities. ... In view of the above bound, it is sufficient to establish that there.