Terror as a Bargaining Instrument: A Case-Study of Dowry Violence in Rural India

American Economic Review (forthcoming), 2001

Francis Bloch IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain

Vijayendra Rao Development Research Group, The World Bank

Revised: October 2000

We are indebted to Rama Ranee for her help with the fieldwork, and to the Editor and three anonymous referees for helpful and detailed comments on the paper. Valuable suggestions were provided by Roger Bolton, Ralph Bradburd, Jill Constantine, Donald Cox, Andrew Foster, Emmanuel Jimenez, Russel Murphy, Sita Reddy, and seminar participants at British Columbia, Michigan, Williams and the World Bank. Rao is grateful to the Mellon Foundation, the Population Centers at Michigan and Brown, and Williams College for financial support. Bloch thanks the Foundation HEC for sponsoring his participation in the project. Please refer correspondence to V. Rao, Development Research Group, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433. e-mail: Erreur! Signet non défini.. The findings, interpretations and conclusions of this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank.

ABSTRACT This paper examines how domestic violence may be used as an instrument to extract larger transfers from a spouse's family. It is based on a case-study of three villages in Southern India, conducted by the authors, that combines qualitative and survey data. Based on the ethnographic evidence, we develop a non-cooperative bargaining and signaling model of dowries and domestic violence. The predictions from these models are tested with survey data. We find that women who pay smaller dowries suffer an increased risk of marital violence, as do women who come from richer families.

JEL Classifications: J12, J16, O12

2

1. Introduction

The threat of violence is often used as a means of redistributing resources. The Mafia extorts protection money from people under its control, and terrorists threaten hostages with death in order to extract concessions from governments. There is obviously a great deal of economic content in violent behavior and yet it has been neglected as a subject of research by most economists1. One prominent example of economically motivated violence comes from the Indian sub-continent where numerous press reports indicate the widespread use of wife-abuse as a means of extracting transfers from the wife’s parents2. In its most publicized form, disputes over the dowry give rise to what newspapers describe as «dowry murders» where wives are burned alive by their husband’s families3. Thus, «dowry» violence does not refer directly to marriage related payments made at the time of the wedding, but to additional payments demanded after the marriage by the groom’s family where the husband systematically abuses the wife in order to extract larger transfers. In this paper we conduct a case-study of domestic violence in rural India focusing on its use as a bargaining instrument. There is a small literature on the economics of domestic violence4; Tauchen, Witte and Long (1991) and Farmer and Tiefenthaler (1997) develop and test non-cooperative bargaining models of violence, and Farmer and Tiefenthaler (1996) theoretically examine how the use of shelters can serve as a signal of a woman's tolerance of violence. More recently, Lundberg and Pollak (1998) have constructed a model of the intergenerational transmission of domestic violence. The literature on intra-household bargaining is both more extensive and more empirical (Alderman, Chiappori and Kanbur, 1995). Most of these studies follow the work of Manser and Brown (1980) and McElroy and Horney (1981) who develop cooperative models of bargaining within marriage with divorce as the threat point. Lundberg and Pollak (1993) extend this by allowing for an internal non-cooperative threat point where the husband and wife live in "separate spheres." Our paper differs from these literatures in various ways: It employs ethnographic information on the behaviors underlying dowry related violence culled from open ended interviews conducted in three villages in rural South India to inform the development of a non-cooperative model of bargaining and signaling. Predictions from the model are then econometrically tested with survey data collected from the

1

Chwe (1990) is an exception. See Karlekar (1998) for a survey of the literature on domestic violence in India. This problem is not unique to India, Jahan(1991), presents an account of the same phenomenon in Bangladesh. 3 One study estimates that 25 per cent of deaths of women between the ages of 15 and 30 in the city of Bombay can be attributed to death by burning - the single highest cause of mortality in that age group (Karkal, 1985). 4 See Heise et. al. (1999) for a survey of the domestic violence literature in the other social sciences and public health. 2

3

same population that is the focus of the ethnographic interviews. Thus, our paper is unusual in two respects. Firstly, it introduces asymmetric information into a model of household bargaining where domestic violence is used as a signal of the husband's satisfaction with the marriage. Secondly, it combines economic and anthropological methods to rigorously examine violence within the context of Indian marriage markets employing data collected by the authors. We find that marital violence is not only closely linked to low dowry payments, but that a woman who comes from a wealthy family is more likely to be beaten by her husband in an effort to extract higher transfers from her parents. The paper is structured as follows: Following this introduction Section 2 summarizes the cultural context and the ethnographic information, Section 3 outlines the theoretical model, Section 4 describes the data and lays out the econometric methodology, and Section 5 analyzes the empirical results and concludes the paper.

2. Cultural Context

To understand why the phenomenon of dowry violence is so widespread, it might help to outline the basic nature of rural Indian marriage markets5: Marriage is restricted to endogamous groups, i.e.: people are only permitted to marry within a well-defined set of families who make up their sub-caste. The sub-caste we study in this paper is a potter community in the South Indian State of Karnataka. The craft of pottery was their primary source of employment for many generations, but today the majority are casual laborers. Yet, any individual from the community would face large social sanctions if s/he married someone who belonged to a non-potter caste. A second feature of the marriage market is that it is patrilocal - brides leave their parents’ home to live with their husbands. A third is that marriages are arranged for both grooms and brides by their parents. Finally it is important to note that marriage is considered final and, while there are cases of separation, divorce is not an option6. Getting one’s daughter married is considered an Indian parent’s primary duty and to have an older unmarried daughter is a tremendous misfortune with large social and economic costs. However, the costs of getting a daughter married have been steadily rising in real terms across the Indian sub-continent. In the community that we focus on here dowries have been increasing substantially for at least two decades. Dowries7 among the potters average six times the annual income of a bride’s parents, an amount that is 5

While there other important factors that affect domestic violence (Karlekar 1998, Rao 1998), this paper focuses on its connection with the marriage market. 6 According the 1991 Indian Census, in this region of India the divorce rate is estimated at 0.3 per cent. 7 The term «dowry» has been used in a number of different ways in the literature. We will employ it to mean a groom-price, a payment in cash and/or kind directly made from a bride’s family to a groom’s. We will call the reverse transaction a brideprice.

4

consistent with findings from other samples8. One possible reason for the rise in dowries is that grooms are scarce. Population growth may have resulted in a surplus of women from large younger cohorts attempting to match with men from smaller older cohorts (Rao 1993, Bhat and Halli 1999)9. Once the wedding is celebrated and the newly married bride has moved to her husband’s home, she is not only a bride but also a potential hostage. Since divorce is impossible, under no circumstances can she move back permanently to her parent’s home. Thus, violence can be used as a mechanism to extract further transfers from the bride’s family. In fact, all the wife-abusers whom we had in-depth interviews with justified their behavior with «instrumental» explanations, as a means to extract transfers or control resources. The interviews that we conducted revealed that there was a close link between abuse by the groom's family and the demand for transfers from the bride’s family. We will illustrate this link with a brief outline of the case of Sannamma and Raju, a young couple who have been married for about two years. Their parents arranged the marriage when Sannamma was 17 and Raju was 24. Sanamma’s parents are relatively rich with 10 acres of irrigated land, while Raju’s are considerably poorer. Raju shares a house with his parents, his brothers, and their wives and children who all live off a five acre plot of dry land supplemented by intermittent work as wage laborers. Raju received a dowry of 25,000 rupees, which is about half the size of most other dowries paid in the community at the time. A few months into the marriage, he demanded that Sanamma ask her father to send some money so that he could set up a small tea shop. She agreed and her father sent Raju 2000 rupees which is what Raju made in 4 months. About two months later Raju demanded a motorcycle - a considerably larger request well beyond the means of Sanamma’s parents. Sannamma passed on the request to her parents who said that they could not afford such a large sum of money. When Raju heard this, he became very angry, hit Sannamma, threw her to the ground and said that if her parents did not send the money, «he could not say what might happen to her.» Subsequently, tensions between Sannamma and Raju have increased considerably and she says that she now lives in fear of her life. Her parents send money when they can even though they cannot really afford to keep up with Raju’s demands. However, Sannamma refuses to leave her husband and go back to her parents fearing social isolation. It should be noted that we did not record any instances of murder - dowry related or otherwise - in these villages10. However, if one thinks of murder as the most extreme mechanism of marital separation 8

This ratio excludes those bride-households that received brideprices, since this community, like many others in the sub-continent, has undergone a transition from paying brideprice to dowry. When brideprice families are included the average dowry is about double the size of annual incomes. These ratios are very similar to those in the frequently analyzed ICRISAT survey which was conducted in two neighboring states (Rao, 1993). 9 One woman we spoke to listed the eligible males available for her fifteen-year-old daughter and demonstrated that the competition for them was quite severe with thirteen females competing for six males.

5

in a society that forbids divorce, we observed less severe but far more common methods by which husbands ended their relationships with their wives and their wives' parents. Wives in bad marriages are often forced by their husbands to break all contact with their parents while being denied access to their husband's income and resources, forcing them to fend for themselves. Thus, while they may continue to live in the same physical space as their husbands because of the taboo against formal divorce, they are effectively abandoned and isolated from family and friends. In the Indian social context where a woman's sense of self is almost entirely derived from her relationship to her family and her social milieu 11

- social and economic isolation have extremely large costs. Moreover, in some instances a husband who

abandons his wife may remarry, though this is not an option for the abandoned wife12.

3. Theoretical Model

While no model can capture all the complex factors that affect marital violence, our task is to construct a theoretical model informed by the qualitative evidence that generates testable hypotheses. From our fieldwork, it is apparent that violence is not merely due to the husbands’ inherent pleasure in beating their wives. Rather, we argue that domestic violence is an instrument used by the husband in the wider context of bargaining between the husband’s and wife’s families over the distribution of their resources. Theoretical models of bargaining under complete information typically predict that the outcome of the bargaining process is efficient, ruling out the exercise of domestic violence in equilibrium. Hence, in order to explain the occurrence of violence, we consider a model with asymmetric information, where violence is interpreted as a signal sent by the husband to the wife’s family about his contentment with the marriage. More specifically, we construct a model with two separate phases of bargaining: before the marriage is concluded, the two families negotiate the level of the dowry; after the marriage is concluded, the husband demands additional transfers paid by the wife’s family. We suppose that once the wedding has taken place, the husband learns his private level of satisfaction with the marriage. Satisfied husbands prefer to maintain links with the wife’s family, whereas dissatisfied husbands would rather sever links, if they don’t receive any additional transfers. We assume that the costs of exercising violence are negatively correlated with the degree of dissatisfaction in the marriage. Hence, dissatisfied husbands have an incentive to exercise violence in order to reveal their type, and obtain additional transfers from the wife by threatening her with separation. 10 11

There was one suspicious death of a young wife that was ruled a suicide by the police. Fruzzetti (1982) and Kapadia (1995) provide illuminating discussions of this.

6

We show that the signaling game admits a unique equilibrium satisfying Cho and Kreps’ (1987) intuitive criterion. In this equilibrium, satisfied husbands never beat their wives, dissatisfied husbands with high costs of violence do not beat their wives but choose to sever links. Dissatisfied husbands with low costs of violence exercise domestic violence, obtain additional transfers from the wife’s family, and keep the marriage intact. At the initial stage of dowry bargaining, both families take into account the postmarital negotiations, and the dowry is adjusted accordingly. We now turn to a formal description of the model.

3.1 Preferences and Timing. We analyze the formation of a link and the distribution of resources between two families denoted h for the husband and w for the wife. By forming and maintaining a link, the two families have access to a flow of utilities whose discounted value at the time of the wedding is given by Uh and Uw . We define Uh = uh (Ih, xh, xw,θ) and Uw = uw(Iw, xh, xw), where Ii, i=h,w represents the income of family i, xi, i=h,w denotes a vector of human capital characteristics of family i (ordered so that higher values of xi correspond to more desirable characteristics), and θ is the husband’s private level of satisfaction with the marriage. We assume that ui, i=h,w are strictly increasing in all their arguments, strictly concave in income, bounded from above and that limIi→0 ui =- Insert Figure 1.

The different stages of the negotiation are illustrated in Figure 1. Prior to the wedding, the two families bargain over the dowry D transferred from the wife’s to the husband’s family. At this stage, we assume that the wife has all the bargaining power and makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer to the husband. By rejecting the offer, the husband obtains a reservation utility R(Yh, xh, m1), where Yh denotes the initial wealth of the husband’s family and m1 the marriage market conditions prevailing before the wedding. The function R(Yh, xh, m1) is increasing in all its arguments, and represents the husband’s alternative prospects on the marriage market. At the time of the wedding (or shortly after) the quality of the match is revealed. This includes a public component, z, observable by both families, and a private component, θ, which is only observed by the husband. For simplicity, we assume that the husband’s level of satisfaction with the marriage, θ, is a dichotomous variable, with value 1 for satisfied husbands, and 0 for dissatisfied husbands. The prior

12

We recorded one instance where a man had abandoned his wife, moved to another village and remarried.

7

probability that the husband is dissatisfied, Pr(θ=0), is a function of the observable characteristics of the marriage, p(z) with p’(z)<0. In the next stage of the model, the husband chooses whether to exercise domestic violence. If violence is committed, both families suffer a utility loss measured by Ch(θ) and Cw. The two families then enter the renegotiation stage. Since the wife is now a «hostage» in the husband’s family, we assume that the husband has all the bargaining power at the renegotiation stage, and makes a take-it-or-leave-it demand of additional transfers t to the wife’s family. The wife’s family responds by accepting or rejecting the offer. In the final stage of the game, the husband chooses whether to sever the links with the wife’s family. If the links are severed, the two families no longer enjoy the joint production possibilities of the marriage, and obtain discounted utility flows denoted Vh and Vw. We define Vh=vh(Ih,xh,m2) and Vw =vw(Iw, xw) where m2 denotes the marriage market conditions prevailing after the wedding,13 and vh and vw are strictly increasing in all their arguments, strictly concave in income, bounded from above and satisfy limIi →0

vi =- In order to analyze the game and guarantee that violence can be used as a credible signal of the

husband’s level of satisfaction with the marriage, we make the following assumptions.

Assumption 1. The dowry D is paid by the wife’s family at the time of the wedding. The transfer t is paid after the husband’s separation decision, and is only paid if the links between the two families are maintained.

Assumption 1 is a simplifying assumption that we need because the dynamics of the marriage and of the transfer of resources are collapsed into a single period where all decisions are taken simultaneously. In reality, both the dowry and the transfers are ongoing payments, which last during the entire duration of the marriage. Our differential treatment of the dowry and post marital transfers (assuming that the dowry is paid irrespective of the maintenance of links but not the transfers) is somewhat arbitrary. It reflects the cultural context of Indian villages, where default on the payment of the dowry – which is publicly observable – bears higher social costs than default on the payment of transfers, which are only observed by the two families. Under Assumption 1, denoting Yw the initial wealth of the wife’s family, the income of the two families can be decomposed as: Ih = Yh + D + t and Iw= Yw - D – t if the links are maintained, and Ih = Yh + D and Iw= Yw - D if the links are severed. 13

In accordance with the cultural evidence, we suppose that the situations of the husband and wife after separation are asymmetric: the husband can eventually remarry whereas the wife cannot.

8

Assumption 2. For any level of income, human capital characteristics and marriage market conditions, satisfied husbands strictly prefer to maintain the links whereas dissatisfied husbands strictly prefer to sever the links, i.e. uh(Ih, xh, xw, 1) > vh (Ih, xh, m2) and uh(Ih, xh, xw, 0) < vh (Ih, xh, m2). Satisfied husbands have an infinite cost of domestic violence, Ch(1)=∞. The cost of violence of dissatisfied husbands, Ch(0), is a random variable κ with cumulative distribution function Fκ on [0,). For any level of income and human capital characteristics, the wife’s utility is higher in an intact marriage with domestic violence than after separation, i.e. uw(Iw, xh, xw) − Cw > vw(Iw, xw).

Assumption 2 indicates that dissatisfied husbands are the only types who have an incentive to separate from their wives, and hence can credibly threaten to sever the links with the wife’s family. In order to guarantee the single-crossing condition, we postulate an extreme form of positive correlation between the husband’s type and the cost of domestic violence: dissatisfied husbands are the only types who may benefit from exercising violence. This assumption is partly justified by our fieldwork; In the villages we consider, the psychic and social costs of exercising violence are high, and unjustified violence in happy marriages is heavily stigmatized by the community. Finally, we assume, as is well documented in our field study, that the wife’s family bears a very high cost of separation.

3.2 Renegotiation and Signaling We start the analysis of the theoretical model with the post-marital renegotiation and signaling game and proceed by backward induction to compute the Bayesian Perfect Equilibria of the game.14 At the last stage of the game, the only husbands who choose to separate from their wives are dissatisfied husbands who do not receive sufficient compensation from the wife’s family. We define the minimal transfer that dissuades a husband from severing the links as th, the solution (when it exists)15 of the following equation: uh (Yh +D+t , xh, xw, 0) − vh (Yh+D, xh, m2) = 0.

(1)

At the third stage of the game, the wife’s family responds to the husband’s demand. As the wife has incomplete information about the husband’s type, we let µ denote her belief that the husband is 14

See Fudenberg and Tirole (1991, p. 325) for a formal definition of Bayesian Perfect Equilibrium in signaling games. 15 From now on, we suppose that there exists a finite transfer th satisfying equation (1). If this were not the case, a dissatisfied husband would always choose to leave his wife, no post marital transfer would be paid, and no husband would ever beat his wife.

9

dissatisfied, given the occurrence of violence and the transfer demanded by the husband. If t
µ<1.16 We conclude that the wife rejects any demand t
µ vw (Yw-D, xw) + (1-µ) uw (Yw-D, xh, xw) − uw (Yw-D-t, xh, xw) = 0.

(2)

Given Assumption 2, equation (2) has a unique solution, tw(µ)>0 We summarize the wife’s family’s optimal decision as follows: the wife’s family accepts any demand tw(µ) ≥ t and rejects any demand t > tw(µ). It is easy to see that tw is an increasing function of the beliefs. The following assumption will greatly simplify the analysis.

Assumption 3. When the wife believes that the husband is dissatisfied, she is willing to dissuade him from separating; when she keeps her prior beliefs on the husband’s type, she does not agree to a transfer w h w preventing the husband from separating, i.e. t (1) > t > t (p(z)).

While Assumption 3 is not expressed in terms of the primitives of the model, it can easily be interpreted. The first inequality, tw(1 )> th , is satisfied if the wife’s family is willing to compensate the husband to prevent separation, i.e.: when her cost of separation is much higher than the husband’s benefits from separation. The second inequality, th > tw(p(z)), is satisfied if the proportion of dissatisfied husbands in the population is low enough. At the signaling stage, the husband announces the transfer t and chooses whether to exercise domestic violence. We distinguish between two types of equilibria: pooling equilibria where both types of husbands adopt the same strategy, and separating equilibria where the different types of husbands choose different strategies.

If µ=1, the wife is indifferent between accepting or rejecting the transfer, but her decision does not affect the payments of the agents, since no transfer will be made to the husband. 16

10

Pooling Equilibria Given Assumption 2, satisfied husbands never exercise violence. Hence, in a pooling equilibrium, neither type of husband behaves violently, and both types choose the same demand t. On the equilibrium path, as the wife’s family keeps her prior belief p(z), and by Assumption 3, the demand is rejected. For this equilibrium to exist, beliefs off the equilibrium path must be specified so that no agent has an incentive to deviate. In particular, a dissatisfied husband with low cost of violence cannot extract an additional transfer by exercising violence. This implies that the wife’s family must reject the demand of a violent husband. But, since tw(1) > th, the wife’s family must assign a positive probability that the husband is satisfied after observing violence. Since satisfied husbands never have an incentive to exercise violence, these beliefs off the equilibrium path do not satisfy the intuitive criterion.

Separating Equilibria We first note that there cannot be a separating equilibrium satisfying the intuitive criterion where neither type of agent behaves violently, and the two types of agents announce different transfers t(0) and t(1). If t(1)< th or t(1)> tw(1), neither type of agent receives a positive transfer on the equilibrium path. By the same argument as above, this equilibrium is sustained by beliefs off the equilibrium path assigning positive probability to satisfied husbands exercising violence and does not satisfy the intuitive criterion. If on the other hand, tw(1)≥ t(1) ≥ th, satisfied husbands can profitably deviate by announcing t(1), thus extracting a positive transfer without incurring any cost. We focus on a separating equilibrium where a dissatisfied husband with low cost of violence exercises domestic violence and announces a transfer tw(1)≥ t ≥ th. By the intuitive criterion, after observing violence, the wife believes that the husband is dissatisfied and accepts any demand. Hence, the optimal strategy of a violent husband is to request a transfer t = tw(1). If the wife does not observe violence, she infers that either the husband is satisfied, or the husband is dissatisfied but has a high cost of violence. Letting κ* denote the maximal cost of a violent husband, we derive the wife’s posterior belief that the husband is dissatisfied as

µ = p(z)(1- Fκ (κ*))/ (p(z)(1- Fκ (κ*))+ 1- p(z)) < p(z). Since tw is an increasing function, by Assumption 4, th > tw(p(z)) > tw(µ0). Hence, the wife rejects the demand of a husband who does not behave violently. We now characterize the value of the maximal cost

κ* for which a dissatisfied husband is indifferent between exercising violence and obtaining the transfer tw(1) and not exercising violence and abandoning his wife. The value κ* is given by:

11

κ* = uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0) − vh (Yh+D, xh, m2).

(3)

Proposition 1. The signaling and renegotiation game admits a unique Bayesian Perfect Equilibrium satisfying the intuitive criterion. It is a separating equilibrium, where dissatisfied husband whose cost of violence is lower than κ*, exercise domestic violence. Dissatisfied husbands whose cost is higher than κ* and satisfied husbands do not exercise violence. Upon observing violence, the wife’s family agrees to a transfer t = tw(1). If no violence is exercised, the wife’s family rejects the husband’s demand. Dissatisfied husbands whose cost is higher than κ* separate from their wives, while satisfied husbands and dissatisfied husbands whose cost is lower than κ* maintain the links with the wife’s family.

Using Proposition 1, we compute the conditional probability of violence given that the husband is dissatisfied as Pr(violence|θ =0)= Fκ(κ*) = Fκ( uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0) − vh (Yh+D, xh, m2)).

Letting B(Yh, D, Yw, xh, xw z, m2) denote the unconditional probability of violence, we have B(Yh, D, Yw, xh, xw z, m2) = p(z) Fκ( uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0) − vh (Yh+D, xh, m2)). (4)

3.3 Dowry Bargaining We now turn to the initial stage of dowry bargaining. Before the marriage is concluded, the values of θ, κ, z and m2 are unknown to the two families. The prior distributions of those variables are given by p(z) ,Fκ, Fz and Fm respectively. The wife’s family makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer to the husband’s family. In computing this offer, the bride’s family takes into account the expected utility of the husband’s family after the marriage. This expected utility depends on the three possible outcomes of the renegotiation game (either the husband is satisfied, or he is dissatisfied with a low cost of violence, or dissatisfied with a high cost of violence). E Uh = ∫ (1-p(z)) uh (Yh +D, xh, xw, 1) dFz +∫∫∫

κ*

p(z) (uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0) − κ) d Fκ dFm dFz

+ ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) vh (Yh+D, xh, m2) d Fκ dFm dFz.

(5)

Similarly, the wife’s expected utility in the marriage is given by E Uw = ∫ (1-p(z)) uw (Yw -D, xh, xw) dFz + ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) (uw (Yw –D – tw(1), xh, xw) − Cw) d Fκ dFm dFz

12

+ ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) vw (Yw-D, xw)) d Fκ dFm dFz.

(6)

In Appendix A, we show that the husband’s expected utility is increasing in the dowry, and, if

∂ κ* / ∂ D < 0, the wife’s expected utility is decreasing in the dowry.17 Hence, in equilibrium, the husband accepts any dowry such that E Uh ≥ R(Yh, xh, m1), and the wife offers the minimal dowry accepted by the husband. We let D= D(Yh, Yw, xh, xw, m1) denote the dowry offered in equilibrium. It is important to note that the determination of the equilibrium dowry relies on our assumption that the wife’s family has all the bargaining power in the negotiation. Other models of bargaining would give rise to alternative specifications of the dowry, and typically produce ambiguous results on the effects of exogenous variables on the equilibrium dowry.

3.4 Comparative Statics In Appendix B, we compute the effect of exogenous variables on the probability of violence after the wedding and on the dowry. In order to perform the comparative statics, we assume that the utility functions are additively separable in income, uh (Ih, xh, xw,θ) = gh(Ih)+ uh ( xh, xw,θ), uw(Iw, xh, xw) =

gw(Iw)+ uw( xh, xw), vh(Ih,xh,m2) = gh(Ih)+ vh(xh,m2) and vw(Iw, xw)= gw(Iw)+ vw(xw). Utilities are increasing in income, and the marginal utility of income is decreasing, i.e. g’h >0, g’w >0, g’’h <0 and g’’w<0.

Proposition 2. Suppose that the utility functions ui and vi are additively separable in income After the marriage, an increase in the income of the wife’s family increases the probability of violence and an increase in the husband’s family’s income, in the observed marriage attributes and in the marriage market conditions reduce the probability of violence. An increase in the income of the wife’s family at the time of marriage reduces the dowry, thereby increasing the probability of violence. An improvement in the marriage market at the time of marriage increases the dowry and reduces the probability of violence.

17

In order to guarantee that the wife’s expected utility is decreasing in the dowry, we need to assume that the probability of violence is decreasing in the dowry. At first glance, this condition may seem counterintuitive. Note however that, by Assumption 2, when facing a dissatisfied husband, the wife would rather incur the cost of violence than the cost of separation. Hence, when ∂ κ* / ∂ D < 0, an increase in the dowry increases the likelihood of separation and reduces the wife’s expected utility. The condition ∂ κ* / ∂ D < 0 is satisfied when utilities are additively separable in income.

13

The first part of Proposition 2 considers the effect of the exogenous variables after the time of marriage. Since utilities are strictly concave in income, an increase in the income of the wife’s family reduces the wife’s family’s marginal utility of income, thereby increasing the level of the transfer tw(1), making violence more attractive to the husband. Similarly, an increase in the husband’s wealth reduces the marginal utility of the transfer, thereby reducing the probability of violence. An increase in the observed attributes of the marriage reduces the probability that the husband is dissatisfied, thus reducing the probability of violence. An increase in the marriage market conditions raises the husband’s incentive to separate from his wife, reducing the probability of violence. Changes in the husband’s and wife’s characteristics, xh and xw, affect both the utility in the marriage and after separation, producing ambiguous effects on the probability of violence. The second part of the Proposition analyzes the effects of changes in the exogenous variables before the marriage is concluded. Most exogenous variables have ambiguous effects on the level of the dowry. Changes in the husband’s wealth affect simultaneously the husband’s reservation utility and his expected utility after marriage, resulting in ambiguous effects. Changes in the wife’s and husband’s characteristics produce ambiguous effects on the expected utility after marriage. The only two variables with clear effects are the wife’s family’s income and the marriage market conditions. As the husband is held to his reservation utility, he cannot benefit from marrying into a richer family. The only effect of an increase in the wife’s family’s wealth is an increase in the transfer paid, resulting in a higher expected utility for the husband and a lower dowry. Better marriage conditions increase the husband’s reservation utility, thereby increasing the dowry. Finally, note that an increase in the dowry affects the probability of violence through two channels: it raises the husband’s income and reduces the wife’s income. As the marginal utility of income of both families is declining, the transfer is reduced, and the probability of violence decreases.

4. Data and Econometric Methodology

To test the predictions from the model we use survey data collected by us from the same potter sub-caste, in three villages in Karnataka State in Southern India, who were the focus of the qualitative interviews. The three villages exchange brides and thus are part of the same marriage market. All 149 potter families in the three villages were interviewed, which included 177 adult women. After dropping never-married and widowed women we are left with a sample of 142 women. In addition to questions relating to socio-economic characteristics and marriage transactions, all the married women were asked if they had ever been severely physically assaulted by the husbands at any time during the marriage, along

14

with questions about the extent and severity of the violence18. The question on the incidence of domestic violence, which was answered by 137 women, elicited a much more accurate response than the questions about its extent and severity19. Thus in this paper we will focus on the determinants of a binary variable indicating whether the wife has ever been severely physically assaulted by her husband. We derive two equations in the previous section for which we provide testable predictions: 1) Dowry Equation: D= D(Yh, Yw, xh, xw, m1) 2) Violence Equation after the Dowry is determined: Pr(violence) = B(Yh, D, Yw, xh, xw z, m2)

We estimate a linear approximation of the Dowry function by OLS. The violence function is estimated with a Probit specification. The Violence equation B(.) is determined endogenously with Dowries and is estimated by Instrumental variables. The variable excluded from the Dowry equation in the first stage is the measure of conditions in the marriage market at the time of the marriage Yh Most of the variables used in the three equations are directly observed, but we do not have direct observations of Yh , Yw and Yh , Yw , the wealth of the husbands and wives families. Wealth is difficult to measure in these villages because most of it is in the form of one or two room homes and very small plots of land which are almost never sold20. Thus, we use the closest proxies we have available - the incomes of the families of the husband and the wife. The characteristics of the husband and wife, Yh , Yw and

Yh , Yw are measured by their years of schooling and ages at marriage, we also include their year of marriage to account for the duration of their marriage. For z, the indicator of the observed characteristics of the marriage, we use the number of male and female children of the couple. Since this is a male dominated society which greatly values male children, their presence should increase the husband’s satisfaction with the marriage. We also include the number of female children for the sake of completeness though their effect is less clear. For conditions in the marriage market, Yh and Yh we use a proxy - the ratio of the number of women to the number men at marriageable ages (defined as women aged 10-19/ men aged 20-29) also

18

The model suggests that some of these women are in bad "separated" marriages where links between the husband's and wife's families have been severed, but where violence is absent. While we have anecdotal evidence from a subsample of 40 interviews suggesting that about fifteen per cent of marriages fall into this category, the survey instrument did not include questions on the quality of the links between the two families. 19 The questions on the extent and severity of violence were answered by only 70 per cent of the sample. Even when the questions were answered the responses had strong interviewer effects with some interviewers being able to elicit more complete and consistent responses than others. On other the hand, the dichotomous question on whether a woman had ever been physically assaulted by her husband was answered by all the respondents without significant interviewer effects. 20 Plots owned by husbands families average 0.61 acres.

15

known as the «marriage squeeze ratio. 21» As the Indian census is conducted every ten years, Yh - the proxy measure for conditions at the time of the marriage - is measured at the census year closest to the year of the marriage, and Yh - the proxy measure for conditions after the marriage - ten years later. While these are macro measures that may not accurately capture conditions specific to these potter families, they are broadly reflective of marriage market conditions encountered by these families22. We obtain the data from the 1951-1991 censuses for Mysore district in Karnataka State - the geographic region within which these households choose their spouses23.

5. Econometric Results

Table 1 provides a few summary statistics about the community. The families in our sample are poor. The mean schooling levels for both women and men is very low, at 1.14 years for women and 1.46 years for men, but the standard deviations are large at 2.56 and 3.03 respectively. This is because 90 per cent of adults have no schooling, while the rest have between five to ten years. The average annual income of the wife’s parents is 5,506 rupees ($625 in PPP adjusted US dollars) while that of the husband’s family is 6440 rupees (PPP $731), but note that the wife’s family’s income has a very large standard deviation of 6572 rupees compared to 784 rupees for the husband’s family income. One possible reason for this large variation is measurement error because we did not interview the parents of the wife directly, but asked the wife to give us an estimate of her parent’s income. Fertility levels are rather low, the average family has 1.18 male children and 1.2 female children. Women are married very young at an average age of 14.7, while their husbands are about ten years older – which helps illustrate the vulnerability of a young bride entering the house of a stranger. Note that 23% of women said that their husbands had beaten them at some time during the marriage. This proportion is higher than the incidence in the US where one in six women report having been struck by their husbands during the course of a marriage (Gelles and Straus, 1989), but consistent with data from other developing countries (Heise et. al., 1999). The average dowry paid is 11,840 rupees with a standard deviation of about six times that. The large variation is mainly because dowries are both negative and positive since this community has moved from paying brideprices (negative dowries) to 21

See Bhat and Halli (1999) for an extended discussion on trends in the availability of grooms in India. There are two reasons for this: firstly the census indicates that over 95% of marriages in these regions occur in the measured age groups. Thus, even older married men who may be contemplating leaving their current wives will be faced with a marriage market dominated by men in younger age groups. Secondly, the relative proportions of men and women in different cohorts are primarily determined by rates of population growth that are, in turn, almost entirely the result of decreases in mortality caused by public health campaigns that impact large regions in a relatively uniform manner.

22

16

dowries. The average of the positive dowries is 39,355 rupees with a standard deviation of 82,993 rupees. The dowry information is reasonably accurate since dowries are the single largest lifetime expense and respondents tended to have a good memory of how much was spent. The mean year of marriage is 1974, but marriages range from 1950 through 1992. The marriage squeeze ratio at the time of the marriage (m1 ) averages 1.06 in this sample indicating that there is a slight surplus of women in the marriage market due to younger cohorts being of larger size than older cohorts because of increases in population growth rates. The ratio ten years after the marriage (m2 ) averages 1.07 suggesting that the surplus has slightly increased with time. Table 2(a) presents OLS estimates of the dowry equation. The theoretical model predicted ambiguous effects for all the exogenous variables with the exception of the income of the wife’s family which was negative and the marriage market parameter which was positive. Most of the estimated coefficients in the dowry regression. The one exception is the marriage squeeze ratio, which is significant at the 10 per cent level, with a 0.01 increase in the ratio raising the dowry by 3000 rupees. The income of the wife’s family has a negative coefficient as hypothesized by the theoretical model, but it is not significantly different from zero. The fact that the other variables are not significant suggests that families may be myopic and focus on the current availability of mates, rather than future prospects when determining the dowry. Tables 2(b) presents estimates from the Probit-IV specification of the violence equation24. Here a number of effects are consistent with the theoretical predictions. A 10,000 rupee increase over the mean of the wife's parents' annual income increases violence by 3.3 per cent indicating that wives with richer parents are more likely to be beaten. The observed and positively valued characteristics of the marriage z, that we measure by the number of male children, also has the predicted effect with an additional male child reducing violence by 10 per cent at the mean. This is consistent with the notion that more male children increases the chances that the husband is satisfied with the marriage. Female children, on the other hand, do not have a significant impact. A 10,000 rupee increase in predicted net dowries, measured at the mean, reduces the probability of violence by five per cent which is also consistent with the theoretical predictions. Note that the dowry effect is significant at the 5 per cent level. While the theoretical model did not generate clear predictions for the human capital variables, husband’s schooling has an interesting impact on violence. A one year increase in the mean value of husband's schooling increases the risk of violence by almost four per cent. The reason for this is unclear, 23

Beedu village is in Coorg district but arranges marriages with families exclusively within Mysore district. The first stage dowry regression in the Probit-IV estimate of violence determinants includes the square of m1 in addition to the other exogenous variables in the system ( R-2 =0.11, F-Statistic=1.23). Note that m1 and m2 are not collinear (ρ=0.19).

24

17

but one possible explanation is that the few educated men in poor communities such as this tend to have hampered expectations. Education is seen as a ticket to life outside the daily grind of rural poverty, but structural constraints and discrimination often force educated men to return to their home villages and the lives of their parents. This results in high levels of depression and alcoholism which in turn increase the probability of domestic violence. This explanation is, of course, outside the boundaries of our model and it suggests that the factors underlying domestic violence may go beyond purely rational considerations.

6. Conclusion

In this case-study we have demonstrated that violence can be used as an instrument to redistribute resources. The example we focus on is the highly publicized link between the marriage market and wifeabuse in the Indian sub-continent. To examine this, we employ an approach that combines the usual methods of economics with ethnographic techniques borrowed from anthropology. We construct a noncooperative bargaining and signaling model of dowries and domestic violence which is informed by the ethnographic evidence. Predictions from this models are tested with survey data gathered from the same population examined in the in-depth interviews. We find that for the most part the econometric evidence is consistent with the theory. In Probit-IV estimates of violence we find that husbands are more likely to beat their wives when the wife’s family is rich because there are more resources to extract and the returns are greater. A husband's greater satisfaction with the marriage indicated by higher numbers of male children, reduces the probability of violence. Thus, it is likely that aspects of violent behavior are strongly linked to economic incentives and deserve greater attention from economists.

18

REFERENCES Alderman, Harold, Pierre-Andre Chiappori and Ravi Kanbur, «Unitary Versus Collective Models of the Household: Is It Time to Shift the Burden on Proof?,» The World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 10 #1, Februrary 1995 Bhat, P.N. Mari, and Shiva S. Halli, "Demography of Brideprice and Dowry: Causes and Consequences of the Indian Marriage Squeeze," Population Studies Vol 53, No. 2, Pp: 129-148, July 1999 Cho, In-Koo and David Kreps, "Signalling Games and Stable Equilibria," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, Pp. 179-221, 1987. Chwe, Michael Suk-Young , «Why Were Workers Whipped? Pain in a Principal-Agent Model,» Economic Journal,100(403), Pp. 1109-21, December 1990 Farmer, Amy and Jill Tiefenthaler, «Domestic Violence: The Value of Services as Signals, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 86, #2, 274-279, May 1996 Farmer, Amy and Jill Tiefenthaler, «An Economic Analysis of Domestic Violence,» Review of Social Economy, Vol. 55, #3, 337-358, Fall 1997 Fruzzetti, Lina M. The Gift of a Virgin: Women, Marriage and Ritual in a Bengali Society, Rutgers University Press, 1982 Fudenberg, Drew and Jean Tirole, Game Theory, MIT Press, Cambridge, 1991. Gelles, Richard J. and Murray A. Straus, Intimate Violence: The Causes and Consequences of Abuse in the American Family, Touchstone - Simon & Schuster Inc., New York, 1989 Heise, Lori, Mary Ellsberg, and Megan Gottemoeller, Ending Violence Against Women, Population Reports, Series L, No. 11, Johns Hopkins University School of Public Health, Population Information Program, Baltimore, December 1999 Jahan, Roshan, «Hidden Wounds, Visible Scars: Violence Against Women in Bangladesh,» in Structures of Patriachy: State, Community and Household in Modernising Asia, Bina Agarwal (ed), Kali for Women, New Delhi, 1991 Kapadia, Karin, Siva and Her Sisters: Gender, Caste and Class in Rural South India. Boulder, Co.: Westview Press, 1995 Karkal, Malini, "Health of Mother and Child Survival," in S. Mukerji (ed.), Dynamics of Population and Family Welfare, Himalaya Publishing House, Bombay, 1985 Karlekar, Malavika, "Domestic Violence," Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XXXIII,No. 27, July 1998 Lundberg, Shelly, and Robert A. Pollak, " Separate Spheres Bargaining and the Marriage Market," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, Pp: 988-1010, December 1993

19

Lundberg, Shelly, and Robert A. Pollak, "An Intergenerational Model of Domestic Violence," Paper Presented at the 1998 Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America, March 1998 Manser, Marilyn and Murray Brown, "Marriage and Household Decision Making: A Bargaining Analysis," International Economic Review, Vol. 21(1), Pp: 31-44, February 1980 McElroy, Marjorie B. and Mary-Jean Horney, "Nash-Bargained Household Decisions: Toward a Generalization of the Theory of Demand," International Economic Review, Vol. 22(2), Pp:333-349, June 1981 Registrar General and Census Commissioner of India, Census of India: Karnataka State - Mysore District; Social and Cultural Tables, Government of India Press, 1951, 1961, 1971, 1981, 1991. Rao, Vijayendra, "The Rising Price of Husbands: A Hedonic Analysis of Dowry Increases in Rural India," Journal of Political Economy,Vol. 101, Pp:666-677, August 1993 Rao, Vijayendra, "Wife-Abuse, Its Causes and Its Impact on Intra-Household Resource Allocation in Rural Karnataka: A "Participatory" Econometric Analysis," in Gender, Population, and Development, M.Krishnaraj, R.Sudarshan, A.Sharif (ed.), Oxford University Press, Delhi and Oxford, 1998 Tauchen, Helen V, Ann Dryden Witte, and Sharon K. Long,» Domestic Violence: A Nonrandom Affair,» International Economic Review, Vol. 32, Pp:491-511, May 1991

20

Appendix APPENDIX A: THE DOWRY EQUATION By equation (2),

∂ tw(1) / ∂ D=-1+(∂ vw (Yw-D, xw)/ ∂ Iw)/( ∂ uw (Yw-D-t, xh, xw)/ ∂ Iw) >-1. Equation (5) yields

∂ E Uh / ∂ D = ∫ (1-p(z)) (∂ uh (Yh +D, xh, xw,, 1) / ∂ Ih) dFz + ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) (∂ uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0)/ ∂ Ih) (1 + ∂ tw(1) / ∂ D ) d Fκ dFm dFz + ∫ ∫ p(z) ( ∂ κ* / ∂ D) (uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0) − κ*) dFm dFz + ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) (∂ vh (Yh+D, xh, m2)/ ∂ Ih) d Fκ dFm dFz. - ∫ ∫ p(z) (∂ κ* / ∂ D ) vh (Yh+D, xh, m2) dFm dFz From equation (3), uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0) − κ* - vh (Yh+D, xh, m2) = 0. Hence,

∂ E Uh / ∂ D = ∫ (1-p(z)) (∂ uh (Yh +D, xh, xw,, 1) /)/ ∂ Ih) dFz + ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) (∂ uh (Yh +D+ tw(1), xh, xw, 0)/ ∂ Ih) (1 + ∂ tw(1) / ∂ D ) d Fκ dFm dFz + ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) (∂ vh (Yh+D, xh, m2)/ ∂ Ih) d Fκ dFm dFz. Since the marginal utility of income is positive, and ∂ tw(1) / ∂ D > -1, ∂ E Uh / ∂ D > 0. Next we use equation (6) to show that, if ∂ κ* / ∂ D < 0, ∂ E Uw / ∂ D < 0.

∂ E Uw / ∂ D = - ∫ (1 - p(z)) ( ∂ uw (Yw -D, xh, xw) / ∂ Iw) dFz - ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) (( ∂ uw (Yw –D – tw(1), xh, xw ) / ∂ Iw )( 1 + ∂ tw(1) / ∂ D ) d Fκ dFm dFz + ∫ ∫ p(z) ( ∂ κ* / ∂ D) (uw (Yw –D – tw(1), xh, xw) − Cw) dFm dFz - ∫ ∫ ∫κ* p(z) ( ∂ vw (Yw-D, xw) / ∂ Iw ) d Fκ dFm dFz. - ∫ ∫ p(z) ( ∂ κ* / ∂ D) vw (Yw-D, xw) dFm dFz. By Assumption 2, uw (Yw –D – tw(1), xh, xw) − Cw - vw (Yw-D, xw) > 0. Hence, since ∂ κ* / ∂ D <0,

∫ ∫ p(z) ( ∂ κ* / ∂ D) (uw (Yw –D – tw(1), xh, xw) − Cw) dFm dFz - ∫ ∫ p(z) ( ∂ κ* / ∂ D) vw (Yw-D, xw) dFm dFz.<0. Since the marginal utility of income is positive and ∂ tw(1) / ∂ D > -1, ∂ E Uw / ∂ D < 0. APPENDIX B: COMPARATIVE STATICS As utilities are additively separable in income, we rewrite equation (2) as gw(Yw-D )- µ(uw(xh,xw) - vw(xw)) - gw(Yw-D-t) = 0. (2’) By implicit differentiation,

21

∂ tw / ∂ D = -1 + (g’w(Yw-D)/ g’w(Yw-D-t)) <0, ∂ tw / ∂ Yw = 1 – (g’w(Yw-D)/ g’w(Yw-D-t)) >0. The violence equation becomes B= p(z) Fκ( gh (Yh +D+ tw(1)) + uh,(xh, xw, 0) − gh (Yh+D) - vh(xh, m2)). (4’) Hence,

∂ B / ∂ Yw = p(z) fκ g’h (Yh +D+ tw(1)) ∂ tw(1) / ∂ Yw >0, ∂ B / ∂ Yh = p(z) fκ (g’h (Yh +D+ tw(1)) – g’h (Yh+D)) <0, ∂ B / ∂ D = p(z) fκ (g’h (Yh +D+ tw(1)) – g’h (Yh+D)) (1 + ∂ tw(1)/ ∂ D) <0, ∂ B / ∂ z = p’(z) Fκ < 0, ∂ B / ∂m2 = - p(z) fκ ∂ vh/ ∂ m2 <0. The dowry is defined by the equation: R(Yh, xh, m1) - E Uh (D) = 0. Simple computations show that

∂ D / ∂ Yw = (∂ E Uh / ∂ tw(1))/ (∂ tw(1)/ ∂ Yw) / (∂ E Uh / ∂ D) <0, ∂ D / ∂ m1 = -(∂ R / ∂ m1)/ (∂ E Uh / ∂ D) >0.

22

Stage 1: Dowry Bargaining

Stage 2: Signaling

Stage 4

The wife’s family makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer to the husband’s family

The husband’s family demands a transfer and chooses whether to exercise violence

The husband decides whether to sever the links with the wife’s family

The marriage is concluded. The husband learns his private level of satisfaction. Both families learn observable marriage characteristics.

Stage 3 The wife’s family responds to the husband’s demand

Figure1: Timing of the Model

23

Table 1: Means and Standard Deviations (N=137) Variables

Mean

Marriage Squeeze Ratio at the time of the Wedding (m1) Marriage Squeeze Ratio ten years after the wedding (m2) Net Dowry in 1992 Rupees

1.060

0.04

1.071

0.02

11,840.44

Beedu Village

0.39

Ooru Village

0.37

Standard Deviation

72,861.06

Year of Marriage

74.39

12.17

Wife’s Age at Marriage

14.71

2.98

Husband’s Age at Marriage

24.46

5.05

Wife’s Education

1.14

2.56

Husband’s Education

1.46

3.03

Husband’s Family’s Income / 1000 (In 1992 Rupees) Wife’s Family’s Income / 1000 (In 1992 Rupees) Number of Male Children Alive

6440.98

784.90

5506.73

6572.05

1.18

1.11

Number of Female Children Alive

1.20

1.08

Incidence of Violence (%)

22.63

24

Table 2: Dowry and Violence Regressions : (Heteroskedasticity Corrected Std. Errors)

Variables

Dowry OLS (N=142) Coefficient |t|

Violence Probit IV (N=137) Derivative |t| P(v) at θ

Marriage Squeeze Ratio at the time of the wedding (m1)

330.111

Marriage Squeeze Ratio ten years after the wedding (m2) Beedu Village

---

--

-0.848

0.4

-3.682

0.2

0.574

0.5

Ooru Village

4.743

0.4

0.155

1.4

Year of Marriage

4.365

0.7

0.081

1.4

Year of Marriage Squared

- 0.037

0.9

-0.001

1.4

Wife’s Age at Marriage

-0.300

0.1

0.014

1.0

Husband’s Age at Marriage

-0.295

0.4

-0.006

1.0

Wife’s Education

2.660

0.8

-0.004

0.2

Husband’s Education

4.518

1.0

0.039

2.3

Husband’s Family’s Income / 1000 (In 1992 Rupees) Wife’s Family’s Income / 1000 (In 1992 Rupees) Number of Male Children Alive

-1.061

1.2

-0.009

1.3

-0.047

0.4

0.003

2.1

---

--

-0.098

2.5

Number of Female Children Alive

---

--

0.018

0.5

Net Dowry /1000 (In 1992 Rupees – Predicted) Constant

---

--

-0.005

2.3

1.6

---

--

-446.774

1.7

---

F-Statistic/Chi-2

0.95

20.36

Adjusted/Pseudo R-Squared

0.08

0.13

--

25

Terror as a Bargaining Instrument: A Case-Study of ...

villages in rural South India to inform the development of a non-cooperative .... At the initial stage of dowry bargaining, both families take into account the ..... addition to the other exogenous variables in the system ( R-2 =0.11, F-Statistic=1.23).

92KB Sizes 1 Downloads 111 Views

Recommend Documents

A characterization of the Nash bargaining solution - Springer Link
Nir Dagan1, Oscar Volij2, Eyal Winter3. 1 Academic Priority Ltd., Rashi 31, 52015 Ramat-Gan, Israel. (e-mail: [email protected]; http://www.nirdagan.com).

A Theory of Disagreement in Bargaining
It is also a good rule not to put overmuch confidence in the observational results that are put ... 79-3, written in November, 1978 and bearing the same title, and 80-18, "A Model of the Commitment. Process in ... of decision-making into account) are

A characterization of the Nash bargaining solution - Springer Link
2 Department of Economics, 260 Heady Hall, Iowa State University, Ames,. Iowa 50011, USA (e-mail address: [email protected]; http://volij.co.il). 3 Department of ...

Download as a PDF
•MATLAB code made publicly available at [1] ... run length distribution, while the red line represents the median of the distribution. Areas of a ... data_library.html.

Download as a PDF
School of Computer Science ... for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy ... This research was sponsored in part by the National Science Foundation under grant ...

Download as a PDF
Oct 15, 2007 - Examples demonstrating the rationale, properties and advantages of this ..... point interacts only with a few of its neighbors, or a local cloud of .... quality and without computing the eigenvectors of the graph Laplacian matrix.

Download as a PDF
Spatial Data Cartridge and ESRI's Spatial Data Engine (SDE). .... include a scan and index-search in conjunction with the plane-sweep algorithm 5]. .... alternative processing strategies for spatial operations during query optimization.

History of cannabis as a medicine - SciELO
Oct 4, 2005 - Abstract. Cannabis as a medicine was used before the Christian era in Asia, mainly in India. The introduction of cannabis in the Western medicine occurred in the midst of the 19th century, reaching the climax in the last decade of that

Download as a PDF
An advantage of this approach is that the shape of the formation can be .... via a wireless RC signal. ... an advantage over previous methods, particularly.

Download as a PDF
•Closed form and online inference algorithm ... parameters our method has a better predictive likelihood than [2]. 500. 1000. 1500. 2000. 2500 ... data_library.html.

Download as a PDF
notebook, taking photographs and video footage of people when they are not ... Ethnography is simply not applicable to ad hoc market research. QMRIJ. 9,2.

Download as a PDF
reaction are attributed to the electronic effects of the xanthone oxygen (O10), the C9 carbonyl ..... ZSE mass spectrometer under fast atom bombardment (FAB).

Download as a PDF
Spectrum sharing between wireless networks improves the efficiency ... scarcity due to growing demands for wireless broadband ..... But it is in the advantage of.

Is a Minimum Wage an Appropriate Instrument for ...
Dec 20, 2016 - Internet: http://people.few.eur.nl/bjacobs/. This is a drastically ..... labor rationing only affects individuals that have the lowest utility surplus of work (e.g.,. Marceau and Boadway, 1994; ...... structural and temporary business-

Spin as a Manifestation of a Nonlinear Constitutive ...
The function Q will be chosen so that the particle solutions are force-free. The determination of Q has to be done for each particle separately. Tij is defined with the opposite sign from what is usually used in 3-dimensions. It is useful because it

A unique demand management instrument in urban transport: the ...
0264-2751/98 $19.00 + 0.00. PII: S0264-2751(97)10004-X. A unique demand management instrument in urban transport: the vehicle quota system in Singapore.

The Preference Survey Module: A Validated Instrument for ... - IZA
cluding, e.g., financial decision-making, educational choices, labor market ... particular preference with a reasonably high degree of precision, and which are held ..... 8 Section A in the online appendix gives a list of all survey items we used in 

The Preference Survey Module: A Validated Instrument for ... - IZA
Belmont, California, USA. Greiner, B. (2004): “An Online Recruitment System for Economic Experiments,”. Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen, 63, ...