European Journal of Political Economy 24 (2008) 737–741

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

European Journal of Political Economy j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w. e l s e v i e r. c o m / l o c a t e / e j p e

The conservative central banker revisited: Too conservative is more costly than too liberal Peter Tillmann Swiss National Bank, Economic Analysis, Börsenstrasse 15, CH-8022 Zurich, Switzerland

a r t i c l e

i n f o

Article history: Received 18 July 2008 Revised 5 September 2008 Accepted 5 September 2008 Available online 26 September 2008

a b s t r a c t A conservative central banker, who puts more weight on inflation stabilization than the social planner, solves the stabilization bias of discretionary monetary policy. This note shows that the welfare costs of deviating from the optimal degree of monetary conservatism are asymmetric. A too conservative central banker is more costly than a too liberal central banker. © 2008 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

JEL classification: E32 E52 E58 Keywords: Optimal monetary policy Delegation Conservative central bank Stabilization bias

“Contrary to an assumption of Rogoff's paper, in practice the policy preferences of a newly appointed central banker will not be precisely known by the public…” Fed Governor Ben S. Bernanke (2004)

1. Introduction In the recent generation of New Keynesian models of the business cycle, discretionary monetary policy results in inflation being insufficiently stabilized. This result is known as the stabilization bias of monetary policy.1 This bias gives a rationale for delegation monetary policy to a central bank which is more inflation-averse than the social planner, i.e. to a “conservative central banker”. In other words, Rogoff's (1985) seminal analysis carries over to a new generation of forward-looking models, even in the absence of a classic inflation bias. Since the public knows that inflation will respond less to a cost-push shock, expected future inflation is subdued. Stabilizing inflation becomes less costly in terms of future output contraction. This note revisits the case for optimal monetary conservatism. Suppose the candidates for the Fed chairmanship attach different weights to the conflicting goals of output versus inflation stabilization. Suppose further, that the social planner, e.g. the government, is not completely certain about the preferences of alternative candidates. What are the costs of appointing the wrong candidate?

1

E-mail address: [email protected]. See Svensson (1997) and Clarida et al. (1999) for this theoretical result. Dennis and Söderström (2006) quantify the size of this bias.

0176-2680/$ – see front matter © 2008 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2008.09.006

738

P. Tillmann / European Journal of Political Economy 24 (2008) 737–741

This note generalizes a finding of Issing et al. (2005, p. 92). As a by-product of their model these authors observe that “deviations in the direction of excessive conservatism entail larger losses than the converse”. We use a standard New Keynesian model and proof that the welfare loss resulting from appointing a central banker with slightly suboptimal output weights is asymmetric. Appointing a too conservative central banker is more costly in terms of welfare than appointing a too liberal central banker.2 This note is organized as follows. Section 2 derives the socially optimal weight on output fluctuations in the central bank's loss function. In Section 3, we show that the welfare costs of deviating from the optimal weight are asymmetric and derive the main result. Section 4 summarizes. 2. Optimal policy delegation This section derives the textbook-result on optimal monetary delegation, see e.g. Walsh (2003, chapter 11). Consider the simplest version of a New-Keynesian model. Inflation is described by a forward-looking Phillips curve (1), which represents a loglinearized equilibrium condition of a simple sticky-price general equilibrium model. Here πt is the inflation rate, xt the output gap, and Et is the expectations operator. The discount factor is denoted by β b 1 and κ, the slope coefficient of the Phillips curve, is inversely related to the degree of nominal rigidities πt ¼ βEt πtþ1 þ κxt þ et :

ð1Þ

The cost-push shock et exhibits some degree of persistence described by the AR(1) coefficient 0 ≤ ρ b 1 et ¼ ρet−1 þ et with et fN ð0; 1Þ: Monetary policy is assumed to minimize the welfare loss L, which is described in terms of inflation volatility and output gap volatility weighted by the parameter λCB N 0 n o min L ¼ min π 2t þ λCB x2t : πt ;xt

πt ;xt

ð2Þ

For simplicity, the target values for output and inflation are set to zero. Woodford (2003, chapter 6) develops this policy objective function as an approximation to the utility of the representative household. Under discretionary policy, expectations are taken as given and the first order conditions of maximizing Eq. (2) subject to Eq. (1) imply κπ t þ λCB xt ¼ 0:

ð3Þ

Equilibrium inflation and output are given by πt ¼

xt ¼

λCB

et

ð4Þ

et :

ð5Þ

CB

λ ð1−βρÞ þ κ 2 −κ λCB ð1−βρÞ þ κ 2

Both inflation and output gap fluctuations are stabilized less if shocks become more persistent. The solution under discretion differs from that under commitment to a rule. Suppose the central bank can credibly commit to a non-inertial rule of the form xrule = bxet and πrule = bπet, where bx and bπ are coefficients to be determined. With this rule, t t equilibrium inflation is given by πrule ¼ t

λð1−βρÞ λð1−βρÞ2 þκ 2

et :

ð6Þ

Comparing Eqs. (4) and (6) makes obvious that inflation is inefficiently stabilized under discretion, i.e. var(πrule ) b var(πt) for t ρ N 0.3 This bias becomes larger if ρ increases. For white noise shocks, the stabilization bias disappears. One way to overcome the stabilization bias is to delegate policy to a central bank that differs from the social planner with respect to the weight attached to conflicting policy objectives. The social planner weights fluctuations in the output gap with

2 In Tillmann (2007), the asymmetric loss that results from appointing the wrong central banker is derived in an environment of model unertainty implying a robust control approach to optimal monetary policy. 3 Note that xt = xrule . t

P. Tillmann / European Journal of Political Economy 24 (2008) 737–741

739

Fig. 1. Welfare loss as a function of 1 ± Δ. P

a weight λ , which is not restricted to coincide with the weight of the central bank. The social planner then chooses λ CB in order to minimize the welfare loss resulting from the equilibrium outcome for a given λ CB 8" #2 " #2 9 = 1 < λCB −κ P : ð7Þ min þλ CB CB CB 1−ρ : 2 2 ; λ λ ð1−βρÞ þ κ λ ð1−βρÞ þ κ As a result, the following condition is obtained λCB ¼ λP ð1−βρÞ:

ð8Þ

Since βρ b 1, the optimal output weight of the central bank lies below the weight the social planner attaches to output gap fluctuations. Hence, the social planner chooses a central banker who puts more weight on inflation stabilization than the social planner. The central bank is conservative in the sense of Rogoff (1985). Since the public knows that inflation will respond less to a cost-push shock, future expected inflation rises less. When a conservative central banker is appointed, the discretionary solution will coincide with the outcome under commitment to the optimal simple rule. In case the cost-push shocks are serially uncorrelated, i.e. ρ = 0, the stabilization bias disappears and the gain from delegation is zero, i.e. λCB = λP. 3. Being too conservative versus too liberal Suppose the planner appoints a central banker whose weight on output gap stabilization λ~CB differs slightly from the socially optimal value λCB λfCB ¼ λCB ð1FΔÞ ð9Þ ¼ λP ð1−βρÞð1FΔÞ; 1NΔN0: where Δ can be interpreted as a “conservatism-gap”. A positive deviation 1 + Δ indicates that the central banker is too dovish, while a negative deviation 1 − Δ stands for a central banker who is too hawkish on inflation stabilization relative to λCB. The following proposition posits the main finding of this note. Proposition 1. A central banker who is too conservative relative to the socially optimal value of conservatism is more costly than a central banker who is too liberal, i.e. L−Δ NLþΔ . Proof. Let the resulting welfare be denoted by LþΔ in case of a positive deviation of size Δ, i.e. a too liberal central banker, and L−Δ in case of a negative deviation, i.e. a too conservative central banker. Inserting Eqs. (4) and (5) in Eq. (2) and using Eq. (9), LþΔ bL−Δ is equivalent to  2  2 λP ð1−βρÞ2 ð1 þ ΔÞ2 þλP κ 2 λP ð1−βρÞ2 ð1−ΔÞ2 þλP κ 2 b h i2 h i2 : λP ð1−βρÞ2 ð1 þ ΔÞ þ κ 2 λP ð1−βρÞ2 ð1−ΔÞ þ κ 2 Solving the algebra reveals that this inequality holds as long as ΔN0; which is true by construction. □ When the central banker places too much weight (relative to the socially optimal weight) on inflation stabilization, welfare sharply deteriorates. When the central banker, in contrast, places too much weight on output gap stabilization, welfare deteriorates

740

P. Tillmann / European Journal of Political Economy 24 (2008) 737–741

Fig. 2. Variance of inflation (blue line) and the output gap (red line) relative to the variances under the optimal degree of conservatism as a function of 1 ± Δ. (For interpretation of the references to colour in this figure legend, the reader is referred to the web version of this article.)

mildly. Hence, the welfare costs of appointing the wrong central banker are asymmetric. Erring on the dovish side is less costly than erring on the hawkish side.4 Fig. 1 plots the welfare loss of discretionary monetary policy as a function of 1 ± Δ for plausible parameter values. Take Δ = 0.3 as an example. All other parameters are calibrated to standard values taken from the literature, i.e. κ = 0.05, β = 0.99, ρ = 0.8, and λP = 0.25. Clearly, the welfare loss of delegating policy to a too liberal central bank gives rise to a welfare loss that falls short of the loss under delegation to a too conservative central bank. Hence, LþΔ bL−Δ . Fig. 2 disentangles the welfare loss into its components, i.e. into the variances of inflation and output. If policy is too liberal, inflation volatility increases and output volatility falls. Weighted by λP, the net effect is a mild deterioration of welfare. If, however, policy is too conservative, output gap volatility explodes while inflation volatility falls moderately. The net effect is a sharp increase of the welfare loss as depicted in Fig. 1. To understand this finding, we reformulate the first order condition (3) in terms of variances as  x2t ¼

−κ

λCB

2 π2t :

Take the inflation variance that results from the optimal delegation weight as given. Then the variance of the output gap depends nonlinearly on λCB.5 4. Conclusions and policy implications Delegating monetary policy to a central banker, who puts more weight on inflation stabilization than the social planner, i.e. a conservative central banker, solves the stabilization bias of discretionary monetary policy. This note showed that the welfare costs of deviating from the optimal degree of monetary conservatism are asymmetric. A too conservative central banker is more costly than a too liberal central banker. Let us turn back to the example used in the introduction. Suppose again that the government is uncertain about the preferences of the central bank, but is aware of the asymmetric nature of the costs associated with deviations from the optimal output gap weight. The analysis presented in this paper suggests that it is cheaper to err on the dovish side than on the hawkish side. If the optimal degree of conservatism remains unchanged under uncertainty, the government will appoint a central banker who is too dovish relative to the socially optimal level of conservatism, thus leading to excessively high inflation volatility. The result will be different, however, if the optimal degree of conservatism reflects the information structure. Hence, the fact that the policymaker is uncertain about the central banker's type will affect the optimal degree of conservatism.6

4 Beetsma and Jensen (2003) argue that the form of the loss function affects the implications of preference uncertainty for the design of monetary institutions. They propose a loss function in which the weights sum to one, i.e. L ¼ ð1−λÞπ 2t þ λx2t . Some additional calculations, which are available upon request, show that the results in this paper are robust to this specification. 5 See Eijffinger et al. (2000) for a similar analysis of the asymmetric effects of central bank preferences on the resulting variances. 6 See Beetsma and Jensen (1998) for an analysis of the gains from monetary delegation under preference uncertainty.

P. Tillmann / European Journal of Political Economy 24 (2008) 737–741

741

Acknowledgements I am grateful to Alex Cukierman and Manfred J. M. Neumann for fruitful discussions on an earlier draft. Moreover, I thank Jakob de Haan (the editor) and an anonymous referee for very helpful comments. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of the Swiss National Bank. References Beetsma, R.M.W.J., Jensen, H., 1998. Inflation targets and contracts with uncertain central bank preferences. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30, 384–403. Beetsma, R.M.W.J., Jensen, H., 2003. Why money talks and wealth whispers: monetary uncertainty and mystique. A comment. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 35, 129–136. Bernanke, B.S., 2004. Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke. Speech given at the conference on Reflections on Monetary Policy 25 Years after October 1979. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, October 8, 2004. Clarida, R., Galí, J., Gertler, M., 1999. The science of monetary policy: a New Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 1661–1707. Dennis, R., Söderström, U., 2006. How important is precommitment for monetary policy? Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 38, 847–872. Eijffinger, S.C.W., Hoeberichts, M., Schaling, E., 2000. Why money talks and wealth whispers: monetary uncertainty and mystique. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 32, 218–235. Issing, O., Gaspar, V., Tristani, O., Vestin, D., 2005. Imperfect knowledge and monetary policy. The Stone Lectures in Economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Rogoff, K., 1985. The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 1169–1189. Svensson, L., 1997. Optimal inflation targets, “conservative” central banks, and linear inflation contracts. American Economic Review 87, 98–114. Tillmann, P., 2007. Does model uncertainty justify conservatism? Robustness and the delegation of monetary policy. Unpublished, University of Bonn. Walsh, C., 2003. Monetary Theory and Policy. MIT Press, Cambridge. Woodford, M., 2003. Interest and Prices. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

The conservative central banker revisited: Too ...

Sep 26, 2008 - Fed Governor Ben S. Bernanke (2004). 1. Introduction. In the recent generation of New Keynesian models of the business cycle, discretionary monetary ..... The Stone Lectures in Economics. Cambridge University Press,. Cambridge. Rogoff, K., 1985. The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate ...

297KB Sizes 0 Downloads 132 Views

Recommend Documents

Revisiting the case for a populist central banker
wages in an independent manner, the degree of labor substitutability and the. *Tel. .... C. G and are, respectively, i's consumption and the in#ation rate.

Revisiting the case for a populist central banker
This paper shows that the source of several di!erences in the results of the two .... The real wage elasticity I under NWB is obtained mapping nominal wage growth (the ..... The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target.

Optimal Inflation Targets, "Conservative" Central Banks ...
conservative" central bank eliminates the inflation bias, mimics an optimal in- ... best equilibrium with an inflation bias relative ..... demand depends on the real interest rate and the nominal interest ... direct control of the central bank, but t

Optimal Inflation Targets, "Conservative" Central Banks ...
We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and .... (ii) No central bank with an explicit inflation target seems to behave as if it wishes to ...... is 2 percent per year (perhaps because a quality ..... "The Optimal Degree of.

Optimal Central Banker Contracts and Common Agency
an interest group, in addition to the contract designed by the government. We ..... Financial support from the Ministerio de Educación y Ciencia of Spain [Grant ...

Optimal Central Banker Contracts and Common Agency
We begin by considering the contract offered by the government. With this aim, let (t*,t*0,τ*,τ*0) denote a set of equilibrium contracts. Taking as given the incentive scheme designed by the interest group (i.e., the values, τ*,τ*0), the governme

Notes _Aggresive conservative investor.pdf
There ought to be available to the investor a reasonable amount of relevant. information that is akin to full disclosure, though this will always be something that. falls somewhat short of the mark. The price at which the equity security can be bough

Conservative treatment of isolated fractures of the ... - Semantic Scholar
J Bone Joint Surg [Am] 1976;58-A:356-7. 3. Joy G, Patzakis MJ, Harvey JP. .... New York: Apple- ton-Century-Crofts 1976:223-5. 34. Weseley MS, Koval R, ...

pdf-1830\competent-to-counsel-the-history-of-a-conservative ...
... the apps below to open or edit this item. pdf-1830\competent-to-counsel-the-history-of-a-conser ... tant-anti-psychiatry-movement-by-david-a-powlison.pdf.