American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2013, 103(3): 369–374 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.3.369

The Home Economics of E-Money: Velocity, Cash Management, and Discount Rates of M-Pesa Users † By Isaac Mbiti and David N. Weil*

M-Pesa, a service operated by the mobile phone network Safaricom in Kenya, allows users to deposit money onto their telephone handsets, transfer e-money to another user with a simple text message, and withdraw cash at one of thousands of outlets throughout the country. The system is safer, cheaper, and far faster than the money transfer systems that it replaced. Although only five years old, M-Pesa has achieved remarkable penetration into the Kenyan economy. As of September 2011, there were 32,000 M-Pesa outlets at which individuals could exchange cash for e-money or viceversa, in a country that as of 2009 had 491 bank branches, 500 postbank branches, and 352 ATMs (Mas and Ng’weno 2009). In the sixmonth period April–September 2011, the volume of transfers was Ksh 314 billion, compared to nominal GDP of Ksh 2.99 trillion that year. (For the period from which our data are drawn, the market exchange rate was approximately 75 Ksh/dollar, and the PPP exchange rate was approximately 35 Ksh/dollar). At present, M-Pesa is primarily a money transfer system. However, it has the potential to evolve in two exciting directions: first as a gateway via which unbanked households can access financial services, and second, as a transaction medium, with e-money partially replacing cash.1

Even in its current form, however, M-Pesa represents a dramatic change in the economic environment of Kenyan households. Further, data on how households use M-Pesa allows for insight into the objectives of and constraints on their money management choices, and consumption more generally. I. Monetary Characteristics of E-Money

A. Velocity For the purposes of understanding where M-Pesa fits into a broader monetary framework, we are interested in calculating the “velocity” of M-Pesa. In standard monetary economics, there are two different definitions of velocity that are used. “Income velocity” is nominal GDP divided by the relevant money stock. “Transactions velocity” is defined as the frequency with which the average unit of money is used in transactions. Although in some ways more fundamental than income velocity, transactions velocity is much harder to measure, because doing so requires being able to observe actual transactions. In the case of M-Pesa, the potentially relevant transactions are the creation of a unit of e-money (corresponding to a deposit of cash with an M-Pesa agent), transfer of e-money from one user to another, and withdrawal of cash (extinguishing of a unit of M-Pesa). Further, among transfers that take place, some will be in the nature of payments (for example, a user transfers e-money from her account to that of a merchant in return for goods and services), while others will be in the form of a gift (for example, one family member sending money to another). The majority of transfers observed are of the latter type, although this has been changing as the system matures. As our measure of M-Pesa velocity, we focus only on transfers. Our measure is thus the total value of person-to-person transfers (i.e.,

* Mbiti: Department of Economics, Southern Methodist University, 3300 Dyer St. Suite 301, Dallas, TX 75275 (e-mail: [email protected]); Weil: Brown University, Box B, Providence, RI 02912 (e-mail: [email protected]). † To view additional materials, and author disclosure statement(s),visit the article page at http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.3.369. 1 As discussed in Mbiti and Weil (2011), Safaricom introduced a savings product, M-Kesho, as well as an insurance product, both of which are linked to the M-Pesa account. Safaricom recently (in December 2012) announced the launch of a new service, M-Shwari, that is essentially an improved version of M-Kesho offering customers a way to earn interest on balances and also obtain small loans through its partner commercial bank. 369

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS

transfers in which neither party is an M-Pesa agent) per unit time divided by the average outstanding balance of e-money. We call this “transfer velocity.” Of the two numbers required to measure transfer velocity, the harder one to obtain is the outstanding balance of e-money. All money deposited to create e-money is held by a trust fund which holds deposits in commercial banks. Thus, the outstanding balance of e-money is in principle perfectly observable at any point in time, although the information is not normally made public. Weil, Mbiti, and Mwega (2011) use data on the size of the trust balance monthly from July 2007 through December 2011. While the trust balance is by construction identical to the quantity of e-money outstanding, to calculate transfer velocity, we want to adjust for e-money that is held by M-Pesa agents. We construct an estimate of this quantity by subtracting estimated e-money held on the phones of M-Pesa agents from the trust balance. Eijkman, Kendall, and Mas (2010) report end of day e-money for different types of M-Pesa outlets. These range from Ksh 90,000 for rural stores to Ksh 40,000 for city stores. Rural stores have particularly high end of day float because they do a primarily cash-out business, that is, they primarily pay out cash in return for e-money presented by their customers. City stores did a more balanced business, though with an excess of cash-in over cash-out. In our calculations we chose a value of Ksh 50,000 per M-Pesa agent. Multiplying this by the number of M-Pesa agents gives our estimate of total e-money held by M-Pesa agents. From the Safaricom website, we have data on the number of agents monthly from April 2007 through April of 2011. For most of the existence of M-Pesa, the ratio of e-money held on agent phones to total e-money has fluctuated narrowly within the range of 10–12 percent. The other piece of information required for the calculation of transfer velocity is the monthly value of person to person transfers. This is reported by Safaricom for the period April 2007–April 2010. Using this data, Figure 1 shows our calculated value of monthly transfer velocity. The series shows a significant upward trend, rising from roughly two transfers per month in the first year of M-Pesa’s operation to roughly four in the last few months for which we have data.

MAY 2013

6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Ju l Se –07 p– N 07 ov – Ja 07 n M –08 ar M –08 ay – Ju 08 l Se –08 p– N 08 ov Ja –08 n M –09 ar M –09 ay – Ju 09 l– Se 09 p N –09 ov – Ja 09 n– M 10 ar –1 0

370

Figure 1. Transfer Velocity of M-Pesa

The calculated values of velocity seem to indicate that M-Pesa is functioning as a hybrid of a money transfer system, on the one hand, and a means for storing value, on the other. Velocity of four, for example, implies that the average unit of e-money was transferred once per week. If M-Pesa were purely being used as a money transfer system, we might expect that velocity would be significantly higher. For example, a simple deposit-transfer-withdraw transaction might involve e-money being created (in the sense that it is transferred from an agent to a customer), transferred, and extinguished (transferred back to an agent’s phone) in much less than a day. This would imply a velocity of over 30 transfers per month. Since we know anecdotally that at least some users indeed do not keep e-money on their phones for very long, our estimates of velocity imply that some other users are keeping their cash on phones for significantly longer than one week. Such a situation would imply that most e-money at any point in time is held by nonfrequent transactors, even though most transfers are done by frequent transactors. Velocity can be written as the ratio of monthly transfers per customer to average balances held per customer. Weil, Mbiti, and Mwega (2011) find that rising monthly transfers per customer were the major factor leading velocity to rise, although this series was quite stable around Ksh 2,700 after December 2008. Balances of e-money per customer were relatively stable, in the neighborhood of Ksh 800, although they fell by about 20 percent from July 2009 to April 2011.

VOL. 103 NO. 3

THE HOME ECONOMICS OF E-MONEY

1.2 1.15 1.1 1.05 1 0.95 0.9 0.85 0.8 Jul–07 Aug–07 Sep–07 Oct–07 Nov–07 Dec–07 Jan–08 Feb–08 Mar–08 Apr–08 May–08 Jun–08 Jul–08 Aug–08 Sep–08 Oct–08 Nov–08 Dec–08 Jan–09 Feb–09 Mar–09 Apr–09 May–09 Jun–09 Jul–09

One of the reasons that economists care about velocity is that it measures the degree to which different components of the money supply contribute to aggregate demand. Were it the case that e-money had a notably higher velocity than other types of money, then it would be possible that conventionally measured monetary aggregates were understating the effective money supply. For the present, however, this is not a concern, because M-Pesa is still very small. In December 2011, currency outside of banks (M0) was Ksh 137 billion, while currency plus demand deposits (M1) was Ksh 623 billion (Central Bank of Kenya 2011). By contrast, in that month, the balance of e-money outstanding was only Ksh 17.4 billion.

371

Figure 2. Length of the E-Money Loop

B. The E-Money Loop Irving Fisher defined the “cash loop” as the number of transactions that a unit of currency goes through between being withdrawn from a bank and returning to a bank.  Analogously, we can think of the “e-money loop” as the number of transfer transactions that the average unit of M-Pesa goes through between being transferred onto a customer phone and being transferred back from a customer phone to the phone of an M-Pesa agent.  As with velocity, we can put together available scraps of information to get an estimate of the length of the e-money loop; Kimenyi and Ndung’u (2009) give the value of “deposits plus withdrawals”  for the period July 2007–July 2009. We combine this with data from Safaricom on the monthly value of person-to-person transfers. For a system that is not growing over time, the relationship between deposits, withdrawals, transfers, and the length of the e-money loop is2  2 × transfers     looplength = __. deposits + withdrawals

2 The key assumption required to derive this equation is that the system is in a steady state, where monthly deposits are equal to monthly withdrawals. In this case (deposits + withdrawals)/2 is just equal to the quantity of deposits.   Also, in this case, transfers made in a given month would be equal to transfers that would eventually be made with the e-money created in a given month. The formula is not fully accurate, since M-Pesa was, in fact, growing over time.

Figure 2 shows our calculated loop length. It is interesting to note that in the data the e-money loop starts out at slightly less than one before trending up to almost exactly one. A loop length of one would obtain if all transactions took the form of deposit-transfer-withdraw, while a length greater than one would be observed if some people who received a transfer sent e-money on somewhere else without doing a withdrawal. Similarly, loop length will be reduced to the extent that people use their phones to store money without its ever being transferred. Of course, it is possible that there was a good deal of both these activities (receiving money and transferring it onward without taking money out, on the one hand, and depositing and withdrawing without transferring, on the other), but the data are suggestive, at least to us, of the overwhelming majority of use being of the deposit-transfer-withdraw type. Observation of the length of the e-money loop provides a convenient diagnostic about the extent to which e-money is substituting for cash (which has a long loop length) as a means of transactions. Clearly, in this data, little or no such substitution is taking place. II. Household Cash Management

A. Prices Table 1 shows a simplified version of the M-Pesa fee schedule (we ignore transfers to and withdrawals by nonregistered users, as these are

372

Table 1—M-Pesa Fee Schedule (Ksh) Transaction type Deposit cash Send money to registered user Withdraw cash (registered user)

Table 2—Distribution of Withdrawal Amounts (Ksh)

Range

Charge

100–35,000 100–35,000 100–2,500 2,501–5,000 5,001–10,000 10,001–20,000 20,001–35,000

Free 30 25 45 75 145 170

relatively rare).3 A notable characteristic of the schedule is the “price notches,” in the sense of Slemrod (2010): points at which an incremental change in customer behavior causes a discrete jump in costs. The incentives at price notches are far stronger than those associated with kinks in price schedules such as changes in marginal tax rates. For example, the fee for withdrawing up to Ksh 2,500 is Ksh 25, while the fee for withdrawing Ksh 2,501–5,000 is Ksh 45. Thus, a person who withdraws Ksh 2,600 will be paying a marginal fee of Ksh 20 (20 percent) on the last Ksh 100 withdrawn compared to a fee of 1 percent on the first Ksh 2,500 withdrawn. Below we examine the behavioral response to these kinks. B. Transaction Frequency and Size Weil, Mbiti, and Mwega (2011) examine data on the frequency of M-Pesa use from the 2009 FinAccess Survey. Focusing their regression analysis on M-Pesa users, they show that urban users, highly educated users (secondary school graduates and above), and individuals with more assets used M-Pesa more frequently than their rural, less educated, and poorer counterparts. Their estimates show that, for instance, an urban M-Pesa user conducts six more transaction per annum relative to a nonurban user, while asset poor M-Pesa users conduct five fewer transactions per year relative to “non–asset poor” users. 3

MAY 2013

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS

In March 2012, after the period from which our data are drawn, the price schedule was changed. Most notably, lower prices were introduced for very small transactions (Ksh 5 to transfer Ksh 100, and Ksh 10 to withdraw up to Ksh 100), and the fee for large transfers was increased (Ksh 50 for transfers of Ksh 5,000–20,000 and Ksh 75 for transfers above that up to Ksh 40,000).

Observations Mean Tenth percentile Twenty-fifth percentile Median Seventy-fifth percentile Nintieth percentile

Cyber Center

Katito

3,477 2,757 300 500 1,000 2,850 6,370

6,401 1,402 250 475 900 1,680 3,000

Homa Bay 2,787 5,762 390 700 1,970 6,500 18,500

The FinAccess Survey also contains information on frequency of M-Pesa use among individuals who describe themselves as users. For example, among men, 1.2 percent report using M-Pesa daily, 12.5 percent weekly, 32.4 percent monthly, and 53.9 percent irregularly. Mbiti and Weil calculate annual frequencies of use from these data. Some of their calculated values are men 21.4; women 15.7; banked individuals 27.8; nonbanked 10.4; rural 13.5; urban 23.9. One implication from this data is that while many individuals do not use M-Pesa frequently, the average transaction (deposit, withdrawal, or transfer) is made by a frequent user. Mbiti and Weil calculate that daily users account for 32 percent of transactions, weekly users for 41 percent of transactions, monthly users 21 percent, and irregular users account for only 6 percent.4 Complementing this survey data, Mbiti and Weil also obtained data on withdrawals and deposits from three M-Pesa agents: Cyber Center, an urban outlet near one of the markets in the city of Kisumu; Katito, a small town with a population of roughly 5,000, located in a rural area; and Homa Bay, a provincial market town with a population of roughly 20,000 on a main highway (more information is given by Eijkman, Kendall, and Mas, 2010). Table 2 gives data on the distribution of withdrawals. The most striking finding in these data is the extent to which a

4 Aside from sending and receiving transfers, data from the 2009 FinAccess and Jack and Suri (2012) show that the main other uses reported by M-Pesa users were saving or storing money (sometimes even temporarily, such as when a user travels on a bus and wants to safely store his money), and/or were paying for goods and services. The proportion of users paying for services via M-Pesa grew from 3 percent in 2009 to over 30 percent in 2012.

VOL. 103 NO. 3

THE HOME ECONOMICS OF E-MONEY

large part of the distribution is composed of very small withdrawals. Mbiti and Weil also present histograms showing the distribution of withdrawal amounts. They find that there is no concentration of withdrawals at amounts corresponding to price notches, other than the lumping one would expect at round-number amounts. For example, at all three outlets, withdrawals of Ksh 2,500 (just below a price notch) are much less common than withdrawals of either Ksh 2,000 or Ksh 3,000. C. Implied Discount Rates Our knowledge of how individuals manage their M-Pesa accounts is imperfect and circumstantial. Far better data are locked away in Safaricom’s computers. Nonetheless, we can pull together several pieces of information to paint a suggestive picture. Specifically, we note that (i) most M-Pesa transactions are made by frequent users; (ii) there is little evidence of spikes in the density of withdrawals at points where there is a price notch; (iii) the average time that a unit of M-Pesa remains on a user phone is about one week. These observations suggest that the majority of users do not use their phones for storing value, and that the majority of transactions in the system involve one user depositing money to a phone and transferring it while a second user withdraws cash soon after receiving a transfer.5 These observations of behavior allow for insight into households’ operative discount rates. Although M-Pesa balances do not pay explicit interest, holding money in M-Pesa does yield interest in the form of reducing transaction costs.  Consider a very simple model of a household that receives small, regular monthly transfers. One strategy would be to withdraw each transfer as it is received. An alternative would be to group two or more transfers together and withdraw them all at once (for simplicity in this example, the only alternative strategy we consider is grouping two transfers at a time together).  The latter strategy holds money on the M-Pesa account for longer but involves lower costs. 5 Our view that individuals do not use their phones for storing value runs counter to the result reported in Jack and Suri (2011) that three out of four M-Pesa users report using it to save money.

373

Let W be the monthly transfer received, and C be the withdrawal cost (we assume that W is such that 2W can be withdrawn at the same cost as W). The monthly discount rate r at which an individual would be indifferent between these two strategies is given implicitly by the equation W −C 2W − C W − C + _ = _. 1+r 1+r Using values of W = 1,000 and C = 25, which would be consistent with the M-Pesa fee schedule and the data we have on the distribution of withdrawals, implies that a household that makes monthly withdrawals is discounting future cash flows at a rate of at least 2.6 percent per month (36 percent per year). From these data it seems reasonable to conclude that a significant fraction of withdrawals are made by people who are applying high time discount rates, since otherwise they would be grouping their withdrawals into more economical chunks.  It is important to note that the high financial discount rates that households apply to cash that moves through M-Pesa do not necessarily imply that households highly discount the future consumption flows or utility. As in a standard Baumol-Tobin model of cash management, another reason to hold small cash balances is if there is a high cost of holding cash itself. Such a cost could be due to theft in a conventional sense, which can be viewed as a tax on cash balances. However, crime rates would have to be extremely high to justify the behavior we see. A more likely cost of holding cash is the high implicit tax represented by the ability of other family members to request either gifts or loans from one’s available cash balances. This notion is supported by Ashraf (2009), who reports that women in Kenya often form secret saving societies to hide income from their husbands. Finally, and somewhat similarly, holdings of cash may simply raise temptations to spend that individuals find impossible to resist. The inability to save cash-holdings has been shown to be a constraint to fertilizer adoption in Western Kenya (Duflo, Kremer, and Robinson 2011) and promotes participation in ROSCAS which can act as a commitment saving device (Gugerty 2007).  It could be that the extra transaction costs associated with

374

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS

holding small cash balances are a price worth paying to avoid giving in to these temptations. Another possibility is that individuals were just getting used to the pricing structure and would learn how to optimize their use of M-Pesa over time. Data from Jack and Suri (2012) show that in 2008, 56 percent of users who received an M-Pesa transfer withdrew the funds immediately, compared to just 21 percent in 2011. REFERENCES Ashraf, Nava. 2009. “Spousal Control and Intra-

household Decision Making: An Experimental Study in the Philippines.” American Economic Review 99 (4): 1245–77. Central Bank of Kenya. 2011. Statistical Bulletin, December 2011. Duflo, Esther, Michael Kremer, and Jonathan Robinson. 2011. “Nudging Farmers to Use

Fertilizer: Theory and Experimental Evidence from Kenya.” American Economic Review 101 (6): 2350–90. Eijkman, Frederik, Jake Kendall, and Ignacio Mas. 2010. “Bridges to Cash: The Retail End

of M-PESA.” Unpublished. Gugerty, Mary Kay. 2007. “You Can’t Save Alone:

Commitment in Rotating Savings and Credit

MAY 2013

Associations in Kenya.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 55 (2): 251–82. Jack, William, and Tavneet Suri. 2011. “Mobile Money: The Economics of M-PESA.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 16721. Jack, William, and Tavneet Suri. 2012. “The Economics of M-PESA: Round 4 Update.” Unpublished. Kimenyi, Mwangi S., and Njuguna S. Ndung’u.

2009. “Expanding the Financial Services Frontier: Lessons from Mobile Phone Banking in Kenya.” Brookings Institution, October 16. Mas, Ignacio, and Amolo Ng’weno. 2010. “Three Keys to M-PESA’s Success: Branding, Channel Management, and Pricing.” Journal of Payments, Strategy, and Systems 4 (4). Mbiti, Isaac, and David N. Weil. 2011. “Mobile Banking: The Impact of M-PESA in Kenya, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 17129. Slemrod, Joel. 2010. “Buenas Notches: Lines and Notches in Tax System Design.” Unpublished. Weil, David N., Isaac Mbiti, and Francis Mwega.

2011. “The Implications of Innovations in the Financial Sector on the Conduct of Monetary Policy in East Africa.” Report submitted to the International Growth Centre Tanzania Country Programme.

The Home Economics of E-Money: Velocity, Cash ...

earn interest on balances and also obtain small loans through its partner ... City stores did a more balanced business, though with an ... the number of agents monthly from April 2007 through ... borhood of Ksh 800, although they fell by about.

71KB Sizes 3 Downloads 228 Views

Recommend Documents

Cash Home Buyers.pdf
Property buyers exist to solve your home selling need. They will give you a free. offer for your house, and if you accept, you can move on with your life. Can you trust a local property buyer? With the recent slow down in the real estate market acros

Florida Cash Home Buyers.pdf
#2 Lifestyle ​allure ​of ​sun, ​sea, ​and ​sand. Not ​only ​does ​investment ​fundamentals ​look ​good ​in ​Florida, ​but ​its ​outstanding ​lifestyle. highly ​appeals ​to ​Chinese ​buyers ​as ​well. 54

Fast Cash Work At Home System.pdf
This system reveals exactly how to dominate any niche market and will become. your foundation for success. Do you believe it's possible? Do you think you can actually make money online if someone showed you step by. Page 3 of 8. Fast Cash Work At Hom

Measurement of the Laboratory's Absolute Velocity
LABORATORY "S ABSOLUTE VELO 3 Iry SQ the position RM (RM) ..... figures in equation (13)], we shall obtain the rotational velocity of our galaxy-. Let us now ...

Prediction of the droplet size and velocity joint ... - Semantic Scholar
for better energy efficiencies on thermal equipment, created a growing interest ...... of the International Conference on Mechanics of Two Phase Flows,. 1989. p.

HOME ECONOMICS CURRICULUM MAP.pdf
HOME ECONOMICS CURRICULUM MAP.pdf. HOME ECONOMICS CURRICULUM MAP.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying HOME ...

Behavioural and Experimental Economics Home ...
Dec 9, 2017 - Home Assignment #2. Solutions. Format: Electronic. Please send your solutions to the following email address: [email protected]. Word or PDF files are accepted, as well as good quality scans, but not photos. Deadline: 20 December,

Direct mapping of the temperature and velocity gradients in discs ...
(2017) recently intro- duced a method to map the thermal and density gas structure of ...... We use the Monte Carlo radiative transfer code MCFOST. (Pinte et al.

the velocity of light is direction dependent
For the sake of simplicity and better visualization, we shall perform the .... If one puts the "coupled-mirrors" apparatus on a rotating platform, then one has.

Evaluating the Effects of Inundation Duration and Velocity on ...
Duration and Velocity on Selection of ... and Velocity on Selection of Flood Management ... Drive, Box 5015, Cookeville, TN 38505-0001, USA ... Effects of Inundation Duration and Veloc ... t Alternatives Using Multi-Criteria Decision Making.pdf.

Derivation of the velocity divergence constraint for low ...
Nov 6, 2007 - Email: [email protected]. NIST Technical ... constraint from the continuity equation, which now considers a bulk source of mass. We.

velocity 2 -
Page 1. VELOCITY 2. (VELOCITY TOO) in their final Bay Area concert. A freewill offering will be taken. May 31, 2015 — 4 p.m.. First Covenant Church. 4000 Redwood Road. Oakland, California.

velocity variance
Dec 2, 1986 - compute both the friction velocity and surface heat flux from the surface-layer wind. profiles alone, using the method suggested by Klug (1967). For the convective AB L, the surface heat flux can also be computed from just the surfac

EXTERIOR OF HOME INTERIOR OF HOME
New Hydro Seed lawn w / sprinklers per sq/ft. $0.60. 810.00 .... Repair window rollers and latch per each. $15.00. 0.00. 0 ... TV & Phone. Per Bid. 0. #DIV/0! 10.

cash balance - Kravitz Cash Balance Design
Small and mid-size businesses are driving Cash Balance growth: 87% of ... Cash Balance Plans: Company Contributions to Employee Retirement Accounts. 7 ..... program that will achieve the plan sponsor's goals while passing all IRS tests ...

Philosophy of Economics The philosophy of economics concerns itself ...
Does economic theory purport to offer abstract theories of real social processes—their ... on the part of the philosopher about the “best practice,” contemporary debates, and .... management, and enjoyment of resources; the deployment and ... f

Ebook Read Economics of Growth (The Economics of ...
students, and as a reference for professional economists in government or international financial organizations. ... Time Series and Panel Data Econometrics.

The Importance of Internationalization at Home tion at Home
grams to top-ranked host universities. ... cess—on top-ranked universities, while collaborating with ... curriculum development and content that engages with.

Velocity Summer Trip_Info.pdf
Croatia. This will truly be a great holiday to remember. KEY INFO. Dates: Monday, 17 ... town of Split (rooms of approximately 5, ... Velocity Summer Trip_Info.pdf.

ENHANCING THE ECONOMICS OF COMMUNICATIONS ...
ket studies and “best guess” extrapolations of current demand. The two quantities that have ..... S represents the current stock price, Γ is a random variable with a ...

Unified formulation of velocity fields for streamline ...
Dec 20, 2005 - flux reconstruction step to obtain continuous velocity fields. Shortcomings ... The velocity field is mapped from the real space to a reference ...

Quasi-static and low-velocity impact failure of ...
University, Singapore. The manuscript was received on 16 March 2006 and was accepted after revision for publication on 9 May 2006. DOI: 10.1243/14644207JMDA98. Abstract: This article presents an extensive experimental and numerical investigation of a

[Ebook] pdf The Curse of Cash AUDIO "BOOKS
The Great Convergence: Information Technology and the New Globalization · The End of Theory: Financial Crises, the Failure of Economics, and the Sweep of ...