TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE∗ Matthias Meier† March 9, 2018

Abstract Investment is central for business cycles and a defining characteristic of investment goods is time to build. This paper establishes a new stylized fact: time to build is volatile and longest during recessions. Motivated by this finding, I study the business cycle implications of time to build fluctuations that are driven by disruptions in the supply chain of capital good producers. At the firm level, I show that disruptions lengthen time to build. At the macro level, innovations to time to build foreshadow large contractions in macroeconomic aggregates and productivity. Toward explaining these findings, I show that capital misallocation is a quantitatively potent mechanism for the transmission of time to build fluctuations. I embed this mechanism in a general equilibrium model with heterogeneous producers, in which supply chain disruptions lengthen time to build. Calibrated to US micro data, disruptions that lengthen time to build by one month, lower GDP by one percent. JEL classification: C32, C68, D92, E01, E22, E32. Keywords: Time to Build, Supply Chain Disruptions, Business Cycles, Investment, Misallocation.



I am extremely thankful to my advisors Christian Bayer and Keith Kuester for their continuous guidance and support. I wish to convey special thanks to Gianluca Violante for conversations on this project and for facilitating my visits at NYU. I thank Benjamin Born, Katka Borovičkovà, Jarda Borovička, Daniel Greenwald, Boyan Jovanovic, Greg Kaplan, Moritz Kuhn, Ben Moll, Morten Ravn, Markus Riegler, Felipe Valencia, Venky Venkateswaran, and Jürgen von Hagen, and numerous seminar participants for useful comments at various stages of this project. Financial support from the Bonn Graduate School of Economics, the Institute for Macroeconomics and Econometrics, the Institute for International Economic Policy, both University of Bonn, and the UniCredit & Universities Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. † University of Mannheim, Department of Economics, Block L7, 3-5, 68161 Mannheim, Germany; E-mail: [email protected].

1

2

MATTHIAS MEIER

1. INTRODUCTION Capital goods are complex and manufactured to the specific needs of investing firms. An assembly line, for example, consists of many elements that need to fit together; think of conveyor belts, robotic arms working along these belts, and the concrete foundation that supports the machines. Together, complexity and specificity result in a lag between the time, when orders for investment goods are placed, and the time of their delivery.1 This delivery lag, commonly referred to as time to build, is assumed constant in modern business cycle theory.2 This paper makes three contributions to the literature: First, I establish a stylized fact: time to build is counteryclical. Second, I provide micro evidence that disruptions in the capital supply chain lengthen time to build, and macro evidence that time to build innovations foreshadow sizable macroeconomic contractions. Third, I develop a macroeconomic model with firm heterogeneity in which supply chain disruptions lengthen time to build. Calibrated to micro data, I show that disruptions are quantitatively important for business cycle fluctuations. To measure time to build, I use aggregate and firm-level data on the value of equipment capital good producers’ order backlog, i.e., unfilled orders, from 1970 until 2016. I estimate time to build as the duration that new orders for capital goods remain unfilled in the order books of capital good producers. I document that time to build exhibits substantial variation between few months and more than a year. Importantly, time to build tends to be longest at the end of recessions. This finding is robust across two different datasets and various other dimensions. The empirical finding provokes the question what drives time to build. Considering time to build as market equilibrating mechanism, see Carlton (1979, 1983), both changes in supply and demand affect time to build. In this paper, I focus on disruptions to the supply chain of capital good producers as driver of time to build.Using firm-level data, I show that time to build of those firms lengthens, that have a supplier located in a county hit by a natural disaster. Beyond hurricanes and earthquakes, sources of supply chain disruptions are supplier defaults and adverse changes in supply chain finance. I provide firm-level evidence suggesting that access to trade credit is important for time to build fluctuations. 1

Relatedly, Belsley (1969) observes that investment goods are produced to order – a reflection of specificity – whereas consumption goods are typically produced to stock. 2 Kydland and Prescott (1982) assumes four quarters time to build, but the standard assumption in quickly shifted to one quarter, see, for example, Prescott (1986) and Smets and Wouters (2007).

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

3

To gauge the empirical relevance of the observed fluctuations in time to build for business cycles, I fit a vector autoregressive model to US data. I show that orthogonalized time to build innovations that lengthen time to build by one month lower GDP by 2%, investment by 6%, and productivity by 0.5%. Time to build innovations account for more than 20% of the forecast error variance of GDP and almost 50% of time to build. While these results are not necessarily causal, one interpretation of our micro and macro evidence is that supply chain disruptions, through their effects on time to build, have important macroeconomic impact. In the theory I propose, it is due to two channels that supply chain disruptions are contractionary. First, later delivery of outstanding orders, as follows from longer time to build, reduces current investment and thus production. Second, longer time to build worsens the allocation of capital across firms. While the efficient allocation dictates that more productive firms use more capital, longer time to build weakens the productivity-capital alignment. At the core of the mechanism, later delivery of a capital good increases the ex-ante uncertainty about productivity in the usage period of the ordered capital good. In turn, firms invest less frequently and, if they invest, their investment tends to be further away from optimal once it arrives. A lengthening of time to build therefore means capital is more misallocated across firms. Therefore aggregate productivity falls, which reflects the time series evidence, and so do output, investment, and consumption. As intermediate step before the full model, I suggest an analytic framework that permits introspection of the misallocation channel and its quantitative bite. The full model I develop is a real business cycle model. Households consume and supply labor. The model distinguishes between firms that supply capital and firms that demand capital. On the demand side, firms produce consumption goods by combining labor and specific capital. To invest in specific capital, they sign an order contract with an engineering firm. The engineering firm devises a blueprint for the investment project and searches for suppliers of the required intermediate goods. After the engineering firm matches with a supplier, ordered capital goods are produced and delivered. Supply chain disruptions are modeled as shocks to the matching technology, which cause fluctuations in time to build. In addition to the time to build friction, investment is partially irreversible, which gives rise to waitand-see behavior, and allows the model to match the micro-level evidence on lumpy investment. To evaluate the quantitative importance of capital supply chain disruptions, I

4

MATTHIAS MEIER

calibrate the model to US data. The strategy is to jointly target moments of the investment rate distribution and aggregate fluctuations in time to build. In the calibrated model, disruption shocks that raise time to build by one month cause a sharp 8% drop in investment and a more persistent drop in output of up to 1%. I show that the direct effects of later delivery are important for the short-term responses while increased capital misallocation explain about half of the mediumterm responses. To investigate the potential role of time to build in historical business cycles, I suppose all time to build variation in the data is explained by disruptions. This allows me to back out a series of disruption shocks from the calibrated model. I then compute the evolution of GDP under the shock series and absent other aggregate shocks. I find that supply chain disruptions explain about half of the decline in output and investment during the early 1990s recession and the Great Recession. Related Literature The notion, that time is a factor in the production of capital goods, has deep roots in the history of economic research. Early treatments include the seminal Ricardo (1817) and von Böhm-Bawerk (1891). Despite time to build being a familiar notion to economists, whether or not it fluctuates along the cycle is not well established. For nonresidential construction, Brooks (2000) uses news articles to estimate time to build and finds no cyclical pattern. The bulk of non-residential investment, however, is in equipment capital. For residential construction, Oh and Yoon (2016) documents countercyclical time to build. Kalouptsidi (2014) documents procyclical time to build for the global shipbuilding industry. Going back in time, Zarnowitz (1962) finds that time to build is procyclical from 1946 until 1959. An explanation may be abnormal demand during the Korean War and the subsequent capital goods boom, see Popkin (1965). Most related, Nalewaik and Pinto (2015) uses aggregate data to document countercylical delivery lags. My paper reconfirms their finding and puts it on a broader empirical basis. I address concerns of compositional effects and document countercyclical time to build at the firm level and the two-digit industry level. A second strand of related literature is the recently emerging research on the role of input-output linkages for the propagation of shocks, see, e.g., Acemoglu et al. (2012), Bigio and La’O (2016), and Baqaee (2016). Closely related to the present paper are Barrot and Sauvagnat (2016), Carvalho et al. (2016), and Boehm et al. (2015), who study the propagation of natural disasters through production

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

5

networks. Whereas theses papers study firms’ sales responses, another consequence of natural disasters are time delays, see Hicks (1970) for a related discussion. I contribute to this literature by showing that upstream disruptions through local natural disasters lengthen time to build. In addition, my quantitative model suggests that the indirect effects of longer time to build, through capital misallocation, are as important as the direct quantity effects. My paper’s evidence on trade credit conditions and fluctuations in time to build relates to a literature on trade finance in supply chains, see, e.g., Boissay and Gropp (2013), Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2014), and Jacobson and von Schedvin (2015). This paper further relates to a series of papers that have shown that investment-specific shocks are of central importance to aggregate fluctuations, see, e.g., Fisher (2006) and Justiniano et al. (2010). A third related strand of literature is on capital misallocation. By endogenously reducing TFP, capital misallocation may play a central role for the transmission of shocks that alter firms’ investment policies; for aggregate productivity shocks, see, e.g., Khan and Thomas (2008) and Bachmann et al. (2013), for financial shocks, see, e.g., Khan and Thomas (2013), and for uncertainty shocks, see, e.g., Bloom (2009). In my model, the transmission mechanism of supply chain disruptions shares the real options effect prominent in the uncertainty literature, see, e.g., Bloom (2009). While longer time to build induces a real option effect, it does not induce the volatility effect that higher uncertainty eventually realizes, which may lead to quick reversals and overshooting. To the extent that longer time to build increases the effective forecast uncertainty, this paper also contributes to the endogenous uncertainty literature, see Bachmann and Moscarini (2011) and Fajgelbaum et al. (2014). On the empirical side, Eisfeldt and Rampini (2006) and Gopinath et al. (2017) provide evidence that capital becomes more misallocated during recessions. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 documents time to build fluctuations and provides VAR evidence. Section 3 discusses the capital misallocation channel of time to build and Section 4 develops the quantitative business cycle model. I discuss the calibration in Section 5 and results in Section 6. Finally, Section 7 concludes and an Appendix follows.

6

MATTHIAS MEIER

2. CYCLICAL FLUCTUATIONS IN TIME TO BUILD 2.1. Measuring time to build To measure time to build I use data on the order books of capital good producers. I show that time to build exhibits substantial variation between less than three months and more than a year. Time to build peaks during recessions and is countercyclical. I use both aggregate (sector-level) and firm-level data on capital good producers’ order backlog, i.e., the the stock of unfilled orders, and sales. Aggregate data from 1968 through 2015 at monthly frequency is obtained from the US Census Manufacturers’ Shipments, Inventories, and Orders Survey (M3).3 M3 data is widely used. This includes the Bureau of Economic Analysis’ practice to compute quarterly investment from M3 sales of capital goods.4 In addition, I use annual Compustat balance sheet data of publicly listed US firms. Since 1970, SEC regulation requires public companies to disclose order backlog with their annual 10-K filings.5 Compustat data on order backlogs is used to predict a firm’s future performance, both by financial analysts and in academic research, see, e.g., Lev and Thiagarajan (1993). Let St denote the flow value of sales during period t, and Bt the beginning-ofperiod t stock of order backlog. My baseline measure of time to build is (2.1)

T T Btbacklog

ratio



Bt . St

This ratio, often referred to as backlog ratio, has been used to estimate delivery lags, see, e.g. Holt et al. (1960), Zarnowitz (1962). Under which conditions does the backlog ratio equal time to build? Let me assume that orders are filled first-in-first-out. Without observing individual orders, this is the most reasonable simplification on the order filling protocol I can make. Second, let me abstract from changes in the sales composition of capital goods with different time to build. I will revisit such changes further below in this subsection. Now, in static equilibrium, the backlog ratio exactly equals time to build, i.e., the time until a new order is filled. Deviating from equilibrium, the backlog ratio measures the expected time to build if sales, i.e. the rate at which unfilled orders are filled, 3 A new order is a legally binding intention to buy for immediate or future delivery. Order backlog is the value of orders that have not yet fully passed through the sales account. The order backlog is adjusted for cancellations and price renegotions. 4 See Concepts and Methods of the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts (2014, ch. 3). 5 See SEC regulation §229 item 101(c) (VIII).

7

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

follows a unit root process. The latter is approximately satisfied in the data.6 An alternative measure for time to build, which captures ex-post time to build, as implied by future realized sales, is (

(2.2)

T T Btrealized

sales



number of months of realized future sales until Bt is depleted (interpolating between months)

)

.

The upper of Figure 1 shows the evolution of time to build constructed for the non-defense equipment goods sector from Census M3 data. Time to build fluctuates between three and ten months. Importantly, time to build tends to start increasing before recessions and peaks at the end of recession periods. The correlation of quarterly real GDP growth with log time to build is -0.28 and -0.33 for the two measures, respectively. This finding reconfirms Nalewaik and Pinto (2015). Note that the two time to build series overlap for most of the sample. This in turn reflects the high persistence in monthly sales.7 I further use M3 data to construct time to build at the level of four broad sub-sectors within the equipment good sector.8 Figure 6 in the Appendix shows that industry-level time to build, abstracting from slow-moving sector-specific trends, is countercyclical, too. Thus the aggregate result appears not to be driven by cyclical shifts between broad categories of capital goods. Firm-level data on order backlogs is only available at annual frequency, thus I exclusively use the backlog ratio. I drop firm-year observations with negative sales and sales growth below -50% and above 100%. The firm-level backlog ratio is winsorized at the upper 98th percentile. Note that the aggregate backlog ratio is equal to the weighted mean of firm-level backlog ratios Bt X Bit wit = , St Sit i if weights are firm-level sales shares, wit = Sit /

P

i Sit .

The lower panel of Figure 1

shows the evolution of cross-sectional mean and the median of time to build computed weighted by sales. Both series are countercyclical and fluctuate substantially, and at magnitudes similar to the aggregate data. Not only the average, but also the dispersion of firm-level time to build is countercyclical, see Figure 7 in the appendix. 6

At monthly frequency, the estimated persistence of time to build in the data is 99.5%. Figure 5 in the appendix plots the time series for order backlog, sales, and new orders. 8 As a note of caution, for more disaggregated two-digit equipment goods sectors, the distinction between defense and non-defense goods is not always available. 7

8

MATTHIAS MEIER

Figure 1: Time to build

10

Months

2

4

6

8

Backlog ratio Realized sales

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

(a) Aggregate data (Census M3)

15

Months

0

5

10

Mean Median

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

(b) Firm-level data (Compustat) Notes: In panel (a), the solid line is time to build measured using the ratio of aggregate order backlog to aggregate monthly shipments, for non-defense equipment goods. The dashed line is time to build measured when counting the number of months of future realizations of sales are required to deplete the current stock of unfilled orders. In panel (b), the solid (dashed) line show the mean (median) of time to build measured as the ratio of order backlog to annual sales, multiplied by 12, and weighted by firm-level sales. Shaded, gray areas indicate NBER recession dates.

9

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

Let me finally revisit the concern that fluctuations in time to build may be driven by changes in the sales composition. Changes in aggregate time to build can be decomposed into changes in firm-level time to build and changes in the sales shares Bit Bit−1 Bt Bt−1 X − = wit − St St−1 Sit Sit−1 i 



+

X

(wit − wit−1 )

i

Bit , Sit

where i denotes a firm, and wit is the firm-level share in aggregate period t sales. A variance decomposition reveals that changes in firm-level time to build account for 83% of the variance of changes in the aggregate backlog ratio. Changes in the sales composition account for another 17% and the two terms are practically uncorrelated. Thus, the concern seems to be of minor relevance. 2.2. Effects of supply chain disruptions One explanation for fluctuations in time to build are disruptions in the supply chain of capital good producers. I provide empirical evidence that causally identifies this link. Further, I provide suggestive evidence that changes in firms’ access to supply chain finance may be important supply chain disruptions. To identify the impact of supply chain disruptions on time to build, I exploit county-level natural disasters as provided by the SHELDUS database. I restrict attention to economically relevant disasters, defined by a minimum economic damage of 1 billion 2013 constant USD. In total, 41 such major disasters occurred between 1978 through 2013. I link disasters to firms through the county location of firms’ headquarters. Further, I exploit self-reported information from the Compustat Segment files on firms’ principal customers from 1978 through 2013.9 Restricting attention to capital good producing firms (SIC codes 35, 36, 37, 38), the combined data allows me to study whether shocks, that hit suppliers of capital good producers, disrupt supply chains to the extent that time to build of affected firms lengthens. The estimation strategy described here mimics Barrot and Sauvagnat (2016) and I refer the interested reader to their paper for a more detailed description of the natural disaster data and of supplier-customer links in Compustat data. The key difference vis-á-vis Barrot and Sauvagnat (2016) is that I study the effect on time to build (of capital good producers) instead of the response in sales growth (of all firms). The effective sample in my analysis differs for two reasons: First, 9

Compustat data on principal customer has also been used, e.g., in Cohen and Frazzini (2008) and Atalay et al. (2011).

10

MATTHIAS MEIER

I restrict attention to the response of capital good producers. Second, instead of quarterly data for sales, time to build can only be measured at annual frequency. The extent to which time to build lengthens depends on (a) the amount of inventory of the respective supplier’s goods before the disaster, and (b) how easily capital good producers can substitute the respective input by another one.10 TABLE I Disruptions in the supply chain of capital producers and time to build

log(Time to Build) Disaster hits firm Disaster hits supplier

0.105∗ (0,055) 0.118∗∗∗ (0,042)

0.108∗∗ (0,054) 0.115∗∗∗ (0,043) -0.292∗∗∗ (0.081)

Trade credit Number of suppliers Firm fixed effect Year fixed effect Observations R2

No Yes Yes 1,445 0.257

Yes Yes Yes 1,445 0.262

No Yes Yes 30,217 0.154

Notes: This table presents estimates from panel regressions of capital good firms’ time to build (backlog ratio) on a dummy indicating whether (at least) one of their suppliers is hit by a major disaster. For the list of major disasters see Barrot and Sauvagnat (2016). All regressions include a dummy indicating whether the firm itself is hit by a major disaster, year, and firm fixed effects. In the second column, I control for the number of suppliers (dummies indicating terciles of the number of suppliers). In the third column, I present the estimate of trade credit (the ratio of accounts payable to total assets) on time to build. The regressions contain all firm-year observations for which information time to build and supply chain links is available (first two columns) and for which time to build and accounts payable and total assets are available (third column). Standard errors presented in parentheses and are clustered at the firm level. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

The first two columns of Table I show the effects of natural disasters. I find that capital good producers in counties that are hit by a natural disaster have 10% longer time to build when controlling for firm and year fixed effects. The key result, 10

The results in Barrot and Sauvagnat (2016) strongly suggest that inputs from one supplier (hit by a shock) cannot be easily substituted by inputs from another supplier (not hit by a shock).

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

11

however, is that natural disaster that hit suppliers significantly disrupt the supply chain of capital good producers. As a result time to build lengthens by 11%. This result contributes to the literature by establishing that not only quantities (sales) are diminished when supply chains are disrupted. It is also the case that capital good producers’ order backlog does not fall by the same extent as sales falls, which implies orders remain backlogged for longer, and thus delivery is delayed. In an attempt to understand firm-level fluctuations in time to build beyond natural disasters, I provide evidence on the role of supply chain finance. Building on a literature that studies the propagation of default through trade credit networks, see, e.g. Boissay and Gropp (2013) and Jacobson and von Schedvin (2015), I study the effect of changes in trade credit on time to build. My measure of trade credit is the share of accounts payable of total assets. I find that decreases in the usage of trade credit by capital good producers are associated with large increases in time to build. Although this is reduced-form evidence, one plausible interpretation is that changes in the access to trade credit lead to substantial delays in production.

2.3. Aggregate implications The evolution of aggregate time to build may reflect a plethora of macroeconomic shocks, in particular any shock that affects capital demand or supply. The focus of my paper is on the role of capital supply shocks, more specifically, capital supply chain disruptions. To gauge the effects of such disruptions, I fit a medium-scale, eight-variable VAR model. The series included are: time to build, real GDP, real consumption, real investment, consumer price, real wage, federal funds rate, and total factor productivity. The model allows for rich dynamic interactions between time to build and several macroeconomic series, prominent in both structural and empirical business cycle models, see, e.g., Christiano et al. (1999). I use data at quarterly frequency that covers 1968Q1 through 2014Q4. Total factor productivity is from Fernald (2014) and the remaining macroeconomic series are sourced from FRED.11 All variables but the federal funds rate are transformed by the natural logarithm. Notice that I use non-durable consumption goods, because durable consumption goods include equipment goods that time to build shocks may 11

The FRED series names are GDPC96 (Real GDP), DNDGRA3Q086SBEA (Real Personal Consumption Expenditures: Nondurable goods), B008RA3Q086SBEA (Real Private Fixed Investment: Nonresidential), CPI, AHETPI/CPI (Average Hourly Earnings of Production and Nonsupervisory Employees: Total Private; deflated by CPI ), FEDFUNDS (Effective Federal Funds Rate).

12

MATTHIAS MEIER

directly affect. Similarly, my preferred investment time series is nonresidential investments because only firms invest in my model. The results are robust against using total consumption and total investment instead. The baseline structural VAR model is estimated in levels with four lags and linear time trend. The baseline identification assumption is a recursive one: time to build increases in response to a capital supply chain disruptions while all other macroeconomic time series do respond only with a one-quarter lag. Figure 2 shows the impulse responses to a supply chain disruption that raises time to build by one month at peak. The shock has a persistent, significant effect on time to build. More interestingly, GDP, investment, and consumption significantly fall in response to a disruption. Not only are the responses statistically significant, but their magnitudes are also economically relevant: GDP and consumption fall by up to 2%, and investment by up to 6% within the first three years. Figure 2: Impulse responses to a one month capital supply chain disruption Time to build (in months)

GDP (in %)

7

1

6.5

0 -1

6 -2 5.5

-3

5

-4 0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0

Investment (in %)

4

8

12

16

20

24

Consumption (in %)

2

1

0

0

-2

-1

-4 -2

-6

-3

-8 -10

-4 0

4

8

12

16

Quarters

20

24

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

Quarters

Notes: Solid, blue lines show (selected) responses to a capital supply chain disruption, under the baseline identification scheme. Shaded, gray areas illustrate the associated 90% confidence intervals.

Complementary to IRF analysis, Table II shows the shares of forecast error variance explained by capital supply chain disruptions. Disruptions explain an important fraction of macroeconomic fluctuations: more than 20% of GDP and consumption,

13

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

and 7% of investment. This provides further evidence in support of this paper’s suggestion that capital supply chain disruption are crucial for a better understanding of business cycle fluctuations. Importantly, at business cycle frequency disruptions explain almost 50% of the forecast error variance of time to build itself. That is, other structural shocks explain only 50%. This further motivates my modeling choice in Section 4, in which I focus on the effects of capital supply chain disruption, instead of conventional business cycle shocks, such as a shock in aggregate productivity. TABLE II Forecast error variance decomposition

GDP Investment Consumption Time to build

1 year

2 years

3 years

4 years

5 years



0.2 0.3 0.8 73.4

7.6 0.9 9.8 57.0

18.1 2.8 22.2 48.8

22.6 4.9 26.9 44.8

23.4 6.6 28.2 42.2

18.2 6.7 24.6 31.1

Note: The shares of forecast error variance explained by capital supply chain disruptions are expressed as percentages for different forecast horizons ranging from 1 year to infinity.

Appendix B provides robustness on the VAR results. First, I examine robustness to the baseline model specification in levels with linear time trend. I show that the results are broadly robust when estimating the VAR in first differences. GDP, investment, and consumption respond significantly and with similar magnitude to a disruption shock. Second, I study an alternative identification scheme, in which capital supply chain disruptions can affect all variables contemporaneously, but no other structural shock can affect time to build contemporaneously. While the responses to a disruption tend to be larger under this alternative scheme, the differences are small. Third, using the methodology developed in Gafarov, Meier, and Montiel Olea (2016), I replace zero restrictions with elasticity bounds. Instead of contemporaneous zero restrictions as in the baseline scheme, I constrain the elasticity of the contemporaneous response to a disruption of variables other than time to build to be bounded by ±1%. I show that my baseline results remain significant under such relaxation. Fourth, I show that the identified capital supply chain disruption do not mistakenly capture other structural shocks. Beyond the robustness in Appendix B, the results are also robust against estimating a monthly VAR, in which I replace GDP by IP and investment by new orders for non-defense capital goods. Further, the results are robust against dropping the Great Recession period.

14

MATTHIAS MEIER

3. CAPITAL MISALLOCATION This section discusses a novel, and quantitatively important, mechanism. In short, firms facing longer time to build have (ex-ante) less information about the profitability of an investment project. In turn, capital becomes more misallocated when time to build lengthens, which depresses real economic activity.

3.1. Analytical introspection of mechanism To introspect capital misallocation as mechanism for time to build fluctuations, I introduce a stylized model economy, which permits analytical solution. The economy consists of a fixed unit mass of perfectly competitive firms, indexed by j, that produce a homogeneous consumption good (3.1)

α ν yjt = xjt kjt `jt ,

using firm-specific capital, kjt , labor, `jt , and with decreasing returns to scale, 0 < α + ν < 1. Idiosyncratic productivity, xjt , follows an AR(1) process in logs (3.2)

log(xjt+1 ) = ρx log(xjt ) + σx jt+1 ,

0 ≤ ρx ≤ 1,

iid

jt+1 ∼ N (0, 1).

I denote by wt the wage rate and by rt the user cost of capital. Labor is adjusted every period to maximize profits (3.3)

α ν πjt = xjt kjt `jt − wt `jt − rt kjt .

For analytical tractability, I assume that capital is adjusted subject to time to build and focus on the long-run effects of exogenous changes in time to build.12 The profit-maximizing capital policy of firm j in period t for period t + τ is (3.4)

1−ν

ν

1

1−ν

1−ν kj,t,t+τ = (α/rt ) 1−α−ν (ν/wt ) 1−α−ν E[xjt+τ |xjt ] 1−α−ν .

In words, kj,t,t+τ is the optimal capital policy subject to τ periods time to build. The aggregate capital stock used in period t + τ with τ periods time to build is Kt,t+τ = 12

R1 0

kj,t,t+τ dj, and aggregates Lt,t+τ , Yt,t+τ are computed analogously. Total

The main model of this paper, introduced in Section 4, extends this setup to allow for a richer set of adjustment frictions and studies the dynamic responses to supply chain disruptions.

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

15

factor productivity is defined as TFPt,t+τ ≡ log Yt,t+τ − α log Kt,t+τ − ν log Lt,t+τ . After some tedious derivations, provided in Appendix C, this simplifies to (3.5)

TFPτ =

1 1 1 α 1 − ρ2τ 1 x 2 σ − σ2 . 2 1 − α − ν 1 − ρ2x x 2 (1 − ν)(1 − ν − α) 1 − ρ2x x

Equation (3.5) shows that longer time to build (τ ) unambiguously lowers aggregate TFP, which is due to increased capital misallocation.13 The quantitative strength of the time to build-TFP nexus depends on three factors: a) If α increases, capital misallocation becomes more important for TFP. b) The closer technology gets to CRS (α + ν % 1), the more optimal firm size responds to productivity, amplifying the capital misallocation of time to build. c) The last term captures the conditional variance of productivity shocks while waiting for capital good delivery V[log xjt+τ | log xjt ] =

1 − ρ2τ x σ2 1 − ρ2x x

ρx →1

= τ σx2 ,

which drives capital misallocation and increases in ρx and σx . Further note that a capital-labor substitution elasticity below unity would strengthen the quantitative impact of time to build on TFP.14 3.2. Quantitative bite of mechanism To understand whether capital misallocation is quantitatively important for the transmission of time to build fluctuations, I need to attach values to α, ν, ρx , and σx . In the literature, a wide range of estimates exist and instead of focusing on a specific estimate, I review the literature. Estimates differ in the micro data employed, which implies differences in time period, frequency (quarterly or annual), unit of observation (plants or firms), and scope (public or private firms, manufacturing or all 13

In general equilibrium, wt and rt may be a function of τ . However, equilibrium prices shift input factors in equal proportion to output, thus TFP is not a function of equilibrium prices. 14 The empirical evidence surveyed in Chirinko (2008) centers around a capital-labor substition elasticity of about 0.5, substantially below unit elasticity as implied by Cobb-Douglas technology.

16

MATTHIAS MEIER

sectors). Further, the calibration or estimation strategy differs. One approach is to estimate all parameters directly from the micro data, another approach is indirect via targeting moments of the investment rate distribution. Table III summarizes prominent estimates in the literature, see the table notes for details. To make parameters of the productivity process comparable, I have imputed the parameters at quarterly frequency. Using equation (3.5), I compute the loss in aggregate TFP if time to build increases from five to six months. The TFP losses range from moderate 0.01% up to above 1%, and centered around quantitatively important TFP losses in between 0.2% and 0.3%. In other words, the capital misallocation mechanism clearly has quantitative bite.

TABLE III Lengthening in time to build from 5 to 6 months: aggregate TFP loss

Calibration

α

ν

ρx

σx

TFP loss

data source: annual manufacturing plant-level LRD data, 1972-1998

Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006) Khan and Thomas (2008) Khan and Thomas (2013)

0.235 0.256 0.270

0.604 0.640 0.600

0.970 0.963 0.901

0.062 0.012 0.068

0.21% 0.01% 0.30%

data source: annual manufacturing plant-level ASM/CMF data, 1972-2009

Kehrig (2015)

0.290

0.650

0.622

0.138

1.14%

0.900

0.150

0.23%

0.940

0.026

0.04%

data source: quarterly firm-level Compustat data, 1973-2012

Gilchrist et al. (2014)

0.255

0.595

data source: quarterly firm-level IRS data, 1997-2010

Winberry (2016a)

0.210

0.640

Notes: A period is a quarter and I increase τ from 5/3 to 6/3. Whenever the original calibration 1/4 is at annual frequency, I impute quarterly persistence ρx using ρx,annual , and quarterly dispersion σx accordingly. Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006) estimate the revenue production function yjt = θ x ˜jt kjt , and θ = α/(1 − ν) = 0.592 together with the labor cost share aL = ν/(α + ν) = 0.72 pins down α and ν. When considering the production function as maximizing out labor, xjt = x ˜1−ν jt , which allows me to impute σx . Khan and Thomas (2008) assume ν = 0.64 following Prescott (1986), and calibrate α = 0.256 to match an aggregate capital-to-output ratio of 2.3. They calibrate ρx and σx by targeting the share of LRD plants with (large) positive/negative investment or inaction. Khan and Thomas (2013) include as target the cross-sectional investment rate dispersion. Kehrig (2015) estimate all parameters from the data while including six-digit industry fixed effects. Gilchrist et al. (2014) assume a 30% capital cost share and estimate the remaining parameters from the data. Winberry (2016a) assumes ν = 0.64, α + ν = 0.85, and targets moments of the investment rate distribution to calibrate ρx and σx .

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

17

4. MODELING CYCLICAL FLUCTUATIONS IN TIME TO BUILD This section develops a model which extends the basic real business cycle model in two ways. First, producers of consumption goods vary in their productivity and use producer-specific capital. Second, investment is partially irreversible and specific capital are supplied by engineering firms, which require intermediate goods purchased on a frictional market. Disruptions to the supply chain of intermediate goods, modeled as shocks to the matching technology on the intermediate goods market, cause fluctuations in time to build. 4.1. Households Households value consumption and leisure. I assume the existence of a representative household with separable preferences (4.1)

U (Ct , Lt ) =

Ct1−σ − ψLt , 1−σ

where Ct is consumption and Lt labor supply in period t. I denote by σ the intertemporal substitution elasticity, ψ parametrizes the disutility of working. This period utility function is common in the related literature, see Khan and Thomas (2008) and Bloom et al. (2014) for example, and may be justified by indivisible labor, see Hansen (1985) and Rogerson (1988). The household owns all firms and receives aggregate profits denoted Πt . The problem of the household is (4.2)

max U (Ct , Lt ) s.t. Ct ≤ wt Lt + Πt ,

Ct ,Lt

where wt is the wage. Due to household ownership, firms discount future profits by (4.3)

Qt,t+1 = β

pt+1 , pt

where pt = Ct−σ denotes the marginal utility of consumption. 4.2. Engineering firms and intermediate good suppliers Producers of consumption goods invest in specific capital by signing an order contract with an engineering firm. Engineering firms devise a blueprint which describes the intermediate goods required for the specific capital good. The specific intermediate goods are purchased through a frictional market on which engineering firms

18

MATTHIAS MEIER

need to search for a matching supplier (think of a single supplier as shortcut for a network of suppliers). Once matched, I assume the engineering firm produces the ordered capital and delivers it at the end of the period. Formally, I assume a continuum of capital sub-markets exogenously differentiated by cost parameter ξ, with cdf G defined for support R+ . Consumption good producers randomly access a sub-market ξ. As will become clear later, this setup serves useful to introduce stochastic fixed capital adjustment costs. The remainder of this subsection focuses on an arbitrary submarket ξ. I assume a large mass of engineering firms (short: engineers) and intermediate good suppliers (short: suppliers). The mass of active engineers be Et , the mass of active suppliers be St . Formally, the matching technology between engineers and suppliers is (4.4)

Mt = mt Etη St1−η .

Stochastic matching efficiency mt follows an AR(1) process in logs (4.5)

log(mt ) = (1 − ρm ) log(µm ) + ρm log(mt−1 ) + σ m m t ,

iid

m t ∼ N (0, 1),

and captures capital supply chain disruptions, which drive time to build fluctuations. I define market tightness as θt = Et /St . The order filling probability for an engineer is qt = mt θtη−1 , and the matching probability for a supplier is θt qt . Once matched, the probability of match separation is exogenously given by χ. Suppliers and engineers need to hire ξ overhead workers to operate. Workers are mobile across sectors so equilibrium wages are equal across sectors. When matched for any given investment order, denoted it , a quantity it of intermediate goods is delivered to the engineer for unit price pSt . Suppliers transform consumption goods into intermediate goods with unit marginal costs. Given the stochastic discount factor in (4.3), the value of an unmatched and matched supplier is (4.6)

S VtS = −ξwt + θt qt JtS + (1 − θt qt )Et [Qt,t+1 Vt+1 ],

(4.7)

S JtS = pSt it − it + (1 − χ)Et [Qt,t+1 Jt+1 ],

respectively. The market for capital good orders is a competitive spot market, and engineers can perfectly commit to a capital good order contract. Further, a consumption good producer can only hire one engineering firm, thus the number of engineers equals the number of orders. Engineers receive price pE t per unit of capital

19

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

goods delivered. To produce capital, the engineer needs to find a matching supplier. The value of an unmatched and matched engineer is, (4.8)

E VtE = −ξwt + qt JtE + (1 − qt )Et [Qt,t+1 Vt+1 ],

(4.9)

S E JtE = pE t it − pt it + (1 − χ)Et [Qt,t+1 Jt+1 ],

respectively. In equilibrium, engineers make zero profits on the spot market for investment orders, and I assume that capital suppliers satisfy a free entry condition (4.10)

VtE = VtS = 0.

When matched, engineer and capital supplier split the match surplus by Nash bargaining over the unit price pSt , where φ is the engineer’s bargaining weight (4.11)

max(JtE − VtE )φ (JtS − VtS )1−φ . pS t

The two equations in (4.10) together with the solution to (4.11) jointly define the equilibrium values of θt , pSt , pE t . Assumption: Matches are formed for a single period, χ = 1. This assumption is technically convenient because any engineer without order contract is identical, i.e. unmatched. The assumption also follows directly from a strict notion of specific capital goods and intermediate goods. Conversely, under χ < 1 consumption good producers could hire a matched engineer to deliver next period using the same intermediate goods. Further, χ = 1 considerably simplifies equilibrium conditions. The solution to (4.11) is pSt = φ + (1 − φ)pE t and the price engineers receive is pE t = 1+

ξwt 1 φqt it .

Investment expenditures pE t it = it + ft consist

of a size-dependent component with unit price, and a fixed cost component (4.12)

ft =

ξwt . φqt

It further follows that equilibrium tightness is constant θ =

φ 1−φ .

Hence, supply

chain disruptions, i.e. lower matching efficiency mt , unambiguously lower delivery probability qt and thus lengthen average time to build.

20

MATTHIAS MEIER

4.3. Consumption good producers The consumption good producers in my model resemble the firms in Section 3. The economy is populated by a fixed unit mass of consumption good producers, indexed by j, that are perfectly competitive. Technology is DRS and combines labor and specific capital to produce a homogeneous consumption good (4.13)

α ν yjt = zt xjt kjt `jt ,

where zt denotes aggregate productivity, and xjt idiosyncratic productivity. Idiosyncratic productivity follows a log AR(1) process described by parameters ρx and σx . Aggregate productivity has a deterministic trend, and the model is formulated along the balanced growth path. Along the trend, zt follows a log AR(1) process described by ρz and σz . Productivity shocks are assumed to be independent of each other. Labor adjustment is frictionless and I define the gross cash flow as (4.14)

cfjt ≡ max

`jt ∈R+

n

o

α ν zt xjt kjt `jt − wt ljt .

Capital adjustment is not frictionless. Firm-specific capital evolves over time according to γkjt+1 = (1 − δ)kjt + ijt , where δ denotes the depreciation rate, ijt is investment, and γ denotes constant, aggregate growth of labor productivity. I assume three types of capital adjustment frictions. (1) To invest, consumption good producers need to sign a contract for quantity iojt of (ordered) investment goods with an engineer. The engineer produces specific capital using intermediate goods purchased from suppliers on a frictional market. As a result, investment orders are not delivered instantaneously, but with probability qt . Thus average time to build is 1/qt . I assume that re-adjusting an outstanding order before delivery is prohibitively costly. (2) Investment entails a fixed sunk cost, ft (ξjt ), which naturally arises from the setup of the capital supply side, see equation (4.12). The fixed cost is a function of capital sub-market ξ. Consumption good producers randomly draw ξjt every period, unless they have signed an order contract. Order contracts specify ξ. (3) I assume resale losses of capital, which reflects the notion of specific capital.15 The resale loss of divestment is captured by investment price function pi (io ), which equals 0 ≤ p¯i ≤ 1 if investment io < 0, and which equals one else. Total investment expenditure is 15

I assume reselling is also subject to time to build: Disinvesting producers need to hire an engineer that searches for a capital supplier that transforms the capital into consumption goods.

21

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

summarized by function ac (4.15)

act (iojt , ξjt ) = (1 − pi (iojt ))iojt + ft (ξjt ).

In the dynamic firm problem, I distinguish between consumer good producers with and without outstanding orders. The idiosyncratic state of firms without outstanding order is described by (kjt , xjt , ξjt ) with probability distribution µV defined for space S V = R+ × R+ × R+ . Firms with outstanding order have idiosyncratic state (kjt , iojt , xjt , ξjt ) with distribution µW defined for S W = R+ × R × R+ × R+ . The V W joint cross-sectional distribution is µt = (µVt , µW t ) defined for S = S × S . The

economy’s aggregate state is denoted by st = (µt , zt , mt ). In the following, I drop time and firm indices and use 0 notation to indicate subsequent periods. The value of a firm without outstanding order is given by V n

o

(4.16)

V (k, x, ξ, s) = max V O (k, x, ξ, s), V N O (k, x, s) ,

(4.17)

V N O (k, x, s) = cf (k, x, s) + E Q(s, s0 )V ((1 − δ)k/γ, x0 , ξ 0 , s0 ) x, k, s ,

(4.18)

V O (k, x, ξ, s) = max W (k, io , x, ξ, s) , o





n



o

i ∈R

where V N O is the value conditional on not ordering investment goods and V O is the firm value conditional on ordering io . The order is chosen to maximize the value of a firm with outstanding order, given by (4.19)

W (k, io , x, ξ, s) = cf (k, x, s) h

i

+ q(s) − ac(io , ξ, s) + E Q(s, s0 )V ((1 − δ)k + io )/γ, x0 , ξ 0 , s0 x, s 



h 

i

+ (1 − q(s)) E Q(s, s0 )W (1 − δ)k/γ, io /γ, x0 , ξ, s0 k, io , x, s . 

An outstanding order io is delivered with probability q. I assume that investment expenditures, ac, are payed upon delivery. This assumption is conservative. Discounting implies that under earlier payment, the cost of investment would increase in time to build, and thereby amplify the effects of supply chain disruptions. The extensive margin of the capital adjustment decision is described by the threshˆ x, s) that satisfies old value ξ(k, (4.20)

ˆ x, s), s) = V N A (k, x, s). V A (k, x, ξ(k,

22

MATTHIAS MEIER

ˆ x, s). Adjustment is optimal whenever fixed adjustment costs ξ < ξ(k, Note that my formulation of the firm problem nests the conventional firm problem with one period time to build whenever q(s) = 1 ∀s. 4.4. Recursive Competitive Equilibrium A recursive competitive equilibrium is a list of value functions (V, W, V S , J S , V E , J E ), ˆ prices (w, ps , pE , f ), market tightness (θ), and the policy functions (C, L, `, io , ξ), cross-sectional distribution (µ) that satisfy ˆ are (i) Consumption good producers: V and W solve (4.16)–(4.19) and (`, io , ξ) the associated policy functions. (ii) Engineers and suppliers: V S , J S , V E , J E solve (4.6)–(4.9). (iii) Households: C and L solve (4.2). (iv) Labor market clearing: Z

Z

`(k, x, s)dµ +

L(s) =

SV

S

1{ξ<ξ(k,x,s)} ξdµV + ˆ

Z

ξdµW

SW

where 1{·} equals one if · is true and zero otherwise. (v) Intermediate good market and capital good market clearing: Free entry and zero profit conditions (4.10) hold and pS is bargained according to (4.11). (vi) Consumption good market clearing: C(s) =Y (s) − I(s) Z

Y (s) =

zxk α `(k, x, s)ν dµ

ZS

I(s) = S VZ

1{ξ<ξ(k,x,s)} q(s)ac(io (k, x, s), ξ, s)dµV ˆ

+

q(s)ac(io , ξ, s)dµW .

SW

(vii) Consistency: The evolution of µ is consistent with policy functions. 4.5. Solution The recursive competitive equilibrium is not computable, because the solution depends on the infinite-dimensional distribution µ and its law of motion. Instead, I solve for an approximate equilibrium adopting the algorithm in Campbell (1998) and Reiter (2009) to my model. The general idea is to use global approximation

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

23

methods with respect to the individual states, but local approximation methods with respect to the aggregate states. I solve the steady state of my model using projection methods and perturb the model locally around the steady state to solve for the model dynamics in response to aggregate shocks. Compared to the Krusell-Smith algorithm, see Krusell et al. (1998), the perturbation approach does not require simulating the model dynamics in order to update the parameters of the forecasting rules. Further it can handle a large number of aggregate shocks. Terry (2015) compares the Krusell-Smith algorithm with the Campbell-Reiter algorithm for a Khan and Thomas (2008) economy. He finds that the Campbell-Reiter algorithm is more than 100 times faster. Ahn et al. (2016) combine the Campbell-Reiter algorithm to compute aggregate dynamics for a general class of heterogeneous agent economies in continuous time. More closely related to this paper, Winberry (2016a) uses (and extends) the Campbell-Reiter algorithm to solve a variation of the Khan and Thomas (2008) economy. In Appendix D, I show that equilibrium conditions can be simplified to reduce the idiosyncratic state space. I further explain in more detail the Campbell-Reiter algorithm applied to my model and contrast it with the Krusell-Smith algorithm, likewise applied to my model. Finally, I explain how the projection method is applied to the firm problem. 5. CALIBRATION The central mechanism for the transmission of supply chain disruptions is the allocation of capital across firms. At the core of my calibration strategy is to match salient features of establishment-level investment dynamics. While the establishmentlevel data is reported annually, the length of a period in the model should reflect the frequency at which economic agents make decisions, see Christiano and Eichenbaum (1987). I set the length of a period to a month. I set the discount factor β to match an annual risk-free rate of 4%. I assume logutility in consumption, σ = 1. The parameter governing the household’s disutility from work, ψ, is calibrated to match one third of time spent working. On the intermediate good markets, I assume symmetric Nash bargaining between engineers and suppliers, φ = 0.5.16 The delivery probability under φ = 0.5 is qt = mt , thus I do not need to calibrate matching function elasticity η. To calibrate mean, persistence, and 16

In fact, I can choose any φ ∈ (0, 1) without any impact on my results, as long as I re-calibrate µm to match average time to build.

24

MATTHIAS MEIER

variance of mt , I target the corresponding first and second moments of the empirical baseline measure of time to build. In the model, I compute time to build consistent with the data by using the backlog ratio. Investment corresponds to shipments and I compute aggregate order backlog according to Z

B(s) = SV

1{ξ<ξ(k,x,s)} ac(io (k, x, s), ξ, s)dµV + ˆ

Z

ac(io , ξ, s)dµW .

SW

I set the mean matching efficiency to match an average time to build of 5.5 months in line with the data. Given that the backlog ratio has a weak, non-linear time trend, I detrend the monthly time series using a low-frequency HP filter with λ = 8, 100, 000 and fit persistence and standard deviations to the cyclical component.17 To calibrate the parameters of the production technology, notably α ν, ρx , σx , I target moments from the manufacturing plant-level Longitudinal Research Database (LRD) based on Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006). For the details I refer to the notes of Table III. The calibrated parameter values are well within the range of estimates surveyed in Table III and imply moderate long-run losses in aggregate TFP. I calibrate δ to match an annual depreciation rate of 10% and γ to satisfy an annualized aggregate productivity growth of 1.6%, see Khan and Thomas (2008). I assume that G, the distribution fixed capital adjustment costs (ξ), is uniform ¯ To calibrate ξ¯ as well as resale losses p¯i , with zero lower bound and upper bound ξ. I target the share of plants with investment rates above 20% and below -20% in the data, respectively. For consistency with the calibration of pararmeters describing the productivity process, I use the share of spike investment rates as documented in Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006) based on the LRD. To account for differences in time frequency, I aggregate simulated data to annual frequency when computing investment spike shares. The two adjustment cost parameters allow me to match the observed 19% share of plants with positive spikes and the 2% share of negative spikes. The fixed cost is important to generate fat tails, while the resale loss is particularly important in generating the large difference between positive and negative spikes. Appendix E provides more details on the calibration and shows that the calibrated model closely matches several non-targeted moments. 17

The low-frequency HP filter, translated to quarterly frequency with λ = 100, 000, has also been used, for example, in Shimer (2005) and Shimer (2012). This filter is a much lower-frequency filter than the common specification (quarterly λ = 1, 600) in business cycle analysis. The common filter, however, seems to remove much of the cyclical volatility in the variable of interest.

25

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE TABLE IV Quarterly model calibration

Description

Parameter

Value

Households Discount factor Intertemporal elasticity Preference for leisure

β σ ψ

0.99 1.000 2.250

Engineers and suppliers Bargaining power Mean matching efficiency Persistence of matching efficiency Dispersion of matching efficiency

φ µm ρm σm

0.500 0.546 0.959 0.144

Consumption good producers Output elasticity of capital Output elasticity of labor Depreciation rate Aggregate productivity growth Idiosyncratic persistence Idiosyncratic dispersion Aggregate persistence Aggregate dispersion Capital resale loss Fixed adjustment cost upper bound

α ν δ γ ρx σx ρz σz p¯i ξ¯

0.235 0.604 0.025 1.004 0.970 0.062 0.950 0.007 0.850 0.001

6. MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SUPPLY CHAIN DISRUPTIONS This section discusses the quantitative impact of capital supply chain disruptions. In short, disruptions that lengthen time to build by one month lower GDP by up to one percent. Furthermore these shocks explain about half of the decline in output and investment during the early 1990s recession and the 2007-09 Great Recession. Figure 3 shows the macroeconomic responses to a disruption that lengthens time to build from 5.5 months to 6.5 months on impact. The one-month increase corresponds to one standard deviation of time to build. The shock causes substantial fluctuations in output, investment, and consumption. Investment is most directly affected by the disruption. It falls by 8 percent on impact and remains depressed by 2 percent two years after the shock. Output falls by 1 percent on impact and converges back reaches its trough of 0.55 percent five quarters later. Measured aggregate total factor

26

MATTHIAS MEIER

productivity declines gradually and reaches its trough at below 0.2 percent 6 quarters after the shock. Figure 3: Responses to a supply chain disruption 7

2 0

6.5

-2 6

-4

5.5

-6

5

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0.8

0.8

0.4

0.4

0

0

-0.4

-0.4

-0.8

-0.8

-1.2

Total response Direct channel

-8

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0.5

-1.2

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0.2

0 0

-0.5 -1

-0.2

-1.5 -2

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

-0.4

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

Notes: The sub-figures show impulse responses to a supply chain disruption that lengthens time to build by one month starting from steady state. ‘Direct channel’ denotes the impulse responses when aggregate TFP changes are eliminated through opposing aggregate productivity (z) shocks. Aggregate TFP is computed as T F P = log(Yt ) − α log(Kt ) − ν log(Lt ).

The aggregate effects of adverse shock to the matching technology are explained

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

27

by a direct and an indirect channel. The direct channel captures that longer time to build delays delivery of outstanding investment orders and thus reduces investment and output. The indirect channel captures that longer time to build affects firm-level investment policies: firms invest less frequently and, if they invest, their investment reflect less their contemporaneous productivity. In turn, the alignment between firm-level capital and productivity weakens. Thus, longer time to build lowers measured aggregate total factor productivity. A more detailed discussion of the indirect channel is provided in Section 3. To understand the relative quantitative importance of the two transmission channels, I suggest a simple exercise. While the indirect channel affects measured aggregate total factor productivity, the direct channel has no impact on measured productivity. To isolate the direct channel, I compute a series of exogenous shocks to aggregate productivity that exactly offset the effects on measured aggregate productivity. Measured aggregate TFP then remains at its steady state level. The effects of the direct channel are the macroeconomic responses to the joint occurrence of the initial match efficiency shock and the series of productivity shocks. The resulting ‘direct channel’ responses are shown as dotted lines in Figure 3. Note that this exercise is an approximation, which gives an upward bias to the effects of the direct channel. The reason is that the series of productivity shock only offsets the effects on realized aggregate productivity, but not the effects on expected future aggregate productivity. The direct channel is central to understand the immediate responses, while the medium-term effects are to a larger extent explained by the indirect channel operating through capital misallocation. In particular, the two-year response of output and consumption is importantly shaped by misallocation.18 The direct channel is most important on impact of the shock because in subsequent periods firms adjust their investment policies. Firms prepone investment orders as delivery takes longer, see Figure 11 in Appendix F. Capital adjustment frequency falls consistent with wait-and-see behavior. Note that I evaluate the quantitative impact of shocks to the matching technology in general equilibrium. Accounting for general equilibrium effects is important, because household consumption smoothing motives may substantially dampen the investment and output responses that would arise in partial equilibrium, see Khan and Thomas (2008). The initial increase in consumption reflects a general equilib18

The prominent role of aggregate productivity in my model may be linked to the finding in Chari et al. (2007) on the efficiency wedge.

28

MATTHIAS MEIER

rium mechanism. Since prices are flexible in my model, the intratemporal household optimality condition dictates that consumption has to increase initially in response to the initial decrease in investment, because the capital input in production is predetermined and labor demand falls. Figure 12 shows the macroeconomic responses to a supply chain disruption in a setting identical to that of Figure 3 except that goods market do not clear. While the baseline model is a closed-economy model, this setup may be justified as small open economy. For the US economy, the truth should be somewhere in between. Figure 12 shows substantially larger responses, with GDP falling by up to 1.5%. In addition, this model features more propagation and the trough output response is obtained only 2 years after the shock hits the economy. The responses in Figure 3 show quantitatively important and persistent effects of capital supply chain disruptions. Next, I assess the importance of supply chain disruptions to understand past business cycles. To this end, I compute a matching technology shock series that fits the empirical time to build series. This confines my analysis to the period from 1968 through 2015. Using the model, I compute the time series for output, investment, consumption, and employment. To be clear, fluctuations in these series are only driven by disruption shocks. To make the quarterly series comparable to the data, I HP filter both the simulated series and their empirical counterparts using the same low-frequency filter I use in the calibration. More details on the empirical time series are provided in Section 2.3. Figure 4 plots the model-implied time series against their empirical counterparts. Three observations stand out. First, NBER recession periods (grey-shaded areas) are matched by periods where shocks to the matching technology induce below-trend output growth. Second, supply chain disruptions explain an important share of the observed business cycle variations. These shocks alone explains a drop in investments of more than 8% during the Great Recession and the early 1990s recession, compared to a drop of 16% in the data. For output, the model also explains about half of the empirically observed drop during these two recessions and for consumption it is almost a quarter. Third, in the model GDP tends to start falling before the recession, which reflects the corresponding pattern in the time to build series. Outside the present model, a possible explanation for this discrepancy may be that time to build also increases in response to increased investment demand, so attributing all the precrisis increase in time to build to supply chain disruptions might be misleading.

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

29

Figure 4: Role of supply chain disruptions in understanding past business cycles

16

4

8 0 0 -4

Model Data

-8 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

-8 -16 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

4

4

0

0

-4

-4

-8 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

-8 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Notes: Above time series are computed matching the empirically observed (filtered) movements in time to build through capital supply chain disruption shocks and otherwise using the baseline model calibration. Grey-shaded areas indicate NBER recession dates.

7. CONCLUSION This paper contributes to our understanding of business cycles by establishing countercyclical time to build as a new stylized fact. It then asks: What are the business cycle implications of fluctuations in time to build? To address this question, I first provide time series evidence, which suggests quantitatively large responses to supply chain disruptions. Second, I develop a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, in which capital good markets are characterized by search frictions. Fluctuations in time to build are driven by shocks to the matching technology, which reflect capital supply chain disruptions. Calibrating the model to US data, I show that the empirically observed fluctuations in time to build are quantitatively of first-order importance for business cycles. Of particular quantitative importance

30

MATTHIAS MEIER

is the interaction of time to build and firm investment policies leading to capital misallocation. It should be a direct consequence of this paper to investigate the sources of fluctuations in time to build. In particular, it may be useful to study capital good supply networks. Small changes at critical points in such networks, for example the exit of an important supplier, could have non-trivial aggregate implications for time to build. A complementary explanation may revolve around trade credit. While the empirical evidence rejects an important role for aggregate financial conditions, trade credit in capital good production networks might be important to understand the observed time to build fluctuations. For example, suppose capital suppliers produce subject to cash-in-advance constraints. During recessions short-run liquidity in the form of trade credit may become scarce. As a result, suppliers may need to slow down production despite long order books.

REFERENCES Acemoglu, D., V. M. Carvalho, A. Ozdaglar, and A. Tahbaz-Salehi (2012): “The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica, 80, 1977–2016. Ahn, S., G. Kaplan, B. Moll, and T. Winberry (2016): “No More Excuses! A Toolbox for Solving Heterogeneous Agent Models with Aggregate Shocks,” Sed presentation slides. Atalay, E., A. Hortaçsu, J. Roberts, and C. Syverson (2011): “Network structure of production,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108, 5199–5202. Bachmann, R. and C. Bayer (2013): “‘Wait-and-See’ business cycles?” Journal of Monetary Economics, 60, 704 – 719. Bachmann, R., R. J. Caballero, and E. M. R. A. Engel (2013): “Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Investment: New Evidence and a DSGE Model,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5, 29–67. Bachmann, R. and G. Moscarini (2011): “Business Cycles and Endogenous Uncertainty,” 2011 Meeting Papers 36, Society for Economic Dynamics. Baqaee, D. (2016): “Cascading Failures in Production Networks,” 2016 Meeting Papers 402, Society for Economic Dynamics. Barrot, J.-N. and J. Sauvagnat (2016): “Input Specificity and the Propagation of Idiosyncratic Shocks in Production Networks,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131, 1543–1592. Baumeister, C. and J. D. Hamilton (2015): “Sign Restrictions, Structural Vector Autoregres-

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

31

sions, and Useful Prior Information,” Econometrica, 83, 1963–1999. Belsley, D. A. (1969): Industry production behavior: The order-stock distinction, vol. 62, NorthHolland. Bigio, S. and J. La’O (2016): “Financial Frictions in Production Networks,” Working Paper 22212, National Bureau of Economic Research. Bloom, N. (2009): “The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks,” Econometrica, 77, 623–685. Bloom, N., M. Floetotto, N. Jaimovich, I. Saporta-Eksten, and S. J. Terry (2014): “Really Uncertain Business Cycles,” Working Paper 14-18, US Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies. Boehm, C. E., A. Flaaen, and N. Pandalai-Nayar (2015): “Input Linkages and the Transmission of Shocks: Firm-Level Evidence from the 2011 Tohoku Earthquake,” Working Papers 15-28, Center for Economic Studies, U.S. Census Bureau. Boissay, F. and R. Gropp (2013): “Payment Defaults and Interfirm Liquidity Provision,” Review of Finance, 17, 1853–1894. Brooks, P. K. (2000): “The Facts About Time-To-Build,” Tech. rep., IMF Working Papers. Campbell, J. (1998): “Entry, Exit, Embodied Technology, and Business Cycles,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 371–408. Carlton, D. W. (1979): “Contracts, Price Rigidity, and Market Equilibrium,” Journal of Political Economy, 87, 1034–1062. ——— (1983): “Equilibrium Fluctuations When Price and Delivery Lag Clear the Market,” Bell Journal of Economics, 14, 562–572. Carvalho, V. M., M. Nirei, Y. U. Saito, and A. Tahbaz-Salehi (2016): “Supply Chain Disruptions: Evidence from the Great East Japan Earthquake,” CEPR Discussion Papers 11711, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers. Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan (2007): “Business Cycle Accounting,” Econometrica, 75, 781–836. Chirinko, R. S. (2008): “σ: The long and short of it,” Journal of Macroeconomics, 30, 671 – 686, the CES Production Function in the Theory and Empirics of Economic Growth. Christiano, L. J. and M. Eichenbaum (1987): “Temporal aggregation and structural inference in macroeconomics,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 26, 63–130. Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans (1999): “Chapter 2 Monetary policy shocks: What have we learned and to what end?” Elsevier, vol. 1 of Handbook of Macroeconomics, 65 –

32

MATTHIAS MEIER

148. ——— (2005): “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy,” Journal of Political Economy, 113, 1–45. Cohen, L. and A. Frazzini (2008): “Economic Links and Predictable Returns,” The Journal of Finance, 63, 1977–2011. Coibion, O. (2012): “Are the Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks Big or Small?” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4, 1–32. Conley, T. G., C. B. Hansen, and P. E. Rossi (2012): “Plausibly Exogenous,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 94, 260–272. Cooper, R. W. and J. C. Haltiwanger (2006): “On the Nature of Capital Adjustment Costs,” Review of Economic Studies, 73, 611–633. Eisfeldt, A. L. and A. A. Rampini (2006): “Capital reallocation and liquidity,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 53, 369 – 399. Fajgelbaum, P., E. Schaal, and M. Taschereau-Dumouchel (2014): “Uncertainty Traps,” Working Paper 19973, National Bureau of Economic Research. Fernald, J. G. (2014): “A quarterly, utilization-adjusted series on total factor productivity,” Working Paper Series 2012-19, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Fisher, J. (2006): “The Dynamic Effects of Neutral and Investment-Specific Technology Shocks,” Journal of Political Economy, 114, 413–451. Gafarov, B., M. Meier, and J. L. Montiel Olea (2016): “Delta-Method Inference for a Class of Set-Identified SVARs,” mimeo, Columbia University. Gali, J. (1999): “Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?” American Economic Review, 89, 249–271. Gilchrist, S., J. W. Sim, and E. Zakrajšek (2014): “Uncertainty, Financial Frictions, and Investment Dynamics,” Working Paper 20038, National Bureau of Economic Research. Gopinath, G., S. Kalemli-Ozcan, L. Karabarbounis, and C. Villegas-Sanchez (2017): “Capital Allocation and Productivity in South Europe,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132, 1915–1967. Hansen, G. D. (1985): “Indivisible labor and the business cycle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 16, 309 – 327. Hicks, J. R. (1970): “A Neo-Austrian Growth Theory,” Economic Journal, 80, 257–281. Holt, C. C., F. Modigliani, J. F. Muth, and H. A. Simon (1960): Planning Production,

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

33

Inventories, and Work Force, International Series in Management, Prentice Hall. Jacobson, T. and E. von Schedvin (2015): “Trade Credit and the Propagation of Corporate Failure: An Empirical Analysis,” Econometrica, 83, 1315–1371. Justiniano, A., G. E. Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti (2010): “Investment shocks and business cycles,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 57, 132 – 145. Kalemli-Ozcan, S., S.-J. Kim, H. S. Shin, B. E. Sorensen, and S. Yesiltas (2014): “Financial Shocks in Production Chains,” mimeo, University of Maryland. Kalouptsidi, M. (2014): “Time to Build and Fluctuations in Bulk Shipping,” American Economic Review, 104, 564–608. Kehrig, M. (2015): “The Cyclical Nature of the Productivity Distribution,” Working papers, Center for Economic Studies, U.S. Census Bureau. Kehrig, M. and N. Vincent (2016): “Do Firms Mitigate or Magnify Capital Misallocation? Evidence from Plant-Level Data,” mimeo, University of Texas at Austin. Khan, A. and J. K. Thomas (2008): “Idiosyncratic Shocks and the Role of Nonconvexities in Plant and Aggregate Investment Dynamics,” Econometrica, 76, 395–436. ——— (2013): “Credit Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with Production Heterogeneity,” Journal of Political Economy, 121, 1055 – 1107. Kilian, L. and D. P. Murphy (2012): “Why Agnostic Sign Restrictions Are Not Enough: Understanding the Dynamics of Oil Market VAR Models,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 10, 1166–1188. Krusell, P., A. A. Smith, and Jr. (1998): “Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy,” Journal of Political Economy, 106, 867–896. Kydland, F. E. and E. C. Prescott (1982): “Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica, 50, 1345–70. Lev, B. and S. R. Thiagarajan (1993): “Fundamental Information Analysis,” Journal of Accounting Research, 31, 190–215. Mertens, K. and M. O. Ravn (2011): “Understanding the aggregate effects of anticipated and unanticipated tax policy shocks,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 14, 27 – 54, special issue: Sources of Business Cycles. Nalewaik, J. and E. Pinto (2015): “The response of capital goods shipments to demand over the business cycle,” Journal of Macroeconomics, 43, 62 – 80. Oh, H. and C. Yoon (2016): “Time to build and the real-options channel of residential investment,”

34

MATTHIAS MEIER

mimeo, Vanderbilt University. Popkin, J. (1965): “The Relationship Between New Orders and Shipments: An Analysis of the Machinery and Equipment Industries,” in Survey of Current Business, vol. 45. Prescott, E. C. (1986): “Theory ahead of business-cycle measurement,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 25, 11 – 44. Ramey, V. A. and M. D. Shapiro (1998): “Costly capital reallocation and the effects of government spending,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48, 145–194. Ramey, V. A. and D. J. Vine (2010): “Oil, Automobiles, and the U.S. Economy: How Much have Things Really Changed?” Working Paper 16067, National Bureau of Economic Research. Reiter, M. (2009): “Solving heterogeneous-agent models by projection and perturbation,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 33, 649 – 665. Ricardo, D. (1817): On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, London:Murray. Rogerson, R. (1988): “Indivisible labor, lotteries and equilibrium,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, 3 – 16. Romer, C. D. and D. H. Romer (2004): “A New Measure of Monetary Shocks: Derivation and Implications,” American Economic Review, 94, 1055–1084. Schmitt-Grohe, S. and M. Uribe (2004): “Solving dynamic general equilibrium models using a second-order approximation to the policy function,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28, 755–775. Shimer, R. (2005): “The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies,” American Economic Review, 95, 25–49. ——— (2012): “Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 15, 127–148. Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2007): “Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach,” American Economic Review, 97, 586–606. Terry, S. J. (2015): “Alternative Methods for Solving Heterogeneous Firm Models,” mimeo, Boston University. von Böhm-Bawerk, E. (1891): The Positive Theory of Capital, original version published in 1888, translated by William Smart in 1891. Winberry, T. (2016a): “Lumpy Investment, Business Cycles, and Stimulus Policy,” mimeo, Chicago Booth. ——— (2016b): “A Toolbox for Solving and Estimating Heterogeneous Agent Macro Models,”

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

35

mimeo, Chicago Booth. Zarnowitz, V. (1962): “Unfilled Orders, Price Changes, and Business Fluctuations,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 44, 367–394.

36

MATTHIAS MEIER

Appendix

37

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE APPENDIX A: TIME TO BUILD FLUCTUATIONS

800

Figure 5: Aggregate order backlog, shipments, and new orders Bln. USD

0

200

400

600

Order Backlog

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

1990

2000

2010

Bln. USD

0

20

40

60

80

Shipments New Orders

1970

1980

Notes: All series refer to the non-defense equipment goods sector from M3 data and are expressed in nominal values. Shaded, gray areas indicate NBER recession dates.

38

MATTHIAS MEIER

Figure 6: Sector-level time to build Industrial Machinery and Equipment

Electronic and Other Electrical Equipment Months

4 2

1

2

3

3

4

5

5

6

Months

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

1970

Transportation Equipment

1980

1990

2000

2010

Instruments and Related Products Months

1

0

1.5

5

2

10

2.5

15

Months

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Notes: Time to build is measured using M3 data as the ratio of order backlog to monthly shipments, for non-defense equipment goods. Shaded, gray areas indicate NBER recession dates.

Figure 7: Cross-sectional dispersion of firm-level time to build

20

Months

0

5

10

15

Standard deviation Interquartile range

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Notes: Firm-level time to build as the ratio of order backlog to sales for equipment goods using annual Compustat data. The figures show the cross-sectional standard deviation, and interquartile range, weighted by firm-level sales. Shaded, gray areas indicate NBER recession dates.

39

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE APPENDIX B: ROBUSTNESS OF THE STRUCTURAL VAR RESULTS B.1. Alternative identification scheme and first differences

First, I investigate the results under an alternative identification assumption. While the baseline identification scheme tends to be conservative, its restrictions are stronger than the restrictions of the general equilibrium model. As alternative identification, I suggest to have the time to build shock ‘ordered first’. This term refers to the ordering of variables in the VAR. It means that time to build shocks can contemporanously affect all other variables in the VAR, but no shock other than time to build shocks can affect time to build contemporaneously. Figure 8 shows that the baseline identification implies smaller macroeconomic respones to time to build shocks compared to the alternative identification, albeit the differences are not large. Impulse responses under the alternative identification remain significant.

Figure 8: Impulse responses to a one standard deviation time to build shock (model in levels with linear time trend, alternative identification schemes) GDP (in %)

Time to build (in months) 5.8

0.2 0

5.7

-0.2 5.6

-0.4

Baseline Ordered First

5.5

-0.6 0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0

Investment (in %)

4

8

12

16

20

24

Consumption (in %)

0.5

0.2

0

0

-0.5 -0.2 -1 -0.4

-1.5 -2

-0.6 0

4

8

12

16

Quarters

20

24

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

Quarters

Notes: Solid lines show (selected) impulse responses to a time to build shock under the baseline identification scheme. Dashed lines show the impulse responses under the alternative identification scheme, in which time to build is ‘ordered first’. Shaded, gray areas illustrate the 90% confidence intervals associated with the alternative identification scheme.

Figure 9 shows the cumulative impulse responses when estimating a VAR, in which all variables enter in first differences and the linear time trend is dropped. At the same time, the figure compares the two identification schemes. The differences of the impulse responses across identification schemes appears negligible. The important finding is that the impulse responses are similar to the ones in Figure 8. While I assumed a linear time trend for the latter, the findings on time to build shocks

40

MATTHIAS MEIER

appear robust to non-linear time trends.

Figure 9: Cumulative impulse responses to a one standard deviation time to build shock (model in first differences, two alternative identification schemes) Time to build (in months)

GDP (in %) 0.2

6.2

0

6

-0.2

5.8

-0.4 -0.6

5.6

Baseline Ordered First

-0.8

5.4

-1 0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0

Investment (in %)

4

8

12

16

20

24

Consumption (in %) 0.2

0

0 -0.2

-1

-0.4 -0.6

-2

-0.8 -3

-1 0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0

Quarters

4

8

12

16

20

24

Quarters

Notes: Solid lines show (selected) cumulative impulse responses to a time to build shock under the baseline identification scheme. Dashed lines show the impulse responses under the alternative identification scheme, in which time to build is ‘ordered first’. Shaded, gray areas illustrate the 90% confidence intervals associated with the alternative identification scheme.

B.2. Elasticity bounds In this subsection, I propose a new approach to provide robustness for point-identified structural VAR models in a frequentist setup. Structural VAR models, such as Gali (1999), Christiano et al. (2005), and Bloom (2009), impose various zero restrictions on contemporaneous and long-run responses to obtain point identification. As robustness, I propose to replace some or all of the zero restrictions by bounds on the elasticity with respect to the shock of interest.19 For example, instead of assuming an uncertainty shock does not contemporaneously affect GDP, as robustness I would restrict the elasticity of GDP with respect to a change in uncertainty due to an uncertainty shock to be bounded between ±c%. This nests the point-identified model in the limit case when all bounds are zero (c = 0). The structural VAR model is no longer point-identified when replacing a zero restriction with strictly positive bounds on the elasticities (c > 0). 19

Elasiticity bounds have recently gained popularity in the Bayesian structural VAR literature, see, e.g., Kilian and Murphy (2012) and Baumeister and Hamilton (2015).

41

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

I implement this robustness exercise using the results in Gafarov, Meier, and Montiel Olea (2016), which provide inference for set-identified structural VAR models. Formally, to apply their results, I need to assume that for a given IRF either the lower and upper elasticity bound may not hold jointly. Notice that confidence sets are estimated based on Delta method inference. In fact, bootstrap inference is not necessarily valid here because the endpoints of the identified sets are not fully differentiable. The suggested robustness is similar to Conley et al. (2012) which proposes as robustness to relax the exclusion restriction when using IV methods. I suggest the following robustness for the conservative baseline identification. Instead of zero restrictions on contemporaneous responses, I constrain the elasticity of all variables (except for the backlog ratio) with respect to the match efficiency shock to be between -1% and +1%, see Table V. For an increase in the backlog ratio of 2.5%, the contemporaneous responses are bound to be between -0.025% and +0.025%. TABLE V identification schemes: constraints on contemporaneous elasticities

Baseline Robustness

TTB

GDP

Inv

Con

CPI

Wag

FFR

LaP

+ +

0 ±1%

0 ±1%

0 ±1%

0 ±1%

0 ±1%

0 ±1%

0 ±1%

Notes: +/0/±1% indicate that the elasticity is constrained to be positive/exactly zero/between -1% and +1%, respectively. The contemporaneous elasticity of variable i and time to build in response to time to build shocks is given by (e0i B1 )/(e01 B1 ), where ei is the i-th column of the identity matrix I8 . TTB: Time to build, GDP: Real GDP, Con: Real Consumption, Inv: Real Investment, CPI : Consumer Prices, Wag: Real Wage, FFR: Federal Funds Rate, LaP: Labor Productivity. Figure 10 shows the resulting impulse responses under the robustness identification scheme. Instead of a single impulse response, there is an interval with admissible impulse responses (dotted lines). The confidence set is adjusted accordingly based on Gafarov, Meier, and Montiel Olea (2016). Notice that the main findings of the baseline model in Figure 10 are ‘robust’ in the sense that the declines in GDP, investment, and consumption remain significant.

42

MATTHIAS MEIER

Figure 10: Impulse responses to a one standard deviation time to build shock (model in levels with linear time trend, two alternative identification schemes) GDP (in %)

Time to build (in months) 5.8

0.2 0

5.7

-0.2 5.6

-0.4

Baseline Bounds of Identi-ed Set

5.5

-0.6 0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0

Investment (in %)

4

8

12

16

20

24

Consumption (in %)

0.5

0.2

0

0

-0.5 -0.2 -1 -0.4

-1.5 -2

-0.6 0

4

8

12

16

Quarters

20

24

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

Quarters

Notes: Solid lines show (selected) responses to a time to build shock under the baseline identification scheme. Dashed lines show the bounds of the identified set under elasticity constraints, see Table V. Shaded, gray areas illustrate the 90% confidence intervals for the identified sets.

43

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE B.3. Correlation of identified capital supply chain disruptions with other shocks

The importance of capital supply chain disruptions could potentially reflect other structural shocks that are not well identified in my model. To address this concern, I correlate my identified capital supply chain disruption series with various business cycles shocks, constructed in a number of papers outside my empirical framework. These business cycles shocks include direct estimates of productivity shocks and numerous policy shocks. Table VI provides the correlation of the capital supply chain disruption series with leads and lags of the external business cycle shock series. By and large, I find capital supply chain disruptions to be uncorrelated with external shocks. This finding further supports to the importance of exogenous shocks to capital supply. TABLE VI Correlogram of time to build shocks with external business cycle shocks

TFP UA-TFP UA-TFP-I UA-TFP-C MP Oil Defense Tax

-4

-3

-2

quarterly lags/leads -1 0 +1

+2

+3

+4

-0.07 -0.09 -0.03 -0.10 0.02 -0.01 -0.12 0.02

-0.05 -0.13∗ -0.15∗∗ -0.08 0.08 0.00 -0.15∗∗ -0.06

0.00 0.04 0.02 0.04 0.04 -0.02 -0.02 0.02

0.00 0.07 0.11 0.03 0.02 -0.02 -0.03 0.04

-0.07 -0.04 0.03 -0.07 0.04 0.01 -0.08 0.09

-0.08 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.09 0.09 -0.01 0.04

0.00 0.07 0.05 0.05 0.11 -0.04 -0.10 -0.02

-0.03 -0.05 0.03 -0.09 -0.01 0.01 -0.16∗∗ 0.01

-0.04 -0.06 -0.03 -0.07 0.06 0.00 -0.04 -0.13

Note: The table shows the correlation of capital supply chain disruptions with various shock series at lags/forwards between -4 and +4 quarters. */**/*** denote 10%/5%/1% significance levels, respectively. Productivity shock series are from Fernald (2014): TFP, Utilization-Adjusted (UA) TFP, UA-TFP in equipment and durables, and UA-TFP in non-durables. Monetary policy shocks (MP) are based on Romer and Romer (2004) and Coibion (2012). Oil price shocks are based on Ramey and Vine (2010). Surprise defense expenditures as fiscal shocks are from Ramey and Shapiro (1998), and tax shocks from Mertens and Ravn (2011). The identified capital supply chain disruption series appears not to reflect investment-specific productivity shocks along the lines of Justiniano et al. (2010) and Justiniano et al. (2010). Beyond the evidence in Table VI, this conclusion is supported by the finding that extending my VAR model by the relative price of investment goods only marginally affects the results presented here. By the same argument, identified capital supply chain disruptions appear not to reflect uncertainty shocks. The identified shocks further do not appear to reflect changes in aggregate financial conditions. This conclusion is based on the following result. The VAR exercise in Gilchrist et al. (2014) finds that uncertainty shocks are crucially transmitted through credit spreads. When replacing uncertainty by time to build, I do not find evidence for the transmission of time to build shocks through credit spreads.

44

MATTHIAS MEIER APPENDIX C: CLOSED-FORM RESULTS FOR AGGREGATE TFP

This section provides some details on the derivation of aggregate TFP. Profit-maximizing labor demand and the profit function after maximizing out labor are

 `jt =

α νxjt kjt wt

1  1−ν

π ˜jt (k) = (1 − ν)

,



ν wt

ν  1−ν

1

α

1−ν xjt k 1−ν − rt k.

Capital is adjusted subject to τ periods time to build, i.e. firms choose in period t how much capital to use in period t + τ . Denoting by Et the conditional expectation operator, the firm problem is kj,t,t+τ = arg max Et [˜ πjt+τ (k)]. k

1 1−ν ], the optimal capital policy follows as Defining x ˜jt = Et [xjt+τ

kj,t,t+τ =

1−ν   1−α−ν 

α rt

ν wt

ν  1−α−ν

1−ν 1−α−ν x ˜jt .

The firm’s employment policy can be simplifed to `j,t,t+τ =

α    1−α−ν

α rt

1−α−ν+αν  (1−ν)(1−α−ν)

ν wt

1

α

1−ν 1−α−ν xjt+τ x ˜jt ,

and the firm’s output follows as yj,t,t+τ =

α    1−α−ν

α rt

ν wt

ν  1−α−ν

1

α

1−ν 1−α−ν xjt+τ x ˜jt .

Denoting by E the unconditional expectation operator, I define two moments of productivity



1−ν

1−α−ν ˜1 = E x X ˜jt 1

h



 = exp α

1−α−ν ˜ 2 = E x 1−ν x X jt+τ ˜jt

i

where στ2 = V[log xjt+τ | log xjt ] = Kt,t+τ =

α rt

α   1−α−ν 

 = exp 1−ρ2τ x 1−ρ2 x

ν wt

 ,

1 1 1 α σx2 − στ2 2 (1 − α − ν)2 2 (1 − ν)(1 − α − ν)2



ν  1−α−ν



˜1 X

1−α−ν+αν

From here, it is straightforward to obtain aggregate TFP as a function of time to build TFPt,t+τ =

˜1, =X

σx2 . Aggregate capital, labor, and output follow as

α ν (1−ν)(1−α−ν) ˜ X2 rt wt α ν   1−α−ν   1−α−ν α ν ˜2 = X rt wt

Lt,t+τ = Yt,t+τ

1−ν    1−α−ν

1 1 α 1 σx2 − στ2 2 (1 − α − ν)2 2 (1 − ν)(1 − α − ν)2

1 1 1 α σx2 − στ2 . 21−α−ν 2 (1 − ν)(1 − α − ν)

45

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE APPENDIX D: SOLUTION ALGORITHM D.1. Simplified consumption good firm problem

To solve the model most efficiently, I rewrite the firm problem. First, I transform the firm problem. Instead of io , the investment order, I let firms choose ko , the new capital stock upon delivery. Computationally, this transformation has the advantage that I can use the same grid for ko as for k, and this grid can be tighter than the one for io . To leave the firm problem unchanged, ko o needs to evolve over time to guarantee the implicitly defined investment order satisfies io0 = iγ . Using the identity, io = γko + (1 − δ)k, the evolution of ko over time (conditional on no delivery) o according to ko0 = kγ − δ(1−δ)k . Second, in slight abuse of notation, I drop the aggregate state γ2 s and instead use time subscripts for functions that depend on the aggregate state. I express the firm value functions in utils, see Khan and Thomas (2008), and redefine the value function such that the expectation with respect to idiosyncratic productivity does not have to be computed within the maximization problem. This raises computational efficiency and it tends to smooth the value functions. More precisely, I define V˜t (k, x, ξ) = pt Ex Eξ V (k, x0 , ξ 0 ), V˜tA (k, x, ξ) = pt VtA (k, x, ξ), ˜ t (k, x, ξ) = Ex W ¯ t (k, x0 , ξ), W ¯ t (k, x, ξ) = pt Wt (k, x, ξ), where Ex (Eξ ) V˜tN A (k, x) = pt V N A (k, x), W 0 0 denotes the expectation with respect to x (ξ ) conditional on x (ξ) and pt = Ct−σ as before. Then equations (4.16), (4.17), (4.18), and (4.19) can be rewritten as:

n

o

V˜t (k, x, ξ) = Ex Eξ max V˜tA (k, x0 , ξ 0 ), V˜tN A (k, x0 )

V˜tN A (k, x) = pt cft (k, x) + βEt V˜t+1 ((1 − δ)k/γ, x, ξ)



V˜tA (k, x, ξ) = max o kt

n

¯ t (k, kto , x, ξ) W

∈R+



o

o

¯ t (k, k , x, ξ) = pt cft (k, x) W

h

+ qt − pt [(1 − pi (k, ko ))(γko − (1 − δ)k) + ftE (ξ)] + βEt V˜t+1 (ko , x, ξ)



h

˜ t+1 (1 − δ)k/γ, ko /γ − δ(1 − δ)k/γ 2 , x, ξ + (1 − qt ) βEt W



i

 i

˜ t (k, ko , x, ξ) = Ex W ¯ t (k, x0 , ξ) W where Et denotes the expectation with respect to aggregate state st+1 conditional on st . The net present value of the fixed adjustment cost can be expressed by f act ξ, where f act is defined recursively f act = qt pt

wt + (1 − qt )βEt f act+1 . φqt

46

MATTHIAS MEIER

In turn, this allows me to simplify the firm problem as

n

o

V˜t (k, x) = Ex Eξ max V˜tA (k, x0 ) − f act ξ 0 , V˜tN A (k, x0 ) wt + (1 − qt )βEt f act+1 φqt   V˜tN A (k, x) = pt cft (k, x) + βEt V˜t+1 ((1 − δ)k/γ, x) f act = qt pt

V˜tA (k, x) = max o

kt ∈R+

n

¯ t (k, kto , x) W

o

¯ t (k, ko , x) = pt cft (k, x) W

h

+ qt − pt (1 − pi (k, ko ))(γko − (1 − δ)k) + βEt V˜t+1 (ko , x)



h

˜ t+1 (1 − δ)k/γ, ko /γ − δ(1 − δ)k/γ 2 , x + (1 − qt ) βEt W



i

 i

˜ t (k, ko , x) = Ex W ¯ t (k, x0 ) W Importantly, this allows me to compute the extensive margin adjustment policy in closed form, V˜ A (k, x0 ) − V˜tN A (k, x0 ) ξˆt = t . f act Next, I approximate firm values using collocation where Φ denotes basis functions in matrix representation and c denotes vectors of coefficients V˜t (k, x) 'ΦV (k, x)cVt ˜ t (k, ko , x) 'ΦW (k, ko , x)cW W t The approximations are exact at the nk collocation nodes k1 , ..., knk and k1o , ..., kno k . In practice, I choose the same collocation nodes for k and ko . As baseline we use cubic B-splines to approximate the firm value functions. This does not only have the advantage of being computationally fast, but also conditional on the coefficients we know the Jacobian in closed form. In particular, I can write down the optimality condition for intensive margin capital adjustment (kto ) as o W qt pt ps (k, kto )γ =qt βEt ΦVk (kto , x)cVt+1 + (1 − qt )βEt ΦW ko ((1 − δ)kt /γ, kt , x)ct+1 , W o where ΦVk = (∂ΦV )/(∂k) and ΦW ko = (∂Φ )/(∂k ). I approximate the AR(1) process of idiosyncratic productivity using Tauchen’s algorithm. I denote the discrete grid points of x by x1 , ..., xnx consisting of nx grid points and the transition probability from state xj to state xj 0 one period later by πx (xj 0 |xj ). To render the infinite-dimensional distribution µt tractable, I approximate it with a discrete histogram. That is, µt measures the share of firms for each discrete combination of capital stock ki1 , outstanding order kio2 (both correspond to the collocation nodes), and productivity xj . A further distinction is useful: Let µVt denote the cross-sectional distribution of firms without outstanding orders over idiosyncratic states (ki , xj ) and µW the distribution of firms with outstanding orders t o V W over (ki1 , ki2 , xj ). It holds that µt = (µt , µt ).

47

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE D.2. Campbell-Reiter algorithm

Using the preceding approximation and simplification steps, the model equilibrium is described by the following non-linear equations: (D.1)

n

ΦV (k, x)cVt = Ex Eξ max V˜tA (k, x0 ) − f act ξ 0 , V˜tN A (k, x0 )

o

ξˆt (k, x) = (V˜tA (k, x) − V˜tN A (k, x))/f act V˜tN A (k, x) = pt cft (k, x) + βEt ΦV ((1 − δ)k/γ, x)cVt+1 ¯ t (k, kto , x) V˜tA (k, x) = W ¯ t (k, ko , x) = pt cft (k, x) W

h

+ qt − pt (1 − pi (k, ko ))(γko − (1 − δ)k) + βEt ΦV (ko , x)cVt+1

h

+ (1 − qt ) βEt ΦW ((1 − δ)k/γ, ko /γ − δ(1 − δ)k/γ 2 , x)cW t+1

i

i

α/(1−ν)

cft (kt , xt ) = (1 − ν) (ν/wt )ν/(1−ν) (zt xt )1/(1−ν) kt wt = ψ/pt qt = mt (φ/(1 − φ))η−1 (D.2) (D.3)

0 ¯ ΦW (k, ko , x)cW t = Ex Wt (k, x ) wt f act = qt pt + (1 − qt )βEt f act+1 φqt

(D.4)

o W qt pt ps (k, kto )γ = qt βEt ΦVk (kto , x)cVt+1 + (1 − qt )βEt ΦW ko ((1 − δ)kt /γ, kt , x)ct+1

(D.5)

1 = Y t − It pt Yt =

X

α/(1−ν)

µt (ki1 , ki2 , xj ) (ν/wt )ν/(1−ν) (zt xj )1/(1−ν) ki1

i1 ,i2 ,j

It =

X

µVt (ki , xj )G(ξˆt (ki , xj ))qt ps (ki , kto (xj )) [γkto (xj ) − (1 − δ)ki ]

i,j

+

X

o s o o µW t (ki1 , ki2 , xj )qt p (ki1 , ki2 ) [γki2 − (1 − δ)ki1 ]

i1 ,i2 ,j

(D.6)

µVt+1 (ki0 , xj 0 )

=

X

πx (xj 0 |xj )µVt (ki , xj )[ωtV,V,A (i, i0 , j) + ωtV,V,N A (i, i0 , j)]

i,j

X

+

o W,V πx (xj 0 |xj )qt µW (i1 , i2 , i0 , j) t (ki1 , ki2 , xj )ωt

i1 ,i2 ,j

(D.7)

µW t+1 (ki01 , ki02 , xj 0 )

=

X

πx (xj 0 |xj )µVt (ki , xj )ωtV,W (i, i01 , i02 , j)

i,j

+

X

W,W πx (xj 0 |xj )µW (i1 , i2 , i01 , i02 , j) t (ki1 , ki2 , xj )ωt

i1 ,i2 ,j

(D.8)

log(mt+1 ) = (1 − ρm ) log(µm ) + ρm log(mt )

(D.9)

log(zt+1 ) = ρz log(zt )

48

MATTHIAS MEIER

With the following auxiliary equations for the law of motion of the distribution:

ωtV,V,A (i, i0 , j) =

 k 0 −kto (xj )  G(ξˆt (ki , xj ))qt kii0 −ki0 −1  G(ξˆt (ki , xj ))qt

  

ωtV,V,N A (i, i0 , j)

=

0

0

(i1 , i2 , i , j) =

=

kto (xj ) ∈ [ki0 , ki0 +1 ]

if

(1 − δ)ki /γ ∈ [ki0 −1 , ki0 ]

(1−δ)k /γ−k [1 − G(ξˆt (ki , xj ))] k 0 i −k 0 i0

if

(1 − δ)ki /γ ∈ [ki0 , ki0 +1 ]

0

else

i +1

i

 k 0 −(1−δ)ki /γ ki0 −kto (xj ) 2 ˆt (ki , xj ))(1 − qt ) i1  G( ξ  ki0 −ki0 −1 ki0 −ki0 −1   1 1 2 2     if kto (xj ) ∈ [ki02 −1 , ki02 ] and (1 − δ)ki /γ ∈ [ki0 −1 , ki0 ]    (1−δ)ki /γ−ki0 ki0 −kto (xj )   2 1 ˆt (ki , xj ))(1 − qt )  G( ξ  ki0 +1 −ki0 ki0 −ki0 −1  1 1 2 2    o  0 −1 , ki0 ] and (1 − δ)ki /γ ∈ [ki0 , ki0 +1 ] if k (x ) ∈ [k  j t i  2 2 o ki0 −(1−δ)ki /γ kt (xj )−ki0

2 G(ξˆt (ki , xj ))(1 − qt ) 1k 0 −k 0 ki0 +1 −ki0  i −1 i  1 1 2 2     if kto (xj ) ∈ [ki02 , ki02 +1 ] and (1 − δ)ki /γ ∈ [ki0 −1 , ki0 ]    (1−δ)ki /γ−ki0 kto (xj )−ki0    G(ξˆt (ki , xj ))(1 − qt ) k 0 −k 0 1 k 0 −k 02  i +1 i i +1 i  1 1 2 2    o  0 , ki0 +1 ] and (1 − δ)k if k (x ) ∈ [k  i /γ ∈ [ki0 , ki0 +1 ] j t i  2 2  

else

 k −k 0  q i i2   t ki0 −ki0 −1   

ωtW,W (i1 , i2 , i01 , i02 , j)

if else

0

ωtW,V

kto (xj ) ∈ [ki0 −1 , ki0 ]

 k −(1−δ)k /γ  [1 − G(ξˆt (ki , xj ))] i0k 0 −k 0 i   i i −1   

ωtV,W (i, i01 , i02 , j) =

kto (xj )−ki0 ki0 +1 −ki0

if

if

ki2 ∈ [ki0 −1 , ki0 ]

k −k 0 qt k 0i2 −ki 0 i +1 i

if

ki2 ∈ [ki0 , ki0 +1 ]

0

else

 ki0 −(1−δ)ki1 /γ  (1 − qt ) 1k 0 −k 0   i i −1  1 (1 − qt )    

(1−δ)ki1 /γ−ki0

1

ki0 +1 −ki0 1

if

(1 − δ)ki1 /γ ∈ [ki01 −1 , ki01 ]

and

i20 = i2

if

(1 − δ)ki1 /γ ∈ [ki01 , ki01 +1 ]

and

i20 = i2

1

0

else

Labeled equations (D.1)–(D.9) are the main equations, and all other unlabeled equations are auxiliary in defining the model equilibrium. Given nk collocation nodes and nx discrete grid points of x, equations (D.1)–(D.9) are nf = 2n2k nx + 3nk nx + 4. I organize these equations in (D.10)

Et [f (xt , xt+1 , yt , yt+1 )] = 0,

z 2 where t = (m t , t ) ∈ R denotes the vector of aggregate shocks. xt denotes predetermined state variables and yt denotes non-predetermined state variables 2

(D.11)

xt = [µt ; log(mt ); log(zt )] ∈ Rnx ≡nk nx +nk nx +2 ,

(D.12)

o ny ≡nk nx +2nk nx +2 yt = [cVt ; cW . t ; log(act ); log(kt ); log(pt )] ∈ R

2

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

49

¯, y ¯, y ¯ ) = 0. In the general case, the model The non-stochastic steady state is defined as f (¯ x, x solution is given by (D.13)

yt = g(xt , ζ),

(D.14)

xt+1 = h(xt , ζ) + ζ σ ˜ t+1 ,

where ζ is the perturbation parameter and g : Rnx × R+ → Rny and f : Rnx × R+ → Rnx . The exogenous shocks are collected in t+1 ∈ Rn , and σ ˜ ∈ Rnx ×n attributes shocks to the right equations while also scaling them (by σ m , σ z ). To solve the two policy functions, I use a firstorder approximation. I follow the perturbation algorithm in Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2004). This requires to compute the Jacobians of function f (locally) at steady state. Importantly, the algorithm in Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2004) checks for existence and uniqueness of a model solution.

D.3. Krusell-Smith algorithm This subsection suggests how the model can be solved using the Krusell-Smith algorithm. Following Krusell et al. (1998), and the adaption for heterogeneous firms by Khan and Thomas (2008), I assume agents in my model only observe a finite set of moments, informative about the entire distribution, instead of observing µ directly. The agents approximate equilibrium prices and the evolution of the observed moments by a log-linear rule. I approximate the distribution µ by the aggregate capital stock,

Z (D.15)

Kt =

kdµ, S

and the stock of investments outstanding from the preceding period (D.16)

Ito =

Z

(γko − (1 − δ)k)dµW .

SW

If time-to-build dropped to zero q = 1, Ito would constitute the investments activated in addition to new orders. I suggest the following log-linear forecast rules (D.17)

log Kt+1 = βk0 (zt , mt ) + βk1 (zt , mt ) log Kt + βk2 (zt , mt ) log Ito ,

(D.18)

o log It+1 = βi0 (zt , mt ) + βi1 (zt , mt ) log Kt + βi2 (zt , mt ) log Ito ,

and the log-linear pricing rule (D.19)

log pt = βp0 (zt , mt ) + βp1 (zt , mt ) log Kt + βp2 (zt , mt ) log Ito .

The forecasting and pricing rules are described by coefficients that depend on the exogenous aggregate shock. For discretized processes of z and m, the equilibrium under bounded rationality with the above rules becomes computable. I use these rules to solve for the optimal policy functions and then simulate the economy and compute equilibrium prices pt in every period t. The simulated economy allows price series are then used to update the coefficients of the log-linear rules. I stop the procedure when the coefficients have converged.

50

MATTHIAS MEIER APPENDIX E: ADDITIONAL INFORMATION ON THE MODEL CALIBRATION

Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006) targets the spike investment shares, but also persistence of investment rates and the correlation of investment rates with idiosyncratic productivity, when estimating a richer specification of capital adjustment costs including convex adjustment costs. I exclude the latter two moments because they may depend sensitively on the specific time to build setup. Nonetheless, the model matches these moments reasonably well with a persistence of 1.6% (empirically 5.8%), and a productivity correlation of 24% (empirically 14%). An alternative strategy to calibrate adjustment costs is to target cross-sectional skewness and kurtosis of investment rates, see Bachmann and Bayer (2013). In fact, our calibrated model closely matches these moments in the data: skewness/kurtosis in the model are 5.1/48.3, while in a balanced panel of Census data these are 6.5/67.4 for total investment and 5.5/47.9 for equipment investment, see Kehrig and Vincent (2016). Since skewness and kurtosis monotonically increase in the adjustment cost parameters, this indicates the calibrated adjustment costs may be too low. TABLE VII calibration targets

Model

Data

18.6% 1.8%

19.1% 1.8%

0.016 0.14

-0.007 0.22

5.1 48.3

4.9 43.4

Targeted (LRD) Positive spikes Negative spikes Non-targeted (LRD) Persistence Productivity correlation Non-targeted (Census) Skewness Kurtosis

Notes: All moments relate to annual investment rates computed as I/K. Positive and negative spikes denote the share of investment rates larger than 20% and smaller than -20%, resp. LRD moments are from Cooper, Haltiwanger (2006), Census moments are from Kehrig, Vincent (2016). Alternative data sources used to calibrate and estimate similar models are the IRS tax data, see, e.g., Winberry (2016b), and Compustat data, see, e.g., Bloom (2009). Both datasets are at the firm-level. The IRS does includes only positive investments, and Compustat is biased to large private firms. The main disadvantage of the LRD dataset is that it covers manufacturing only.

51

TIME TO BUILD AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE APPENDIX F: ADDITIONAL RESULTS FROM THE MODEL SIMULATION

Figure 11: Further responses to a supply chain disruption Order backlog 88 87 86 85

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0.34 0.32 0.3 0.28 0.26 0.24 0.22 0.2 0

4

8

12

16

20

24

Quarters Notes: The sub-figures show impulse responses to a supply chain disruption that lengthens time to build by one month starting from steady state. ‘Direct channel’ denotes the impulse responses when aggregate TFP changes are eliminated through opposing aggregate productivity (z) shocks. Aggregate TFP is computed as T F P = log(Yt ) − α log(Kt ) − ν log(Lt ). Inaction measures the share of firms without outstanding orders that do not make a new order in a given period. The order backlog is the total of investment orders outstanding for delivery.

52

MATTHIAS MEIER

Figure 12: Partial equilibrium responses to a supply chain disruption 7

5

6.5

0 -5

6 -10 5.5 5

Total response Direct channel

-15 0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0.5

-20

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

0.2

0 0

-0.5 -1

-0.2

-1.5 -2

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

-0.4

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

Notes: The sub-figures show impulse responses to a supply chain disruption that lengthens time to build by one month starting from steady state. ‘Direct channel’ denotes the impulse responses when aggregate TFP changes are eliminated through opposing aggregate productivity (z) shocks. Aggregate TFP is computed as T F P = log(Yt ) − α log(Kt ) − ν log(Lt ).

Time to Build and the Business Cycle

Mar 9, 2018 - ering time to build as market equilibrating mechanism, see Carlton (1979, 1983), both changes in supply and demand affect time to build. In this paper, I focus on disruptions to the supply chain of capital good producers as driver of time to build.Using firm-level data, I show that time to build of those firms ...

2MB Sizes 0 Downloads 121 Views

Recommend Documents

Time to Build and the Business Cycle
Nov 24, 2017 - required intermediate goods. The ordered capital goods are ..... modeled as shocks to the matching technology on the intermediate goods market, cause fluctuations in time to build. 4.1. ..... Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrat

Search in the labor market and the real business cycle
Existing models of the business cycle have been incapable of explaining many of the stylized facts that characterize the US labor market. The standard real business cycle model is modified by introducing two-sided search in the labor market as an eco

SLIM: Short Cycle Time and Low Inventory in ...
IBM Korea, Inc., MMAA Building, Dogok-dong, Gangnam-gu, Seoul, Korea 467–12. Leachman and .... time, that is, the sum of times required for machine processing and material ...... through a learning curve of cycle time in the first months of a ...

2.0 The Architecture Business Cycle -
“Software architecture is a result of technical, business, and social influences. Its existence in turn affects ..... target system or application? .... elements that do not affect how they use, are used by, relate to, or interact with other elemen

Entry and Exit of Manufacturing Plants over the Business Cycle
This paper analyzes the plant-level entry and exit over the business cycle. ... and Productivity in Tokyo, the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Federal Reserve Bank of ... productive plants—those that could have survived in good times—to sh

Unemployment and Endogenous Reallocation over the Business Cycle
Using the solutions for zr and zs we provide a decomposition of the evolution ... unemployment during the reallocation process, this friction is the only one ... such that (almost) all islands are home to a continuum of workers of various measure.

Unemployment and Endogenous Reallocation over the Business Cycle
Keywords: Unemployment, Business Cycle, Search, Reallocation. ... might decide not to search for jobs on offer, but rest until the state of their labor market ...

Involuntary Unemployment and the Business Cycle
Jun 11, 2012 - In addition, the model does well at accounting for the response of ... other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. ...... where dut ut u and ut is a small deviation from steady state unemployment, u: Substi-.

Policy Risk and the Business Cycle
We directly measure risk from aggregate data and find a moderate .... is fundamentally demand-driven in the short run, this increase in markups is contractionary.

Hours and Employment Over the Business Cycle: A ... - Giuseppe Fiori
Nov 8, 2017 - Intuitively, total output produced by firms must be equal to the sum of market consumption, investment in physical capital, the costs associated to job creation, the purchase of goods from the government, and the real cost of changing p

Employment Duration and Match Quality over the Business Cycle
race, education, and whether the job is protected by a union. ...... technology shock that is cohort-specific.21 Second, the change in job-to-job transition rate.

2.0 The Architecture Business Cycle -
“Software architecture is a result of technical, business, and social influences. ... built from it can enable a company to establish a foothold in a particular market ...

Involuntary Unemployment and the Business Cycle
11 Jun 2012 - Recently, the unemployment rate and the labor force participation rate have been dis- .... view of the family, households are assumed to have no access to loan markets, while families ...... Monthly observations on the unemployment and

labor market institutions and the business cycle ... - SSRN papers
2 Universidad de Navarra, Graduate Institute of International Studies; e-mail: [email protected] ... Giuseppe Bertola (Università di Torino) and Julián Messina.

Hours and Employment Over the Business Cycle: A ... - Giuseppe Fiori
Nov 8, 2017 - We show that an estimated business cycle model with search-and-matching frictions and a neoclassical hours-supply decision cannot account for the cyclical behavior of U.S. hours and employment and their comovement with macroeconomic var

Employment Duration and Match Quality over the Business Cycle
We thank seminar and conference participants at the CEF conference in ... If a worker has a better match with a particular firm compared to another .... The contrasting effect on different types of separations calls for a theoretical interpreta- tion

Policy Risk and the Business Cycle
Oct 3, 2014 - Policy Risk and the Business Cycle: Online Appendix. Benjamin Born∗ ..... degrees of freedom as proposal density for θn,l, ql. ( θn,l|θn,−l,xT ).

Uncertainty, Wages, and the Business Cycle
Apr 29, 2016 - influences job creation by affecting the present discounted value of the stream of wage payments. As we illustrate in a simple three-period model, .... 6 For example, in 1948 the United Auto Workers (UAW) agreement with General Motors

Appendix: “Time to build and the real-options channel ...
1.2 Alternative measure of economic time to build . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4. 1.3 Permit ... built in a factory and transported to the site to be joined together on a permanent ...