What Happens When Wal-Mart Comes to Town: An Empirical Analysis of the Discount Retailing Industry Author(s): Panle Jia Reviewed work(s): Source: Econometrica, Vol. 76, No. 6 (Nov., 2008), pp. 1263-1316 Published by: The Econometric Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/40056507 . Accessed: 18/01/2012 18:10 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

The Econometric Society is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Econometrica.

http://www.jstor.org

Econometrica, Vol. 76, No. 6 (November, 2008), 1263-1316

WHATHAPPENS WHEN WAL-MARTCOMES TO TOWN: AN EMPIRICALANALYSISOF THE DISCOUNT RETAILINGINDUSTRY By Panle Jia1 In the past few decades multistore retailers, especially those with 100 or more stores, have experienced substantial growth. At the same time, there is widely reported public outcry over the impact of these chain stores on other retailers and local communities. This paper develops an empirical model to assess the impact of chain stores on other discount retailers and to quantify the size of the scale economies within a chain. The model has two key features. First, it allows for flexible competition patterns among all players. Second, for chains, it incorporates the scale economies that arise from operating multiple stores in nearby regions. In doing so, the model relaxes the commonly used assumption that entry in different markets is independent. The lattice theory is exploited to solve this complicated entry game among chains and other discount retailers in a large number of markets. It is found that the negative impact of Kmart's presence on Wal-Mart's profit was much stronger in 1988 than in 1997, while the opposite is true for the effect of Wal-Mart's presence on Kmart's profit. Having a chain store in a market makes roughly 50% of the discount stores unprofitable. Wal-Mart's expansion from the late 1980s to the late 1990s explains about 40-50% of the net change in the number of small discount stores and 30-40% for all other discount stores. Scale economies were important for Wal-Mart, but less so for Kmart, and the magnitude did not grow proportionately with the chains' sizes. Keywords:

Chain, entry, spatial correlation, Wal-Mart, lattice.

Bowman's [in a small town in Georgia] is the eighth "main street" business to close since For the first time in seventy- three years the big corner store is Wal-Mart came to town empty. Up Against the Wal-MartArcher and Taylor (1994) There is ample evidence that a small business need not fail in the face of competition from large discount stores. In fact, the presence of a large discount store usually acts as a magnet, keeping local shoppers. . . and expanding the market Morrison Cain, Vice President of International Mass Retail Association lrThispaper is a revision of Chapter 1 of my thesis. I am deeply indebted to my committee members - Steven Berry, Penny Goldberg, Hanming Fang, and Philip Haile - for their continual support and encouragement. Special thanks go to Pat Bayer and Alvin Klevorick, who have been very generous with their help. I also thank the editor, three anonymous referees, Donald Andrews, Pat Bajari, Donald Brown, Judy Chevalier, Tom Holmes, Yuichi Kitamura, Ariel Pakes, Herbert Scarf, and seminar participants at Boston University, Columbia University, Duke University, Harvard, MIT, Northwestern University, NYU, Princeton, Stanford University, UCLA, UCSD, University of Chicago, University of Michigan, University of Minnesota, University of Pennsylvania, and participants of the 2006 Review of Economic Studies European Meetings in Oslo, Essex, and Tel Aviv for many helpful comments. Financial support from the Cowles Foundation Prize and a Horowitz Foundation Fellowship is gratefully acknowledged. All errors are my own. Comments are welcome. © 2008 The Econometric Society

DOI: 10.3982/ECTA6649

1264

PANLEJIA 1. INTRODUCTION

The landscape of the U.S. retail industry has changed considerably over the past few decades as the result of two closely related trends. One is the rise of discountretailing;the other is the increasingprevalenceof large retail chains. In fact, the discountretailingsector is almost entirelycontrolledby chains.In 1997,the top three chains (Wal-Mart,Kmart,and Target)accounted for 72.7%of total sector sales and 54.3%of the discountstores. Discount retailing is a fairly new concept, with the first discount stores appearingin the 1950s.The leading magazinefor the discountindustry,Discount Merchandiser(1988-1997), defines a modern discount store as a departmentalized retail establishmentthat makes use of self-servicetechniques to sell a largevarietyof hardgoods and soft goods at uniquelylow margins.23Over the span of several decades, the sector has emerged from the fringe of the retail industryand become one of the major sectors.4From 1960 to 1997, the total sales revenue of discountstores, in real terms, increased 15.6 times, compared with an increaseof 2.6 times for the entire retail industry. As the discountretailingsector continuesto grow,oppositionfrom other retailers,especiallysmallones, begins to mount.The criticstend to associatediscounters and other big retailerswith small-townproblemscaused by the closing of small firms,such as the decline of downtownshoppingdistricts,eroded tax bases, decreased employment,and the disintegrationof closely knit communities. Partlybecause tax money is used to restore the blighted downtown business districtsand to lure the businessof big retailerswith variousforms of economic developmentsubsidies,the effect of big retailerson small firmsand local communitieshas become a matterof publicconcern.5My firstgoal in this paper is to quantifythe impactof national discount chains on the profitability and entry and exit decisions of small retailersfrom the late 1980s to the late 1990s. The second salient feature of retail developmentin the past severaldecades, includingin the discount sector, is the increasingdominance of large chains. In 1997, retail chainswith 100 or more stores accountedfor 0.07%of the total numberof firms,yet they controlled21% of the establishmentsand accounted for 37% of sales and 46% of retail employment.6Since the late 1960s, their share of the retail market more than doubled. In spite of the dominance of 2See the annual report, "The True Look of the Discount Industry," in the June 1962 issue of Discount Merchandiser for the definition of the discount retailing, the sales and store numbers for the top 30 largest firms, as well as the industry sales and total number of discount stores. J According to Annual Benchmark Report for Retail Trade and Food Services (U.S. Census Bureau (1993-1997)), the average markup for regular department stores was 27.9%, while the average markup for discount stores was 20.9%. Both markups increased slightly from 1998 to 2000. *The other retail sectors are building materials, food stores, automotive dealers, apparel, furniture, eating and drinking places, and miscellaneous retail. 'See Shils (1997). 6See U.S. Census Bureau (1997).

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1265

chain stores, few empiricalstudies (except Holmes (2005) and Smith (2004)) have quantifiedthe potential advantagesof chains over single-unit firms, in part because of the modeling difficulties.7In entry models, for example, the store entry decisions of multiunitchains are related across markets.Most of the literatureassumesthat entrydecisionsare independentacrossmarketsand focuses on competition among firmswithin each local market.My second objective here is to extend the entry literatureby relaxingthe independence assumptionand to quantifythe advantageof operatingmultipleunitsby explicitly modelingchains'entrydecisions in a large numberof markets. The model has two key features. First,it allowsfor flexiblecompetitionpatterns among all retailers.Second, it incorporatesthe potential benefits of locating multiple stores near one another. Such benefits, which I group as "the chain effect," can arise throughseveral differentchannels.For example,there may be significantscale economies in the distributionsystem. Stores located near each other can split advertisingcosts or employee trainingcosts, or they can share knowledgeabout the specificfeatures of local markets. The chain effect causes profits of stores in the same chain to be spatially related. As a result, choosing store locations to maximizetotal profit is complicated, since with N marketsthere are 2N possible location choices. In the currentapplication,there are more than 2000 marketsand the numberof posWhen severalchainscompete againsteach sible location choices exceeds 10600. Nash for the other, solving equilibriumbecomes furtherinvolved,as firmsbalance the gains from the chain effect against competition from rivals.I tackle this problem in several steps. First, I transformthe profit-maximizationproblem into a search for the fixed points of the necessaryconditions. This transformation shifts the focus of the problem from a set with 2N elements to the set of fixed points of the necessaryconditions. The latter has a much smaller dimension, and is well behaved with easy-to-locate minimum and maximum points. Having dealt with the problem of dimensionality,I take advantage of the supermodularityproperty of the game to search for the Nash equilibrium.Finally, in estimatingthe parameters,I adopt the econometric technique proposed by Conley (1999) to address the issue of cross-sectionaldependence. The algorithmproposed above exploits the game's supermodularitystructure to solve a complicatedproblem. However, it has a couple of limitations. First, it is not applicableto oligopoly games with three or more chains.8The 7I discuss Holmes (2005) in detail below. Smith (2004) estimated the demand cross-elasticities between stores of the same firm and found that mergers between the largest retail chains would increase the price level by up to 7.4%. 8Entry games are not supermodular in general, as the competition effect is usually assumed to be negative. However, with only two chains, we can redefine the strategy space for one player to be the negative of the original space. Then the game associated with the new strategy space is supermodular, provided that each chain's profit function is supermodular in its own strategy. See Section 5.2 for details. This would not work for oligopoly games with three or more chains.

1266

PANLEJIA

algorithm is also not applicable to situations with negative chain effects, which might happen if a chain's own stores in different markets compete for sales and the negative business stealing effect overwhelms the positive spillover effect. However, the frame is general enough to accommodate business stealing among a chain's own stores within a market. See Section 6.2.5 for further discussions. Nishida (2008) is a nice application that studies retail chains in the Japanese markets. The analysis exploits a unique data set I collected that covers the entire discount retailing industry from 1988 to 1997, during which the two major national chains were Kmart and Wal-Mart.9 The results indicate that the negative impact of Kmart's presence on Wal-Mart's profit was much stronger in 1988 than in 1997, while the opposite is true for the effect of Wal-Mart's presence on Kmart's profit. Having a chain store in a market makes roughly 50% of the discount stores unprofitable. Wal-Mart's expansion from the late 1980s to the late 1990s explains about 37-55% of the net change in the number of small discount stores and 34-41% for all other discount stores. Scale economies were important to Wal-Mart, but less so for Kmart, and their importance did not grow proportionately with the size of the chains. Finally, government subsidies to either chains or small firms in this industry are not likely to be effective in increasing the number of firms or the level of employment. This paper complements a recent study by Holmes (2005) which analyzes the diffusion process of Wal-Mart stores. Holmes's approach is appealing because he derives the magnitude of the economies of density, a concept similar to the chain effect in this paper, from the dynamic expansion process. In contrast, I identify the chain effect from the stores' geographic clustering pattern. My approach abstracts from a number of important dynamic considerations. For example, it does not allow firms to delay store openings because of credit constraints nor does it allow for any preemption motive as the chains compete and make simultaneous entry decisions. A dynamic model that incorporates both the competition effects and the chain effect would be ideal. However, given the great difficulty of estimating the economies of density in a single-agent dynamic model, as Holmes (2005) shows, it is currently infeasible to estimate a dynamic model that also incorporates the strategic interactions within chains and between chains and small retailers. Since one of my main goals is to analyze the competition effects and perform policy evaluations, I adopt a three-stage model. In the first stage, or the "pre-chain" period, small retailers make entry decisions without anticipating the future entry of Kmart or Wal-Mart. In the second stage, Kmart or Wal-Mart emerges in the retail industry and optimally locates their stores across the entire set of markets. In the third stage, existing small firms decide whether to continue their business, while potential entrants 9During the sample period, Target was a regional store that competed mostly in the big metropolitan areas in the Midwest with few stores in the sample. See the data section for more details.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1267

decide whether to enter the market and compete with the chains. The extension of the currentframeworkto a dynamicmodel is left for future research. This paper contributes to the entry literature initiated by Bresnahan and Reiss (1991, 1990) and Berry (1992), where researchersinfer the firms' underlyingprofit functionsby observingtheir equilibriumentry decisions across a large number of markets.To the extent that retail chains can be treated as multiproductfirmswhose differentiatedproductsare stores with different locations, this paper relates to several recent empiricalentry papers that endogenize firms' product choices upon entry. For example, Mazzeo (2002) considered the quality choices of highwaymotels and Seim (2006) studied how video stores soften competition by choosing different locations. Unlike these studies, in which each firmchooses only one product,I analyzethe behaviorof multiproductfirmswhose productspaces are potentiallylarge. This paper is also related to a large literatureon spatialcompetitionin retail markets,for example,Pinkse,Slade, and Brett (2002), Smith(2004), and Davis (2006). All of these models take the firms'locations as given and focus on price or quantitycompetition.I adopt the opposite approach.Specifically,I assume a parametricform for the firms'reduced-formprofit functionsfrom the stage competition and examine how they compete spatiallyby balancingthe chain effect againstthe competitioneffect of rivals'actions on their own profits. Like manyother discrete-choicemodels with complete information,the entry games generallyallow multiple equilibria.There is a very active literature on estimatingdiscrete-choicegames that explicitlyaddressesthe issue of multiple equilibria.For example, Tamer(2003) proposed an exclusion condition that leads to point identificationin two-by-twogames. Andrews,Berry,and Jia (2004), Chernozhukov,Hong, and Tamer(2007), Pakes, Porter,Ho, and Ishii (2005), Romano and Shaikh (2006), and others analyzed bound estimations that exploit inequalityconstraintsderived from necessaryconditions. Bajari, Hong, and Ryan (2007) examined the identification and estimation of the equilibriumselection mechanismas well as the payoff function. Cilibertoand Tamer(2006) studied multiple equilibriain the airline markets and used the methodologyof Chernozhukov,Hong, and Tamer(2007) to constructthe confidence region. Ackerbergand Gowrisankaran(2007) analyzedbanks' adoptions of the automated clearinghouse electronic payment system, assuming each networkwas in one of the two extreme equilibriawith a certainprobability. In the currentapplication,I estimate the parametersusing the equilibrium that is most profitablefor Kmart,and also provide the parameterestimates at two other differentequilibriaas a robustnesscheck. This paper's algorithmis an applicationof the lattice theory, in particular Tarski's(1955) fixedpoint theorem and Topkis's(1978) monotonicitytheorem. Milgromand Shannon (1994) derived a necessaryand sufficientcondition for the solution set of an optimizationproblemto be monotonic in the parameters of the problem. Athey (2002) extended the monotone comparativestatics to situationswith uncertainty.

1268

PANLEJIA

Finally, this paper is part of the growingliteratureon Wal-Mart,which includes Stone (1995), Basker (2005b, 2005a), Hausman and Leibtag (2005), Neumark,Zhang, and Ciccarella(2005), and Zhu and Singh (2007). The remainderof the paper is structuredas follows. Section 2 providesbackgroundinformationabout the discountretailingsector. Section 3 describesthe data set and Section 4 discussesthe model. Section 5 proposes a solution algorithmfor the game between chains and small firmswhen there is a large number of markets.Section 6 explainsthe estimationapproach.Section 7 presents the results. Section 8 concludes. The Appendix outlines the technical details not covered in Section 5. Data and programsare provided as supplemental material(Jia (2008)). 2. INDUSTRYBACKGROUND

Discount retailingis one of the most dynamicsectors in the retail industry. Table I displayssome statisticsfor the industryfrom 1960 to 1997. The sales revenue for this sector, in 2004 U.S. dollars, skyrocketedfrom 12.8 billion in 1960 to 198.7 billion in 1997. In comparison,the sales revenue for the entire retail industryincreasedonly modestlyfrom 511.2 billion to 1313.3billion during the same period. The number of discount stores multipliedfrom 1329 to 9741, while the numberof firmsdroppedfrom 1016 to 230. Chain stores dominate the discount retailingsector, as they do other retail sectors. In 1970, the 39 largest discount chains, with 25 or more stores each, operated 49.3% of the discount stores and accounted for 41.4% of total sales. By 1989,both shareshad increasedto roughly88%. In 1997, the top 30 chains controlled about 94% of total stores and sales. The principal advantages of chain stores include the central purchasing unit's abilityto buy on favorableterms and to foster specializedbuyingskills; the possibilityof sharingoperatingand advertisingcosts among multipleunits; the freedom to experimentin one selling unit without risk to the whole operation. Stores also frequentlysharetheir privateinformationabout local markets and learn from one another'smanagerialpractices.Finally,chainscan achieve TABLEI The Discount Industry From 1960to 1997a

Year

1960 1980 1989 1997

Number of Discount Stores

1329 8311 9406 9741

Total Sales (2004 $, billions)

12.8 119.4 123.4 198.7

Average Store Size (thousand ft2)

Number of Firms

38.4 66.8 66.5 79.2

1016 584 427 230

aSource: Various issues of Discount Merchandiser.The numbers include only traditional discount stores. Wholesale clubs, supercenters, and special retailing stores are excluded.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1269

economies of scale by combiningwholesaling and retailingoperationswithin the same businessunit. Until the late 1990s,the two most importantnationalchainswere Kmartand Wal-Mart.Each firmopened its firststore in 1962.The firstKmartwas opened by the varietychain Kresge.Kmartstoreswere a new experimentthat provided consumerswith quality merchandiseat prices considerablylower than those of regularretail stores. To reduce advertisingcosts and to minimizecustomer service, these stores emphasized nationally advertisedbrand-nameproducts. Consumersatisfactionwas guaranteedand all goods could be returnedfor a refund or an exchange (see Vance and Scott (1994, p. 32)). These practices were an instant success, and Kmartgrew rapidlyin the 1970s and 1980s. By the early 1990s, the firm had more than 2200 stores nationwide. In the late 1980s,Kmarttried to diversifyand pursuedvariousforms of specialtyretailing in pharmaceuticalproducts,sportinggoods, office supplies,buildingmaterials, and so on. The attemptwas unsuccessful,and Kmarteventuallydivested itself of these interests by the late 1990s. Strugglingwith its managementfailures throughoutthe 1990s, Kmartmaintainedroughlythe same numberof stores; the opening of new stores offset the closing of existingones. Unlike Kmart,which was initially supported by an established retail firm, Wal-Martstartedfrom scratchand grew relativelyslowly in the beginning.To avoid direct competitionwith other discounters,it focused on small towns in southernstates where there were few competitors.Startingin the early 1980s, the firmbegan an aggressiveexpansionprocess that averaged140 store openings per year. In 1991, Wal-Martreplaced Kmartas the largest discounter.By 1997,Wal-Marthad 2362 stores (not includingthe wholesale clubs) in all states, includingAlaska and Hawaii. As the discounterscontinuedto grow,other retailersstartedto feel their impact. There are extensive media reports on the controversiesassociated with the impactof large chains on small retailersand on local communitiesin general. As earlyas 1994,the United States House of Representativesconvened a hearingtitled "The Impact of Discount Superstoreson Small Businesses and Local Communities"(House Committeeon SmallBusiness (1994)). Witnesses from mass retail associationsand small retail councils testified, but no legislation followed, partly due to a lack of concrete evidence. In April 2004, the Universityof California,Santa Barbara,held a conference that centered on the culturaland social impactof the leading discounter,Wal-Mart.In November 2004, both CNBC and PBS aireddocumentariesthat displayedthe changes Wal-Marthad broughtto society. 3. DATA

The available data sets dictate the modeling approachused in this paper. Hence, I discussthem before introducingthe model.

1270

PANLEJIA

3.1. Data Sources There are three main data sources. The data on discount chains come from an annual directory published by Chain Store Guide (1988-1997). The directory covers all operating discount stores of more than 10,000 ft2. For each store, the directory lists its name, size, street address, telephone number, store format, and firm affiliation.10The U.S. industry classification system changed from the Standard Industrial Classification System (SIC) to the North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) in 1998. To avoid potential inconsistencies in the industry definition, I restrict the sample period to the 10 years before the classification change. As first documented in Basker (2005a), the directory was not fully updated for some years. Fortunately, it was fairly accurate for the years used in this study. See Appendix A for details. The second data set, the County Business Patterns (CBP), tabulates at the county level the number of establishments by employment size category by industry sectors.11 There are eight retail sectors at the two-digit SIC level: building materials and garden supplies, general merchandise stores (or discount stores), food stores, automotive dealers and service stations, apparel and accessory stores, furniture and home-furnishing stores, eating and drinking places, and miscellaneous retail. Both Kmart and Wal-Mart are classified as firms in the general merchandise sector. I focus on two groups of retailers that compete with them: (a) small general merchandise stores with 19 or fewer employees; (b) all retailers in the general merchandise sector. I also experimented unsuccessfully with modeling the competition between these chains and retailers in a group of sectors. The model is too stylized to accommodate the vast differences between retailers in different sectors. The number of retailers in the "pre-chain" period comes from 1978 CBP data. Data prior to 1977 are in tape format and not readily usable. I downloaded the county business pattern data from the Geospatial and Statistical Data Center of University of Virginia.12 Data on county level population were downloaded from the websites of the U.S. Census Bureau (before 1990) and the Missouri State Census Data Center (after 1990). Other county level demographic and retail sales data are from various years of the decennial census and the economic census. 10The directory stopped providing store size information in 1997 and changed the inclusion criterion to 20,000 ft2 in 1998. The store formats include membership stores, regional offices, and, in later years, distribution centers. 11CBP reports data at the establishment level, not the firm level. As it does not include information on firm ownership, I do not know which establishments are owned by the same firm. Given this data limitation, I have assumed that, in contrast to chain stores, all small retailers are single-unit firms. Throughout this paper, the terms "small firms" and "small stores" will be used interchangeably. 12Theweb address (as of January 2008) is http://fisher.lib.virginia.edu/collections/stats/ccdb/.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1271

3.2. MarketDefinitionand Data Description In this paper, a market is defined as a county. Although the Chain Store Guide (1988-1997) publishes the detailed street addresses for the discount stores, informationabout smallfirmsis availableonly at the countylevel. Many of the market size variables, like retail sales, are also available only at the county level. I focus on counties with an average population between 5000 and 64,000 from 1988 to 1997. There are 2065 such counties among a total of 3140 in the United States. Accordingto Vance and Scott (1994), the minimumcounty population for a Wal-Martstore was 5000 in the 1980s, while Kmartconcentrated in places with a much larger population. 9% of all U.S. counties were smallerthan 5000 and were unlikelyto be a potential marketfor either chain, while 25% of them were large metropolitanareas with an averagepopulation of 64,000or more. These big counties typicallyincludedmultipleself-contained shoppingareas,and consumerswere unlikelyto travelacrossthe entire county to shop. The marketconfigurationin these big counties was very complexwith a large numberof competitorsand many marketniches. Defining a county as a marketis likely to be problematicfor these counties. Given the data limitation, I model entry decisions in those 2065 small- to medium-sizedcounties, and treat the chain stores in the other counties as exogenouslygiven. The limitation of this approachis that the spillovereffect from the chain stores located in large counties is also treated as exogenous. Using a county as a marketdefinition also assumes away the cross-bordershopping behavior. In future research, any data on the geographicpatternsof consumers'shoppingbehavior would enable a more reasonablemarketdefinition. During the sample period, there were two national chains: Kmart and Wal-Mart.The third largest chain, Target,had 340 stores in 1988 and about 800 stores in 1997. Most of them were located in metropolitan areas in the Midwest,with on average fewer than 20 stores in the counties studied here. I do not include Targetin the analysis. In the sample, only 8 counties had two Kmart stores and 49 counties had two Wal-Martstores in 1988;the figureswere 8 and 66 counties, respectively, in 1997. The current specification abstractsfrom the choice of the number of opening stores and considers only market entry decisions, as there is not enough variation in the data to identify the profit of the second store in the same market.In Section 6.2.5, 1 discuss how to extend the algorithmto allow for multiple stores in any given market. TableII presents summarystatisticsof the sample for 1978, 1988, and 1997. The averagecountypopulationwas 21,470 in 1978.It increasedby 5% between 1978 and 1988, and by 8% between 1988 and 1997. Retail sales per capita, in 1984 dollars,was $4070 in 1977. It droppedto $3690 in 1988, but recoveredto $4050in 1997.The averagepercentageof urbanpopulationwas 30%in 1978.It barelychanged between 1978 and 1988, but increasedto 33% in 1997. About

1272

PANLEJIA TABLEII Summary Statistics for the Data Set3 1978

1997

1988

Variable

Std.

Mean

Mean

Std.

Mean

Std.

Population(thousand) Per capitaretail sales (1984$, thousands) Percentageof urbanpopulation Midwest(1 if in the Great Lakes, Plains, or RockyMountainregion) South (1 if Southwestor Southeast) Distance to Benton, AR (100 miles) % of countieswith Kmartstores % of countieswith Wal-Martstores Numberof discountstores with 1-19 employees Numberof all discountstores (excludingKmartand Wal-Mart) Numberof counties

21.47 4.07 0.30

13.38 1.42 0.23

22.47 3.69 0.30

14.12 1.44 0.23

24.27 4.05 0.33

15.67 2.02 0.24

0.41 0.50 6.14

0.49 0.50 3.88

0.41 0.50 6.14 0.21 0.32

0.49 0.50 3.88 0.41 0.47

0.41 0.50 6.14 0.19 0.48

0.49 0.50 3.88 0.39 0.50

4.75

2.86

3.79

2.61

3.46

2.47

4.89 2065

3.24

4.54

3.10

4.04

2.85

aSource: The population is from the website of the Missouri State Census Data Center. Retail sales are from the 1977, 1987, and 1997 Economic Census. The percentage of urban population is from the 1980, 1990, and 2000 decennial census. Region dummies are defined according to the 1990 census. The numbers of Kmart and Wal-Mart stores are from the annual reference Directoryof Discount DepartmentStores (Chain Store Guide (1988-1997)). The numbers of small discount stores and all other discount stores are from various years of the county business patterns.

one-quarterof the counties were primarilyruralwith a small urban population, which is why the average across the counties seems somewhat low. 41% of the counties were in the Midwest (which includes the Great Lakes region, the Plains region, and the Rocky Mountain region, as defined by the Bureau of Economic Analysis), and 50% of the counties were in the southern region (which includes the Southeast region and the Southwestregion), with the rest in the Far West and the Northeast regions. Kmart had stores in 21% of the counties in 1988.The numberdroppedslightlyto 19%in 1997.In comparison, Wal-Marthad stores in 32% of the counties in 1988 and 48% in 1997. 1 do not have data on the numberof Kmartand Wal-Martstores in the sample counties in 1978. Before the 1980s, Kmartwas mainlyoperating in large metropolitan areas, and Wal-Martwas only a small regional firm. I assume that in 1978, retailersin my sample counties did not face competitionfrom these two chains. In 1978, the average number of discount stores per county was 4.89. The majorityof them were quite small, as stores with 1-19 employees accounted for 4.75 of them. In 1988, the numberof discountstores (excludingKmartand Wal-Martstores) dropped to 4.54, while that of small stores (with 1-19 employees) droppedto 3.79. By 1997,these numbersfurtherdeclined to 4.04 and 3.46, respectively.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1273

4. MODELING

4.1. ModelSetup The model I develop is a three-stagegame. Stage 1 correspondsto the prechain period when only small firmscompete against each other.13They enter the market if profit after entry recovers the sunk cost. In stage 2, Kmartand Wal-Martsimultaneouslychoose store locations to maximizetheir total profits in all markets.In the last stage, existingsmallfirmsdecide whetherto continue their business,while potential entrantsdecide whether to enter the marketto compete with the chain stores and the existing small stores. Small firms are single-unitstores and only enter one market.In contrast,Kmartand Wal-Mart operate manystores and compete in multiplemarkets. This is a complete-informationgame except for one majordifference:in the first stage, small firms make entry decisions without anticipatingKmart and Wal-Martin the later period. The emergence of Kmartand Wal-Martin the second stage is an unexpectedevent for the small firms.Once Kmartand WalMarthave appearedon the stage, all firmsobtainfull knowledgeof their rivals' profitabilityand the payoffstructure.Facinga numberof existingsmallfirmsin each market,Kmartand Wal-Martmake locationchoices, takinginto consideration small retailers'adjustmentin the third stage. Finally,unprofitablesmall firms exit the market and new entrants come in. Once these entry decisions are made, firmscompete and profitsare realized.Notice that I have implicitly assumed that chains can commit to their entry decisions in the second stage and do not further adjust after the third stage. This is based on the observation that most chain stores enter with a long-termlease of the rentalproperty, and in many cases they invest considerablyin the infrastructureconstruction associatedwith establishinga big store. The three-stage model is motivated by the fact that small retailers existed long before the era of the discount chains. Accordingly,the first stage should be consideredas "historical"and the model uses this stage to fit the numberof small retailersbefore the entryof Kmartand Wal-Mart.Stages 2 and 3 happen roughlyconcurrently:small stores adjustquicklyonce they observe big chains' decisions. 4.2. TheProfitFunction One way to obtain the profit function is to start from primitiveassumptions of supply and demand in the retail markets, and derive the profit functions from the equilibriumconditions. Without any price, quantity,or sales data, and with very limited informationon store characteristics,this approachis extremely demandingon data and relies heavily on the primitiveassumptions. 13In the empirical application, I also estimate the model using all discount stores, not just small stores. See Section 7 for details.

1274

PANLEJIA

Instead, I follow the convention in the entry literature and assume that firms' profit functions take a linear form and that profits decline in the presence of rivals. In the first stage, or the pre-chain period, profit for a small store that operates in market m is

(1)

J7° = X°mfi,+8SS ln(iV° ) + 7We°m + pi," - SC,

where s stands for small stores. Profit from staying outside the market is normalized to 0 for all players. There are several components in the small store's profit /7°m: the observed market size X^Ps that is parameterized by demand shifters, like population, the extent of urbanization, and so forth; the competition effect 8SSln(A^°m)that is monotonically increasing (in the absolute value) in the number of competing stores NSjm;the unobserved profit shock y/\ - p2e°m+ pyfsmyknown to the firms but unknown to the econometrician; and the sunk cost of entry SC. As will become clear below, both the vector of observed market size variables Xm and the coefficients /3 are allowed to vary across different players. For example, Kmart might have some advantage in the Midwest, Wal-Mart stores might be more profitable in markets close to their headquarters, and small retailers might find it easier to survive in rural areas. The unobserved profit shock has two elements: e°m,the market-level profit shifter that affects all firms operating in the market, and 7j°m,a firm-specific profit shock. e°mis assumed to be independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) across markets, while rfsm is assumed to be i.i.d. across both firms and markets. y/1 - p2 (with 0 < p < 1) measures the importance of the market common shock. In principle, its impact can differ between chains and small firms. For example, the market-specific business environment - how developed the infrastructure is, whether the market has sophisticated shopping facilities, and the stance of the local community toward large corporations including big retailers - might matter more to chains than to small firms. In the baseline specification, I restrict p to be the same across all players. Relaxing it does not improve the fit much. yfsmincorporates the unobserved store level heterogeneity, including the management ability, the display style and shopping environment, and employees' morale or skills. As is standard in discrete choice models, the scale of the parameter coefficients and the variance of the error term are not separately identified. I normalize the variance of the error term to 1. In addition, I assume that both e°mand 17°m are standard normal random variables for computational convenience. In other applications, a more flexible distribution (like a mixture of normals) might be more appropriate. As mentioned above, in the pre-chain stage, the small stores make entry decisions without anticipating Kmart's and Wal-Mart's entry. As a result, N^m is only a function of (X^9 e°m,rj°m), and is independent of Kmart's and Wal-Mart's entry decisions in the second stage.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1275

To describe the choices of Kmart and Wal-Mart,let me introduce some vector variables. Let Dim e {0, 1} stand for chain i's strategy in market m, where Dim = 1 if chain i operates a store in market m and Dim = 0 otherwise. Di = {A,i, . . . 9DiM) is a vector indicating chain i's location choices for the entire set of markets.Djm denotes rival ;'s strategyin market m. Finally,let Zm\designatethe distancefrom marketm to market/ in miles and let Zm = {2mi, . . . , ZmM}.

The following equation system describes the payoff structure during the "post-chain"period when small firms compete against the chains.14The first equation is the profit for chains, the second equation is the profit for small firms,and the last equation defines how the marketunobservedprofit shocks evolve over time: (2)

Xm,Zm,em,r]iim) nim(Di, Djjn,NStm; = DUm* \xmPi + 8ijDjtm+ 8isln(Ns,m+ 1) + 5» £

~ ~T~ + Vl P2em+ PVi,m,

«,j € {k, W],

= Xmps+ J^ 8siDiim + Sssln(NStm) i=k,w

- SC * l[new entrant], p € [0, 1], + y/\ - p2em+ pr]Sym £m= re°m+ y/\ - r2em, r e [0, 1], where k denotes Kmart,w denotes Wal-Mart,and s denotes smallfirms.In the following,I discusseach equation in turn. First,notice the presence of Dt in chain i's profiti7/,m(): profitin marketm depends on the number of stores chain i has in other markets.Chains maximize their total profitsin all markets£m nim, internalizingthe spillovereffect among stores in differentlocations. As mentioned above, Xm/3iis indexedby i so that the marketsize can have a differentialimpacton firms'profitability.The competitioneffect from the rival chain is capturedby 6yD;>, where Djm = 1 if rival; operates a store in market m. 8isln(NSym + 1) denotes the effect of small firmson chain i's profit.The additionof 1 in ln(NStm + 1) is used to avoid lnOfor marketswithout any small firms.The log form allowsthe incrementalcompetitioneffect to taperoff when there are many small firms. In equilibrium,the number of small firms in the 141 treat stage 2 and stage 3 as happening "concurrently" by assuming that both chains and small firms share the same market-level shock em.

1276

PANLEJIA

last stage is a function of Kmart'sand Wal-Mart'sdecisions:Ns,m(Dk,m, Dw,m). When makinglocation choices, the chains take into considerationthe impact of small firms'reactionson their own profits. The chain effect is denoted by SiiJ2^m(Du/zmi), the benefit that having stores in other marketsgenerates for the profit in marketm. 8u is assumedto be nonnegative. Nearby stores split the costs of operation, delivery, and advertisingto achieve scale economies. They also share knowledgeof local markets and learnfrom one another'smanagerialsuccess.All these factorssuggest that havingstores nearbybenefits the operationin marketm and that the benefit declines with the distance. Following Bajari and Fox (2005), I divide the spillover effect by the distance between the two markets Zm/,so that profit in market m is increased by 8u(Ditl/Zml)if there is a store in market / that is Zmimiles away.This simple formulationserves two purposes. First, it is a parsimoniousway to capture the fact that it might be increasinglydifficultto benefit from stores that are farther away.Second, the econometric technique exploited in the estimation requires the dependence among observationsto die awaysufficientlyfast. I also assume that the chain effect takes place among counties whose centroids are within 50 miles, or roughlyan area that expands 75 miles in each direction. Includingcounties within 100 miles increases the computingtime with little change in the parameters. This paper focuses on the chain effect that is "localized"in nature. Some chain effects are "global";for example,the gain that arisesfrom a chain'sability to buy a large volume at a discount.The latter benefits affect all stores the same and cannot be separatelyidentifiedfrom the constant of the profitfunction. Hence, the estimates Su should be interpretedas a lower bound to the actual advantagesenjoyedby a chain. As in small firms' profit function, chain /'s profit shock contains two elements: the market shifter common to all firms sm and the firm-specificshock y]ittn.Both are assumedto have a standardnormaldistribution. Small firms'profit in the last stage 775,mis similar to the pre-chainperiod, ssiDi,mcaptures the impact of Kmart except for two elements. First, J2i=k,w and Wal-Marton small firms.Second, only new entrantspay the sunk cost SC. The last equation describesthe evolution of the market-levelerror term sm over time. em is a pure white noise that is independent across period, r measures the persistence of the unobservedmarket features. Notice that both t and the sunkcost SC can generate historydependence,but they have different implications.Consider two markets A and B that have a similar market size today with the same numberof chain stores: XA = XB, DiA = DiB, i e {k, w}. Market A used to be much bigger, but has graduallydecreased in size. The opposite is true for market B: it was smaller before, but has expanded over time. If history does not matter (that is, both r and SC are zero), these two marketsshould on averagehave the same numberof small stores. However,if SC is important,then marketA should have more small stores that entered in the past and have maintainedtheir business after the entry of chain stores. In

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1277

otherwords,big sunkcost impliesthat everythingelse equal, marketsthatwere bigger historicallycarrymore small stores in the currentperiod. On the other hand, if r is important,then some marketshave more small stores throughout the time, but there are no systematicpatternsbetween the market size in the previousperiod and the numberof stores in the currentperiod, as the history dependence is driven by the unobservedmarket shock sm that is assumed to be independentof Xm. The market-level error term em makes the location choices of the chain and the numberof small firms Ns,mendogenous in the stores Dkm and DWtfn9 profitfunctions,since a large emleads to more entries of both chains and small firms.The chain effect 8u(Difi/Zmi)is also endogenous, because a large emis associatedwith a high value of Dim, which increases the profitabilityof market /, and hence leads to a high value of Dih I solve the chains' and small firms'entry decisions simultaneouslywithin the model, and requirethe model to replicatethe location patternsobservedin the data. Note that the above specificationallows very flexible competition patterns amongall the possiblefirm-paircombinations.The parametersto be estimated are {/?,,8ih 8ih p, t, SC}, i, j € {k, w, s}. 5. SOLUTIONALGORITHM

The unobserved market-levelprofit shock em9together with the chain effect 8uJ2itm(Du/Zmi), renders all of the discrete variables JV°m,Dim, Djm, Dih and Ns,mendogenous in the profitfunctions(1) and (2). Findingthe Nash equilibriumof this game is complicated. I take several steps to address this problem.Section 5.1 explainshow to solve each chain's single-agentproblem, Section 5.2 derives the solution algorithmfor the game between two chains, and Section 5.3 adds the small retailersand solves for the Nash equilibriumof the full model. 5.1. Chain i's Single-AgentProblem In this subsection,let us focus on the chain's single-agentproblem and abstractfrom competition.In the next two subsectionsI incorporatecompetition and solve the model for all players. For notational simplicity,I have suppressed the firm subscript/ and used Xm instead of XmPi + y/1 - p2em+ pr)Umin the profit function throughout this subsection.Let M denote the total numberof marketsand let D = {0, 1}M denote the choice set. An element of the set D is an M -coordinatevector D = {£>!,. . . , DM}-The profit-maximizationproblemis

max n = f)\Dm*(xm+ 8Y]-§l-)\

1278

PANLEJIA

The choice variable Dm appears in the profit function in two ways. First, it directlydetermines profit in market m: the firm earns Xm+ 5£^mCD//Zm/) if Dm= 1 and earns zero if Dm= 0. Second, the decision to open a store in marketm increasesthe profitsin other marketsthroughthe chain effect. The complexity of this maximizationproblem is twofold: first, it is a discrete problemof a large dimension.In the currentapplication,with M = 2065 and two choices for each market (enter or stay outside), the numberof possible elements in the choice set D is 22065, or roughly 10600.The naive approach that evaluates all of them to find the profit-maximizingvector(s) is infeasible. Second, the profit function is irregular:it is neither concave nor convex. Consider the functionwhere Dmtakes real values, ratherthan integers {0, 1}. The Hessian of this function is indefinite, and the usual first-ordercondition does not guarantee an optimum.15Even if one could exploit the first-ordercondition, the searchwith a large numberof choice variablesis a dauntingtask. Instead of solving the problem directly,I transformit into a search for the fixed points of the necessaryconditions for profit maximization.In particular, I exploit the lattice structureof the set of fixedpoints of an increasingfunction and propose an algorithmthat obtains an upperbound Du and a lower bound DL for the profit-maximizingvector(s). With these two bounds at hand, I evaluate all vectors that lie between them to find the profit-maximizinglocation choice. Throughoutthis paper, the comparisonbetween vectors is coordinatewise. A vector D is biggerthan vector D' if and only if every element of D is weakly bigger:D > D' if and only if Dm> D'mVm.D and Df are unorderedif neither D > Df nor D < D'. They are the same if both D > D1and D < Df. Let the profitmaximizerbe denoted D* = argmax£>€D/7(D). The optimality of D* implies that profit at D* must be (weakly) higher than the profit at any one-marketdeviation,

II(Dl...9D*m,...,D*M)>mD*l9...9Dm9...,D*M) Vm, which leads to

(3)

Vm. + D; = l[*m L 28£^Uol $£ Zml -I

The derivationof equation (3) is left to Appendix B.I. These conditions have the usual interpretationthat Xm+ 28^liim{D] / Zmi)is market m's marginal 15A symmetric matrix is positive (negative) semidefinite if and only if all the eigenvalues are nonnegative (nonpositive). The Hessian of the profit function (2) is a symmetric matrix with zero for all the diagonal elements. Its trace, which is equal to the sum of the eigenvalues, is zero. If the Hessian matrix has a positive eigenvalue, it has to have a negative one as well. There is only one possibility for the Hessian to be positive (or negative) semidefinite, which is that all the eigenvalues are 0. This is true only for the zero matrix H = 0.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1279

contributionto total profit.This equation system is not definitional;it is a set of necessaryconditionsfor the optimalvector D*. Not all vectorsthat satisfy(3) maximizeprofit,but if D* maximizesprofit,it must satisfythese constraints. Define Vm(D)= l[Xm + 2S£¥m(A/Zm/) > 0] and V(D) = {^(D), ..., VM(D)}.V(>) is a vector function that maps from D into itself: K:D -> D. It is an increasingfunction:V(Df) > V(D") wheneverD > D%as Su is assumed nonnegative. By construction,the profit maximizerD* is one of F()'s fixed points. The following theorem, proved by Tarski(1955), states that the set of fixed points of an increasingfunction that maps from a lattice into itself is a lattice, and has a greatest point and a least point. Appendix B.2 describesthe basic lattice theory. Theorem 1: Supposethat Y(X) is an increasingfunctionfrom a nonempty completelatticeX into X. (a) Theset of fixedpoints of Y(X) is nonempty,supx({JTeX,X < Y (X)}) is thegreatestfixedpoint, and infx({^ € X, Y(X) < X}) is the leastfixedpoint. (b) Theset of fixedpoints of Y(X) in X is a nonemptycompletelattice. A lattice in which each nonempty subset has a supremumand an infimum is complete. Any finite lattice is complete. A nonemptycomplete lattice has a greatest and a least element. Since the choice set D is a finite lattice, it is complete and Theorem 1 can be directly applied. Several points are worth mentioning. First, X can be a closed intervalor it can be a discrete set, as long as the set includes the greatest lower bound and the least upper bound for any of its nonempty subsets. That is, it is a complete lattice. Second, the set of fixedpoints is itself a nonemptycomplete lattice,with a greatest and a smallest point. Third,the requirementthat Y (X) is "increasing"is crucial;it cannot be replaced by assumingthat Y(X) is a monotone function. Appendix B.2 provides a counterexamplewhere the set of fixed points for a decreasingfunction is empty. Now I outline the algorithmthat delivers the greatest and the least fixed point of V(D), which are, respectively,an upper bound and a lower bound for the optimal solution vector D*. To find D*91 rely on an exhaustivesearch among the vectors lyingbetween these two bounds. Start with D° = sup(D) = {1, . . . , 1}. The supremumexists because D is a complete lattice. Define a sequence [D'}: D1 = V(D°) and D'+1= V(D'). By construction,we have D° > V(D°) = D1. Since V(-) is an increasingfunction, V(D°) > V(Dl) or Dl > D2. Iterating this process several times generates a decreasingsequence: D° > Dl > • • > Df. Given that D° has only M distinct elements and at least one element of the D vector is changed from 1 to 0 in each iteration,the process convergeswithin M steps: DT = DT+1,T D\ where Df is an arbitraryelement of the set

1280

PANLEJIA

of fixed points. Applyingthe function F() to the inequalityT times, we have

Du = VT(D°)> VT(D')= D'.

Using the dual argument,one can show that the convergentvector derived from D° = inf(D) = {0, . . . , 0} is the least element in the set of fixed points. Denote it by DL. In Appendix B.3, 1 show that startingfrom the solution to a constrainedversion of the profit-maximizationproblemyields a tighter lower bound. There I also illustratehow a tighter upper bound can be obtained by startingwith a vector D such that D>D* and D>V(D). With the two bounds Du and DL at hand, I evaluate all vectors that lie between them and find the profit-maximizingvector D*. 5.2. TheMaximizationProblemWithTwoCompetingChains The discussionin the previoussubsectionabstractsfrom rival-chaincompetition and considersonly the chain effect. With the competitionfrom the rival chain,the profitfunctionfor chain i becomes nt{Dh D,) = Z^=1[A,m* (Xim+ 8a Y,i*m(D«/Zmi)+ 8ijDj,m)lwhere Ximcontains Xm/3i+ y/l-p2em + pt]^ To addressthe interactionbetween the chain effect and the competitioneffect, I invoke the following theorem from Topkis(1978), which states that the best responsefunctionis decreasingin the rival'sstrategywhen the payofffunction is supermodularand has decreasingdifferences.1617 THEOREM 2: // X is a lattice, K is a partiallyorderedset, Y(X, k) is suin permodular X on X for each k in K, and Y(X, k) has decreasingdifferences in (X,k) on X x K, then argmax^x^C^Ck) is decreasingin k on {k:k eK, argmax^GX Y(X, k) is nonempty). Y(X, k) has decreasing differences in (AT,k) on X x K if Y(X, k") Y(X, kf) is decreasing in X e X for all k' < k" in K. Intuitively, Y(X, k) has decreasing differences in (X, k) if X and k are substitutes. In Appendix B.4, I verify that the profit function nt(Dh D}) = £^=1[A> * (Xim+ is supermodularin its own strategyDt and has diiUfrm&v/Zmt) + 8fyZ)y>m)] in differences decreasing (Di9Dj). From Theorem 2, chain /'s best response function argmaxD/eD/ TIi(DhD}) decreasesin rival;'s strategyD,. Similarlyfor chain ;'s best response to i's strategy. 16The original theorem is stated in terms of i7(D, t) having increasing differences in (D, t) and of argmaxDeDFI(D, t) increasing in t. Replacing t with -t yields the version of the theorem stated here. 17See Milgrom and Shannon (1994) for a detailed discussion on the necessary and sufficient conditions for the solution set of an optimization problem to be monotonic in the parameters.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

128 1

The set of Nash equilibriaof a supermodulargame is nonempty,and it has a greatestelement and a least element.1819The currententrygame is not supermodular,as the profitfunction has decreasingdifferencesin the joint strategy space D x D. This leads to a nonincreasingjoint best response function, and we knowfrom the discussionafterTheorem 1 that a nonincreasingfunctionon a lattice can have an empty set of fixed points. A simple transformation,however, restoresthe supermodularitypropertyof the game. The trickis to define a new strategyspace forone player(for example,Kmart)to be the negativeof the originalspace. Let D* = -D*. The profitfunctioncan be rewrittenas

nk(-Dk,Dw) = Y(~Dk,m) * \-Xkm + 8kkT ^ + (Skw)Dw,m], -1 L m U Zml nw(Dw,-Dk) = YDw,m * \xwm+ Sww T ^

+ (-8wk)(-Dk,m)\

It is easy to verifythat the game defined on the new strategyspace (D*, Dw) is supermodular,therefore, a Nash equilibriumexists. Using the transformation I)* = -D*, one can find the correspondingequilibriumin the originalstrategy space. In the followingparagraphs,I explainhow to find the desiredNash equilibriumdirectly in the space of (Dk,Dw) using the "roundrobin" algorithm, where each playerproceeds in turn to update its own strategy.20 To obtain the equilibriummost profitablefor Kmart,startwith the smallest vector in Wal-Mart'sstrategyspace: D°w= inf(D) = {0, . . . , 0}. Derive Kmart's best response K(D°W)= argmaxDjtGD/J,t(D*, D°w)given D°w,using the method outlined in Section 5.1, and denote it by D\ = K(D°W).Similarly,find WalIIW(DW, Mart'sbest response W{D\) = argmaxDu;€D D\) given D\, again using the method in Section 5.1, and denote it by Dlw.Note that Dlw> D°wby the . This finishesthe firstiteration [D\ ,Dlw}. constructionof D°w Fix Dlwand solve for Kmart'sbest response D\ = K{Dlw).By Theorem 2, Kmart'sbest response decreasesin the rival'sstrategy,so D\ = K(DXW) The same argumentshows that D2W Dlw.Iteratingthis process generK(D°W). < • • < D'w. ates two monotone sequences: D\ > D\ > • • • > D\ and Dlw< D2W In every iteration, at least one element of the Dk vector is changed from 1 to 0, and one element of the Dw vector is changed from 0 to 1, so the algorithm = DTW+X, T _,) is supermodular in D, for each D-i and each player /, and TI^Di, D_t) has increasing differences in (Dh /)_,-) for each i. 20See page 185 of Topkis (1998) for a detailed discussion.

PANLEJIA

1282

= W(DTk). and DTW vectors (D[, DTW) constitute an equilibrium:DTk= K(DTW) Furthermore,this equilibriumgives Kmartthe highest profit among the set of all equilibria. obtainedusingD°w= {0, . . . , 0} That Kmartprefersthe equilibrium(L>[,DTW) to all other equilibriafollows from two results:first,D^ < D*wfor any D*wthat belongs to an equilibrium;second, IIk(K(Dw),Dw) decreases in Dw, where K(DW) denotes Kmart's best response function. Together they imply that > TIk(D*k,D*w) V{D*k,D*Jthat belongs to the set of Nash equiIIk(pl,Dl) libria. To show the first result, note that D°w< D*wby the construction of D°w. = D*k.Similarly,Dlw= Since K(DW)decreases in Dw, D\ = K(D°J > K(D*W) < = T times leads to DTk= this process W(D\) W(D*k) D*w.Repeating > < = = = and K{DTW) K(D*W) D\ DTW W{DTk) W(D\) D*w.The second result < IIk(K(DTw), follows from IIk(K(D*w),D*J < nk(K(D*w),DTW) Dp. The first in rival'sstratholds its because Kmart's function decreases inequality profit of the best while the second follows from the definition egy, response inequality function K{DW). By the dual argument,startingwith D°k= inf(D) = {0, . . . , 0} delivers the equilibriumthat is most preferredby Wal-Mart.To search for the equilibrium that favorsWal-Martin the southernregion and Kmartin the rest of the country,one uses the same algorithmto solve the game separatelyfor the south and the other regions. 5.3. AddingSmallFirms It is straightforwardto solve the pre-chain stage: N®is the largest integer such that all enteringfirmscan recovertheir sunk cost,21

Kn = Kb + Sssln«J + JU^fisl + p 0. After the entry of chain stores, some of the existing small stores will find it unprofitableto compete with chains and exit the market,while other more efficient stores (the ones with larger 7j5>m) will enter the market after paying the sunk cost of entry.The numberof small stores in the post-chainperiod is a sum of new entrantsNf and the remainingincumbentsN{. Except for the idiosyncraticprofit shocks, the only difference between these two groups of small firmsis the sunk cost:

+ Vl - P2em ns,m= Xmps+ J2 8*Am + 8ssln(tf,,m) i=k,w

+ PVs,m- SC * l[new entrant]. 21The number of potential small entrants is assumed to be 11, which was within the top two percentile of the distribution of the number of small stores. I also experimented with the maximum number of small stores throughout the sample period. See footnote 28 for details.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1283

Potentialentrantswill enter the marketonly if the post-chainprofitcan recover the sunk cost, while existing small firmswill maintainthe business as long as the profitis nonnegative. Both the numberof entrantsNf(Dk, Dw) and the numberof remainingincumbentsNj (Dk,Dw) arewell definedfunctionsof the numberof chainstores. To solve the game between chains and small stores in the post-chain period, I follow the standardbackwardinduction and plug in small stores' reaction functions to the chains' profit function. Specifically,chain /'s profit function now becomes

77,(A, Dj) = f)Wm * (xim + 8U£^

+ SijDjim

+ Sisln(ATf + l)YL (Dz>,Dj,m)+ N!s(Diim, DjtM) where Xim is defined in Section 5.2. The profit function U/(D,-,Dj) remains supermodularin Dt with decreasingdifferencesin (Di9Dj) under a minor assumption,which essentiallyrequiresthat the net competitioneffect of rivalDj on chain /'s profitis negative.22 The main computationalburden in solving the full model with both chains and small retailersis the search for the best responses K(DW)and W(Dk). In AppendixB.5, 1 discussa few technicaldetails related to the implementation. 6. EMPIRICALIMPLEMENTATION

6.1. Estimation The model does not yield a closed form solution to firms'location choices conditioningon market size observablesand a given vector of parametervalues. Hence I turnto simulationmethods.The ones most frequentlyused in the empiricalindustrialorganizationliterature are the method of simulated loglikelihood (MSL) and the method of simulatedmoments (MSM). Implementing MSL is difficultbecause of the complexitiesin obtainingan estimate of the log-likelihoodof the observedsample.The cross-sectionaldependence among the observedoutcomes in differentmarketsindicatesthat the log-likelihoodof 22Ifwe ignore the integer problem and the sunk cost, then 8ss\n(Ns + 1) can be approxiand the assumptionis 8kw- (8ks8sw/8ss)< 0 and 8wkmated by -{Xsm + 8skDk+ 8SWDW), (8ws8sk/8ss)< 0. The expressionis slightlymore complicatedwith the integer constraint,and the distinctionbetween existingsmall stores and new entrants.Essentially,these two conditions implythat when there are small stores, the "net"competitioneffect of Wal-Mart(its direct impact, together with its indirectimpactworkingthroughsmall stores) on Kmart'sprofit and that of Kmarton Wal-Mart'sprofitare still negative.I have verifiedin the empiricalapplicationthat these conditionsare indeed satisfied.

1284

PANLEJIA

the sample is no longer the sum of the log-likelihoodof each market,and one needs an exceptionallylarge number of simulationsto get a reasonable estimate of the sample'slikelihood.Thus I adopt the MSM method to estimatethe parametersin the profit functions 0O= {£/, S«, 8y, p, r, SC}i=k^se 0 c Rp. The following moment condition is assumed to hold at the true parameter value 0O: E[g(Xm,60)] = 0, where g(Xm, •) e RLwith L > P is a vector of moment functionsthat specifies the differencesbetween the observedequilibriummarketstructuresand those predictedby the model. A MSM estimator0 minimizesa weightedquadraticform in J2m=i8(Xm, 0):

M

(4)

M

1f T f 0 = argmin- \J^g(Xm,9) flJ £$(*„, 0) ,

where g(-) is a simulatedestimate of the true moment function and fiM is an L x L positive semidefiniteweighting matrix.Assume ilM -4 /20, an L x L positive definite matrix.Define the L x P matrixGo= E\V#g(Xm, 0O)LUnder some mild regularityconditions,Pakes and Pollard(1989) and McFadden (1989) showed that (5)

VM(0 - 0o) 4 Normal(0, (I + 7?"1)* VBoV)>

where R is the number of simulations, Aq = Gof2oGo,Bo= Gq/2oco/2oGo, and Ao = E[g(Xm, do)g(Xm,00)'] = Vsi[g(Xm, 0O)].If a consistent estimator of Aq1 is used as the weighting matrix,the MSM estimator 0 is asymptotically efficient,23with its asymptoticvariance being Avar(0) = (1 + R~l) *

(G^A-'Gor'/M.

The obstacle in using this standardmethod is that the moment functions g(Xm, •) are no longer independent across marketswhen the chain effect induces spatialcorrelationin the equilibriumoutcome. For example,Wal-Mart's entrydecision in Benton County,Arkansasdirectlyrelates to its entrydecision in Carroll County, Arkansas,Benton's neighbor. In fact, any two entry decisions, Dim and Dih are correlated because of the chain effect, although the dependence becomes very weak when market m and market / are far apart, since the benefit D,-f//Zm/evaporateswith distance.As a result, the covariance matrixin equation (5) is no longer valid. 23The MSM estimator 6 is asymptotically efficient relative to estimators which minimize a quadratic norm in g(-). Different moments could improve efficiency. I thank the referee for pointing this out.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1285

Conley (1999) discussedmethod of moments estimatorsusing data that exhibit spatialdependence.That paper providedsufficientconditionsfor consistency and normality,which require the underlyingdata generatingprocess to satisfya strong mixingcondition.24Essentially,the dependence among observations should die away quicklyas the distance increases. In the current application,the consistencycondition requiresthat the covariancebetween Dim and Du goes to 0 as their geographicdistance increases.25In other words, the entry decisions in different markets should be nearly independent when the distancebetween these marketsis sufficientlylarge. Unlike some other iterationproceduresthat searchfor the fixed points, \SU\ does not have to be less than 1. To see this, note that by construction,

= l\xi,m+ 28iiY^>o] Di,m

Vm,

where Dim = 1 if chain i has a store in market m. The system stays stable as long as 8U is finite, because Dim is bounded Vm. The geographic scope of the spillover effect can increase with the sample size, but the sum 5//|^¥m(D/5//Z/m)should remain finite to prevent the profit function from exploding. There are many ways to formulate the relationshipbetween the spillover effect and the distance, as long as it guarantees that the (pairwise) covariancebetween the chain stores' entry decisions in differentmarketsgoes to 0 as the geographicdistanceincreases.26 24Theasymptoticargumentsrequire the data to be generated from locations that grow uniformlyin spatialdimensionsas the sample size increases. 25Here I brieflyverifythat the consistencyconditionis satisfied.By construction, DUm= 1\x^m + 28«^ + PVi,m> ol , Zm/ J L

+ pvu > ol ,

A, / = 1\xu + 2fi«^

The cowhere XUm= Xmpi + 2Sn T,kl,i:JDifk/Zmk)+ SyZ),,m+ 8is\n(NSjm+ 1) + y/\-p2sm. variancebetween Dim and Diti is covCD^, Du) = E(Ditm* Du) - E{Di,m)* E(DU)

< PrUo > -XUm ^, pvu> -XU p) - Pr(pi?,> > -Xi,m) * ?r(pr)U> -Xu) -

0

as

Zmi - > oo.

26Thenormalityconditionsin Conley(1999) requirethe covarianceto decreaseat a sufficiently fast rate. See page 9 of that paper for details.These conditionsare triviallysatisfiedhere, as the

1286

PANLEJIA

With the presence of the spatial dependence, the asymptotic covariance matrix of the moment functions Ao in equation (5) should be replaced by eo)g(Xs, (Jq)'].Conley (1999) proposed a nonparametric K = Y,SzMEJL8(xm> covariance matrix estimator formed by taking a weighted average of spatial autocovariance terms, with zero weights for observations farther than a certain distance. Following Conley (1999) and Conley and Ligon (2002), the estimator of AdQ is

m s€Bm

where Bm is the set of markets whose centroid is within 50 miles of market m, including market mP The implicit assumption is that the spillover effect is negligible for markets beyond 50 miles. I have also estimated the variance of the moment functions A summing over markets within a 100 miles. All of the parameters that are significant with the smaller set of Bm remain significant, and the changes in the f-statistics are small. The estimation procedure is as follows. Step 1. Start from some initial guess of the parameter values and draw independently from the normal distribution the following vectors: the marketlevel errors for both the pre-chain period and the post-chain period - {^}^=1 and {sm}%=l;profit shocks for the chains- {Tj^m}Jf=1 and {rjwtm}%=v and profit shocks for each of the potential small entrants- [vosm)m=ianc*iVs m}m=vwhere J = l,..., II.28 Step 2. Obtain the simulated profits 77,-,i = k, w, s, and solve for N®, Dk, Dw, and Ns. Step 3. Repeat Steps 1 and 2 R times and formulate g(Xm, 0). Search for parameter values that minimize the objective function (4), while using the same set of simulation draws for all values of 0. To implement the two-step efficient estimator, I substitute a preliminary estimate 6 into equation (6) to compute the optimal weight matrix A"1 for the second step. spillover effect is assumed to occur only within 50 or 100 miles. In other applications, one needs to verify that these conditions are satisfied. 27As mentioned in Conley (1999), this estimator is inefficient and not always positive semidefinite. Newey and West (1987) introduced a weight function w(l, m) as a numerical device to make the estimator positive semidefinite. The weight used in the empirical application is 0.5 for all the neighbors. ^The number of potential small entrants is assumed to be 11. During the sample period, only one county had 25 small stores, while the median number was 4 for the 1970s, and 3 for the 1980s and 1990s. As the memory requirement and the computational burden increase with the number of potential entrant, I have capped the maximum number of small stores at 11, which is within the top one percentile of the distribution in the 1990s and the top two percentile in the 1980s. The competition effects of chains on small stores do not change much with a maximum number of 25 small stores.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1287

Instead of the usual machine-generatedpseudorandomdraws, I use Halton draws,which have better coverage propertiesand smallersimulationvariances.29'30 Accordingto Train(2000), 100 Halton drawsachievedgreateraccuracy in his mixed logit estimation than 1000 pseudorandomdraws.The parameter estimation exploits 150 Halton simulationdraws,while the variance is calculatedwith 300 Halton draws. There are 29 parameterswith the following set of moments that match the model-predictedand the observedvalues of (a) numbersof Kmartstores, WalMart stores, and small stores in the pre-chainperiod as well as the post-chain period, (b) various kinds of market structures(for example, only a Wal-Mart store but no Kmartstores), (c) the numberof chain stores in the nearbymarkets, (d) the interactionbetween the marketsize variablesand the above items, and (e) the differencein the numberof small stores between the pre-chainand post-chain periods, interacted with the changes in the market size variables between these two periods. 6.2. Discussion:A CloserLook at theAssumptionsand PossibleExtensions Now I discuss several assumptionsof the model: the game's information structureand issues of multiple equilibria,the symmetryassumptionfor small firms, and the nonnegativityof the chain effect. In the last subsection, I consider possible extensions. 6.2.1. InformationStructureand MultipleEquilibria In the empiricalentryliterature,a common approachis to assume complete informationand simultaneousentry. One problem with this approachis the presence of multiple equilibria,which has posed considerable challenges to estimation. Some researcherslook for features that are common among different equilibria.For example, Bresnahan and Reiss (1990, 1991) and Berry 29A Halton sequence is defined in terms of a given number, usually a prime. As an illustration, consider the prime 3. Divide the unit interval evenly into three segments. The first two terms in the Halton sequence are the two break points: | and |. Then divide each of these three segments into thirds and add the break points for these segments into the seNote that the lower break points in all three quence in a particular way: 5,5,5,5,5,5,1,5. segments (5, 5, 5) are entered in the sequence before the higher break points (§,§,§). Then each of the 9 segments is divided into thirds and the break points are added to the sequence: 5, 5, 5, 5,5, 5, |, |> tj, j}> M>£> M>§> and so on* ™* process is continued for as many points as the researcher wants to obtain. See Chapter 9 of Train (2003) for an excellent discussion of the Halton draws. 30Insituations of high-dimensional simulations (as is the case here), the standard Halton draws display high correlations. The estimation here uses shuffled Halton draws, as proposed in Hess and Polak (2003), which has documented that the high correlation can be easily removed by shuffling the Halton draws.

1288

PANLEJIA

(1992) pointed out that althoughfirmidentities differ acrossdifferentequilibria, the numberof enteringfirmsmightbe unique. Groupingdifferentequilibria by their common features leads to a loss of informationand less efficient estimates.Further,common features are increasinglydifficultto findwhen the model becomes more realistic.31Other researchersgive up point identification of parametersand searchfor bounds.These paperstypicallyinvolvebootstraps or subsampling,and are too computationallyintensiveto be applicablehere.32 Given the above considerations,I choose an equilibriumthat seems reasonable a priori.In the baseline specification,I estimate the model using the equilibriumthat is most profitablefor Kmartbecause Kmartderivesfrom an older entity and historicallymighthave had a first-moveradvantage.As a robustness check, I experimentwith two other cases. The first one chooses the equilibrium that is most profitablefor Wal-Mart.This is the direct opposite of the baseline specificationand is inspired by the hindsightof Wal-Mart'ssuccess. The second one selects the equilibriumthat is most profitablefor Wal-Martin the south and most profitablefor Kmartin the rest of the country.This is based on the observationthat the northernregions had been Kmart'sbackyarduntil recently,while Wal-Martstarted its business from the south and has expertise in serving the southern population. The estimated parametersfor the different cases are very similar to one another, which provides evidence that the results are robust to the equilibriumchoice. In Section 7.1, 1 also investigate the differences between these equilibriaat the estimated parametervalues.33 On average,they differ only in a small portion of the sample, and resultsfrom the counterfactualexercisesdo not varymuch acrossdifferentequilibria. 6.2.2. TheSymmetry Assumptionfor SmallFirms I have assumed that all small firms have the same profit function and only differ in the unobservedprofit shocks. The assumptionis necessitatedby data 31For example, the number of entering firms in a given market is no longer unique in the currentapplicationwith the chain effect. See footnote 40 for an illustration. 32Forexample, the methods proposed in Andrews, Berry, and Jia (2004), Chernozhukov, Hong, and Tamer(2007), and Romano and Shaikh(2006) all involve estimatingthe parameters for each bootstrapsample or subsample.It takes more than a day to estimate the model once; it will take about a year if 300 bootstrapsamplesor subsamplesare used for inference.The method proposed by Pakes, Porter,Ho, and Ishii (2005) is less computationallydemanding,but as the authorspointed out, the precisionof their inferenceis still an open question. 33If we were to formallytest whetherthe data preferone equilibriumto the other, we need to derive the asymptoticdistributionof the difference between the two minimizedobjectivefunction values, each associatedwith a differentequilibrium.It is a nonnested test that is somewhat involved,as one objectivefunctioncontainsmomentswith a nonzeromean at the true parameter values. In the currentapplication,the objectivefunctionvalues are very similarin 1997 (108.68 for the objective function that uses the equilibriummost profitablefor Kmart, 105.02 for the equilibriummost profitablefor Wal-Mart,and 103.9 for the equilibriumthat grants a regional advantageto each player),but differ somewhatin 1988 (the objectivefunctionvalues are 120.26, 120.77,and 136.74,respectively).

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1289

availability,since I do not observeanyfirmcharacteristicsfor smallfirms.Making this assumptiongreatlysimplifiesthe complexityof the model with asymmetriccompetitioneffects, as it guaranteesthat in the firstand the thirdstage, the equilibriumnumberof small firmsin each marketis unique. 6.2.3. TheChainEffect 8n The assumptionthat 5» > 0, i e {k, w], is crucialto the solution algorithm, since it implies that the function V(D) defined by the necessarycondition (3) is increasingand that the profit function (2) is supermodularin chain /'s own strategy.These results allow me to employ two powerful theorems- Tarski's fixed point theorem and Topkis'smonotonicitytheorem- to solve a complicated problem that is otherwise unmanageable.The parameter §„ does not have to be a constant. It can be region specific or it can varywith the size of each market(for example,interactingwith population), as long as it is weakly positive. However, the algorithmbreaks down if either 8kkor Swwbecomes negative, and it excludes scenarioswhere the chain effect is positive in some regions and negative in others. The discussionso far has focused on the beneficial aspect of locating stores close to each other. In practice,stores begin to compete for consumerswhen the distance becomes sufficientlysmall. As a result, chains face two opposing forces when makinglocation choices:the chain effect and the businessstealing effect. It is conceivablethat in some areas stores are so close that the business stealingeffect outweighsthe gains and S» becomes negative. Holmes (2005) estimatedthat for places with a populationdensityof 20,000 people per 5-mile radius(whichis comparableto an averagecity in my sample counties), 89% of the averageconsumersvisit a Wal-Martnearby.34When the distance increases to 5 miles, 44% of the consumersvisit the store. The percentage dropsto 7% if the store is 10 miles away.Surveystudies also show that few consumersdrive fartherthan 10-15 miles for general merchandiseshopping. In my sample, the median distance to the nearest store is 21 miles for Wal-Martstores and 27 miles for Kmartstores. It seems reasonable to think that the business stealingeffect, if it exists, is small. 6.2.4. Independent Error Terms:em

In the model, I have assumedthat the market-levelprofitshocks smare independent across markets.Under this assumption,the chain effect is identified from the geographic clustering pattern of the store locations. Theoretically, one can use the numberof small stores across marketsto identifythe correlation in the errorterm,because small stores are assumedto be single-unitfirms. Conditioningon the covariates,the number of small stores across marketsis independentif there is no cross-sectionaldependence in the errorterms.Once 34This is the result from a simulation exercise where the distance is set to 0 mile.

1290

PANLEJIA

we controlfor the cross-sectionaldependence,the extraclusteringexhibitedby the chain stores' location choice should be attributedto the chain effect. However, implementingthis idea is difficult,as there is no easy way to simulate a large numberof errortermsthat exhibitdependencewith irregularspatialpatterns. Therefore, cross-sectionaldependence of the error term is potentially anotherexplanationfor the spatialclusteringpatternthat I currentlyattribute to the chain effect. 6.2.5. Extensions Extendingthe model to allowfor multiplestores in anygivenmarketinvolves only a slight modification.In solving the best response given the rival'sstrategy, instead of startingfrom D = {1, . . . , 1}, we use D = [N\9 . . . , NM],where Nm is the maximumnumberof stores a chain can potentiallyopen in a given market m. The iteration will converge within £m Nm steps. Notice that even though the size of the strategyspace has increased from 2Mto Y\m=\W«>the numberof iterationsonly increaseslinearly,ratherthan exponentially,as there are at most £w Nm steps for D = {Afi,. . . , NM] to monotonicallydecrease to {0, . . . , 0}. In general,the computationalcomplexityincreaseslinearlywith the number of stores in each market. There is one caveat:when there are more stores in an area that are owned by the same firm,the negative business stealing effect acrossmarketscan potentiallyoutweighthe positive spillovereffect. As a result,the assumptionthat 8U> 0 mightnot be supportedby data in some applications. 7. RESULTS

7.1. ParameterEstimates The sample includes 2065 small- and medium-sizedcounties with populations between 5000 and 64,000 in the 1980s. Even though I do not model Kmart'sand Wal-Mart'sentry decisions in other counties, I incorporateinto the profit function the spilloverfrom stores outside the sample. This is especiallyimportantfor Wal-Mart,as the numberof Wal-Martstores in big counties doubledover the sampleperiod.TableIII displaysthe summarystatisticsof the distanceweighted numbersof adjacentKmartstores J^i^mieBm(^k,i/Zmi) and Wal-Martstores J2i?mj<=Bm which from measure the (Dwj/Zmi), nearby spillover stores (includingstores outside the sample). In 1997, the Kmartspillovervariable was slightlyhigherthan in 1988 (0.13 vs. 0.11), but the Wal-Martspillover variablewas almost twice as big as in 1988 (0.19 vs. 0.10). The profit functions of all retailers share three common explanatoryvariables: log of population,log of real retail sales per capita, and the percentage of populationthat is urban.Many studies have found a pure size effect: there tend to be more stores in a marketas the populationincreases.Retail sales per capita capturethe "depth"of a marketand explainfirm entrybehaviorbetter

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1291

TABLEIII Summary Statistics for the Distance Weighted Number of Adjacent Stores3 1988 Variable

Distanceweightednumberof adjacent Kmartstores within50 miles Distanceweightednumberof adjacent Wal-Martstoreswithin50 miles Numberof counties

1997

Mean

Std.

Mean

Std.

0.11

0.08

0.13

0.11

0.10 2065

0.08

0.19

0.19

aSource: Directoryof Discount DepartmentStores (Chain Store Guide (1988-1997)).

than personalincome does. The percentageof urbanpopulationmeasuresthe degree of urbanization.It is generallybelieved that urbanizedareas have more shoppingdistrictsthat attractbig chain stores. For Kmart,the profit function includes a dummyvariable for the Midwest regions. Kmart'sheadquartersare located in Troy,Michigan.Until the mid1980s, this region had alwaysbeen the "backyard"of Kmartstores. Similarly, Wal-Mart'sprofitfunctionincludesa southerndummy,as well as the log of distance in miles to its headquartersin Bentonville,Arkansas.This distancevariable turns out to be a useful predictorfor Wal-Martstores' location choices. For small firms,everythingelse equal, there are more small firmsin the southern states. It could be that there have alwaysbeen fewer big retail stores in the southern regions and that people rely on neighborhood small firms for dayto-day shopping.The constant in the small firms'profit function is allowed to differbetween the pre-chainperiod and the post-chainperiod to capturesome general trend in the numberof small stores that is unrelatedwith chain stores' entry. Tables IV and V list the parameterestimates for the full model in six different specifications.Table IV uses the 1988 data for the post-chain period, while TableV uses the 1997 data for this period. The first five columns focus on the competitionbetween chains and small discountstores. The last column estimates the model using Kmart,Wal-Mart,and all other discount stores, including the small ones. The first column is the baseline specification,where the estimates are obtained using the equilibriummost profitablefor Kmart. The second column estimates the model using the equilibriummost profitable for Wal-Mart,while the third column repeats the exercise using the equilibriumthat grantsWal-Martan advantagein the south and Kmartan advantage in the rest of the country.The estimates are quite similaracross the different equilibria. One mightbe concernedthat retail sales is endogenous:conditioningon demographics,countieswith a Kmartor Wal-Martstore will generate more retail

1292

PANLEJIA TABLEIV Parameter Estimates From Different Specifications-

1988a

Favors Wal-Mart

Regional Advantage

Personal Income

Rival Stores in

1.40* 1.43* (0.11) (0.09) 2.27* 2.20* Log retailsales/log (0.08) (0.07) personalincome Urban ratio 2.29* 2.37* (0.35) (0.32) Midwest 0.52* 0.54* (0.14) (0.11) Constant -24.59* -25.28* (0.73) (0.51) -0.33* -0.28* delta_kw (0.15) (0.12) 0.59 0.64* delta_kk (0.68) (0.16) -0.01 -0.02 deltajcs (0.07) (0.09) delta_kw2

1.44* (0.09) 2.18* (0.07) 2.31* (0.25) 0.52* (0.12) -24.49* (0.50) -0.31 (0.20) 0.63 (0.50) -0.01 (0.08)

2.09* (0.11) 1.78* (0.10) 2.98* (0.45) 0.27* (0.12) -25.47* (0.67) -0.31* (0.15) 0.53* (0.27) -0.04 (0.09)

1.38* (0.10) 2.20* (0.08) 2.20* (0.37) 0.55* (0.20) -24.54* (0.69) -0.31 (0.25) 0.57* (0.28) -0.001 (0.13) 0.19 (4.76)

1.55* (0.08) 2.25* (0.07) 2.24* (0.22) 0.47* (0.14) -25.17* (0.58) -0.251" (0.15) 0.56* (0.22) -0.11 (0.10)

1.40* 2.05* (0.09) (0.16) 1.62* 1.22* (0.08) (0.05) 2.43* 3.37* (0.33) (0.38) -1.42* -1.49* (0.10) (0.11) 1.05* 1.62* (0.15) (0.19) -10.66* -11.14* (0.75) (0.80) -1.13* -1.10* (0.18) (0.24) 1.34* 1.36* (0.33) (0.37) -0.02 -0.01 (0.11) (0.09) 0.69* 0.90* (0.06) (0.05)

1.37* (0.15) 1.68* (0.08) 2.24* (0.39) -1.48* (0.16) 1.08* (0.14) -10.73* (1.08) -0.93* (0.28) 1.36* (0.56) -0.02 (0.07) 0.71* (0.05) 0.18 (2.75)

1.86* (0.12) 1.62* (0.07) 2.15* (0.26) -1.57* (0.12) 1.24* (0.14) -10.72* (0.66) -0.85* (0.28) 1.30* (0.51) -0.37* (0.10) 0.87* (0.05)

Baseline

Kmart'sprofit Log population

Wal-Mart'sprofit Log population

1.39* 1.43* (0.08) (0.09) 1.68* 1.73* Log retailsales/log (0.07) (0.06) personalincome Urbanratio 2.40* 2.43* (0.38) (0.27) -1.49* -1.54* Log distance (0.12) (0.10) South 1.06* 1.11* (0.16) (0.13) Constant -10.70* -11.04* (1.03) (0.87) -1.10* -1.18* delta_wk (0.28) (0.29) 1.31* 1.36* delta_ww (0.64) (0.53) -0.02 -0.02 delta_ws (0.07) (0.05) rho 0.68* 0.71* (0.06) (0.06) delta_wk2

Neighborhood

All Other Discount Stores

(Continues)

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1293

TABLEIV- Continued

Baseline

Favors Wal-Mart

Regional Advantage

Smallstores'profit/allother discountstores'profit 1.53* 1.57* 1.50* Log population (0.06) (0.07) (0.06) 1.19* 1.14* 1.15* Log retailsales (0.06) (0.07) (0.05) -1.42* -1.46* -1.38* Urbanratio (0.13) (0.14) (0.14) 0.92* 0.96* 0.91* South (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) -9.71* -10.01* -9.57* Constant_88 (0.46) (0.63) (0.48) -0.97* -0.99* -0.98* delta_sk (0.16) (0.15) (0.13) -0.93* -0.93* -0.94* delta_sw (0.13) (0.14) (0.15) -2.26* -2.31* -2.39* delta_ss (0.10) (0.09) (0.09) 0.58* 0.68* 0.54* tao (0.12) (0.11) (0.10) -8.86* -8.50* -8.62* Constant_78 (0.60) (0.63) (0.50) -1.80* -1.86* -1.80* Sunkcost (0.33) (0.25) (0.34) Functionvalue Observations

120.26 2065

120.77 2065

136.74 2065

Personal Income

Rival Stores in

1.45* (0.07) 1.12* (0.05) -1.55* (0.12) 0.87* (0.06) -9.32* (0.42) -0.63* (0.12) -0.63* (0.13) -2.26* (0.11) 0.67* (0.15) -7.80* (0.60) -2.07* (0.35)

1.52* (0.06) 1.17* (0.05) -1.44* (0.14) 0.92* (0.07) -9.75* (0.37) -0.98* (0.13) -0.96* (0.18) -2.32* (0.09) 0.61* (0.10) -8.60* (0.47) -1.90* (0.42)

1.75* (0.06) 1.34* (0.04) -0.73* (0.10) 0.77* (0.06) -11.73* (0.36) -0.76* (0.12) -0.95* (0.12) -2.24* (0.10) 0.26* (0.10) -10.14* (0.42) -2.32* (0.26)

155.65 2065

119.62 2065

96.05 2065

Neighborhood

All Other Discount Stores

aAsterisks (*) denote significance at the 5% confidence level daggers and (+) denote significance at the 10% confidence level. Standard errors are in parentheses. Midwest and South are regional dummies, with the Great Lakes region, the Plains region, and the Rocky Mountain region grouped as the Midwest, and the Southwest region and the Southeast region grouped as the South. delta_kw, deltajcs, delta_wk, delta_ws, delta_sk, delta_sw, and delta_ss denote the competition effect, while delta_kk and deltaww denote the chain effect, "k"stands for Kmart, "w"stands for Wal-Mart,and "s" stands for small stores in the first five columns, and all discount stores (except Kmart and WalMart stores) in the last column, yl - p2 measures the importance of the market-level profit shocks. In the first three columns, the parameters are estimated using the equilibrium most profitable for Kmart, the equilibrium most profitable for Wal-Mart,and the equilibrium that grants Kmart advantage in the Midwest region and Wal-Martadvantage in the South, respectively. In the last three columns, the parameters are estimated using the equilibrium that is most favorable for Kmart. In the fourth column, log of personal income per capita is used in Kmart'sand Wal-Mart'sprofit function. In the fifth column, the existence of rival stores in neighboring markets matters. The sixth column estimates the model using Kmart, Wal-Mart,and all other discount stores, not just small stores.

sales.35In the fourthcolumn, I estimatedthe model using personalincome per 35 Accordingto annual reports for Kmart(1988, 1997) and Wal-Mart(1988, 1997), the combined sales of Kmartand Wal-Martaccountedfor about 2% of U.S. retail sales in 1988 and 4% in 1997.As I do not observesales at the store level, I cannot directlymeasurehow mucha Kmart or a Wal-Martstore contributesto the total retail sales in the counties where it is located. However, given that there are on average400-500 retailersper county and that these two firmsonly

1294

PANLEJIA TABLEV Parameter Estimates From Different Specifications-1997

Baseline

Favors Wal-Mart

Kmart'sprofit Log population

1.50* 1.45* (0.11) (0.21) 2.16* 2.08* Log retail sales/log (0.16) (0.13) personalincome Urban ratio 1.36* 1.43* (0.23) (0.41) Midwest 0.38* 0.42* (0.13) (0.20) Constant -24.26* -23.47* (1.59) (0.69) -0.74* -0.77* delta_kw (0.19) (0.25) 0.63 0.69 delta_kk (0.54) (0.53) -0.03 -0.002 deltajcs (0.20) (0.18) delta_kw2

Wal-Mart'sprofit Log population

2.02* 1.97* (0.08) (0.11) 1.99* 1.93* Log retailsales/log (0.06) (0.08) personalincome Urban ratio 1.63* 1.71* (0.29) (0.20) -1.06* -1.03* Log distance (0.10) (0.15) South 0.88* 0.94* (0.20) (0.21) Constant -16.95* -16.53* (0.76) (0.87) -0.68* -0.74* delta_wk (0.26) (0.34) 0.79* 0.76 delta_ww (0.36) (0.50) -0.10 -0.10 delta_ws (0.13) (0.07) rho 0.86* 0.86* (0.06) (0.08) delta_wk2

Regional Advantage

Personal Income

Rival Stores in Neighborhood

All Other Discount Stores

1.42* 1.34* (0.14) (0.10) 2.17* 2.06* (0.13) (0.09) 1.41* 1.79* (0.24) (0.28) 0.33f 0.37* (0.18) (0.15) -24.20* -25.04* (0.87) (0.73) -0.59* -0.96* (0.18) (0.14) 0.56* 0.85* (0.32) (0.27) -0.003 -0.02 (0.08) (0.09)

1.50* (0.10) 2.16* (0.09) 1.25* (0.20) 0.35f (0.18) -24.26* (0.59) -0.67* (0.31) 0.64 (0.55) -0.01 (0.12) 0.27 (1.99)

1.65* (0.09) 2.14* (0.08) 1.47* (0.42) 0.36* (0.12) -24.70* (0.61) -0.64* (0.23) 0.51 (0.33) -0.07 (0.08)

2.00* 2.31* (0.14) (0.16) 1.99* 1.82* (0.12) (0.08) 1.57* 1.74* (0.63) (0.34) -1.07* -1.10* (0.16) (0.09) 0.81* 0.99* (0.21) (0.11) -16.68* -18.38* (1.08) (0.95) -0.59* -0.68* (0.16) (0.21) 0.86* 0.77* (0.33) (0.29) -0.12f -0.06 (0.07) (0.08) 0.90* 0.85* (0.05) (0.04)

2.01* (0.15) 2.00* (0.12) 1.48* (0.36) -1.05* (0.11) 0.88* (0.13) -16.95* (1.20) -0.53+ (0.27) 0.73+ (0.41) -0.10 (0.17) 0.88* (0.06) 0.10 (3.46)

2.01* (0.12) 1.94* (0.08) 1.64* (0.24) -1.00* (0.04) 0.93* (0.13) -16.58* (0.51) -0.87* (0.18) 0.76* (0.23) -0.28* (0.08) 0.90* (0.05)

(Continues)

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1295

TABLEV- Continued Favors Wal-Mart

Regional Advantage

Personal Income

Neighborhood

All Other Discount Stores

Smallstores'profit/allother discountstores'profit 1.64* 1.62* 1.67* Log population (0.10) (0.08) (0.10) 1.37* 1.33* 1.38* Log retailsales (0.07) (0.07) (0.06) Urban ratio -1.87* -1.76* -1.91* (0.18) (0.17) (0.19) 1.11* South 1.14* 1.13* (0.09) (0.08) (0.08) -11.75* -11.46* -11.84* Constant_97 (0.52) (0.61) (0.43) -0.45* -0.44* -0.41f delta_sk (0.15) (0.15) (0.22) -0.79* -0.71* -0.64* delta_sw (0.17) (0.14) (0.15) -2.68* -2.64* -2.75* delta_ss (0.19) (0.11) (0.14) 0.57* 0.53* 0.63* tao (0.19) (0.21) (0.24) -9.62* -9.33* -9.48* Constant_78 (0.65) (0.63) (0.73) -2.31* -2.50* Sunkcost -2.36* (0.40) (0.44) (0.62)

1.66* (0.09) 1.37* (0.06) -1.95* (0.13) 1.19* (0.08) -11.75* (0.77) -0.43* (0.15) -0.78* (0.15) -2.73* (0.21) 0.61* (0.17) -9.98* (1.25) -1.90* (0.78)

1.65* (0.11) 1.37* (0.08) -1.88* (0.17) 1.13* (0.07) -11.76* (0.68) -0.39f (0.21) -0.72* (0.16) -2.69* (0.21) 0.60* (0.16) -9.56* (0.93) -2.40* (0.60)

1.92* (0.07) 1.37* (0.06) -0.80* (0.11) 0.89* (0.06) -12.35* (0.42) -0.38* (0.12) -0.96* (0.12) -2.69* (0.10) 0.11 (0.13) -9.77* (0.54) -2.69* (0.30)

216.24 2065

104.64 2065

91.24 2065

Baseline

Functionvalue Observations

108.68 2065

105.02 2065

103.90 2065

Rival Stores in

aAsterisks (*) denote significance at the 5% confidence level and daggers (t) denote significance at the 10% confidence level. Standarderrors are in parentheses. See Table IV for the explanation of the variables and the different specifications for each column.

capitain place of the retail sales variable.36Neither the competitioneffects nor the chain effects change much. The objectivefunctionvalue is higher,indicating a worse fit of the data. The model assumes that stores in different markets do not compete with each other. However,it is possible that a chain store becomes a strongercompetitor when it is surroundedby a large numberof stores owned by the same firmin nearbymarkets.As a result, rivalstores in neighboringmarketscan inaccountedfor 2-4% of total retail sales, the endogeneityof the retail sales is not likely to be a severe problem. 361 did not use personalincome per capita in small stores' profitfunction,because it does not explainvariationsin the numberof small stores very well. In the ordinaryleast squaresregression of the numberof small stores on marketsize variables,personal income per capita is not significantonce populationis included.

1296

PANLEJIA

directlyaffect competitionbetween stores in a given market.The fifth column estimates the followingprofitfunctionfor chain stores:

= DUm* \xmPi + SijDj^ * (l + 8*2 T ^A + s» Yl ^r~ + \/l - P2^m+ pi7/,m,

+ 1) + 8isln(NStm

i, ; e {&,w],

where the competition effect 8,yD;> is augmented by 8ijaJ2i^m(Dhi/Zmi), which is the distance weighted number of rival stores in the nearbymarkets. Neither 8kWt2 nor 5^,2 is significant.The magnitudeis also small:on average, the competitioneffect is only raisedby 2-3% due to the presence of surrounding stores. In the rest of this section, I focus on the coefficientsof the marketsize variables j8. 1 discussthe competitioneffects and the chain effects in the next section. The j8 coefficients are highlysignificantand intuitive,with the exception of the Midwest dummy,which is marginallysignificantin two specificationsin 1997. p is smaller than 1, indicatingthe importanceof the market-levelerror terms and the necessity of controllingfor endogeneity of all firms'entry decisions. TablesVI and VII displaythe model's goodness of fit for the baseline specification.37In TableVI, the firstand thirdcolumns displaythe sample averages, while the other two columns list the model's predicted averages.The model matchesexactlythe observedaveragenumbersof Kmartand Wal-Martstores. The number of small firms is a noisy variable and is much harder to predict. Its sample median is around3 or 4, but the maximumis 20 in 1978,25 in 1988, TABLEVI Model's Goodness of Fit for the Baseline Specification 1988 Number of

Kmart Wal-Mart Smallstores in 1978 Smallstores

1997

Sample Mean

Model Mean

Sample Mean

Model Mean

0.21 0.32 4.75 3.79

0.21 0.32 4.80 3.78

0.19 0.48 4.75 3.46

0.19 0.48 4.74 3.39

37Theresultsfor the rest of the specificationsare availableupon request.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

Correlation

1297

TABLEVII Between Model Prediction and Sample Observation

Number of

1988

1997

Kmart Wal-Mart Smallstores in 1978 Smallstores

0.66 0.72 0.61 0.65

0.63 0.75 0.61 0.67

and 19 in 1997. The model does a decent job of fitting the data. The sample averageis 4.75, 3.79, and 3.46 per county in 1978, 1988, and 1997, respectively. Such resultsmight The model'spredictionis 4.80, 3.78, and 3.39, respectively.38 be expected, as the parametersare chosen to match these moments. In Table VII, I reportthe correlationsbetween the predictedand observednumbers of Kmartstores, Wal-Martstores, and small firms in each market.The numbers varybetween 0.61 and 0.75. These correlationsare not includedin the set of moment functions,and a high value indicatesa good fit. Overall,the model explainsthe data well. To investigatethe differences across equilibria,Table VIII reports the percentage of marketswhere the two extreme equilibriadiffer. It turns out that these equilibriaare not very different from each other. For example, in 1988, using the baseline parameter estimates, the equilibriummost profitable for Kmartand the equilibriummost profitablefor Wal-Martdiffer in only 1.41% TABLEVIII Percentage of Markets Where the Two Extreme Equilibria Differ3

Using parametersassociatedwith the equilibriummost profitablefor Kmart Using parametersassociatedwith the equilibriummost profitablefor Wal-Mart Using parametersassociatedwith the equilibriumthat favorsWal-Martin the South

1988

1997

1.41%

1.58%

1.20%

2.03%

1.45%

1.11%

aFor each of these exercises, I solve the two extreme equilibria (the one most profitable for Kmart and the one most profitable for Wal-Mart) evaluated at the same set of parameter values, compute their difference, and average over 300 simulations.

381 have estimatedthe three-stagemodel twice.The firsttime, I used data in 1978for the prechain period and data in 1988 for the post-chainperiod. The second time, I used data in 1978 and data in 1997 for the pre- and post-chainperiods, respectively.Therefore,the model has two predictionsfor the numberof small stores in 1978, one from each estimation.In both cases, the model'spredictioncomes very close to the sample mean.

1298

PANLEJIA

of the markets.39 As all equilibria are bounded between these two extreme equilibria, the difference between any pair of equilibria can only be (weakly) smaller. In the absence of the chain effect, the only scenario that accommodates multiple equilibria is when both a Kmart store and a Wal-Mart store are profitable as the only chain store in the market, but neither is profitable when both stores are in the market.40 Accordingly, the two possible equilibrium outcomes for a given market are Kmart in and Wal-Mart out or Kmart out and Wal-Mart in.41Using the baseline parameter estimates, on average, this situation arises in 1.1% of the sample in 1988 and 1.4% of the sample in 1997. These findings suggest that while multiple equilibria are potentially an issue, they do not represent a prevalent phenomenon in the data.4243 It also suggests that using different profit functions for different firms helps to reduce the occurrence of multiple equilibria in this entry model, because the more asymmetric firms are in any given market, the less likely the event occurs where both firms are profitable as the only chain store, but neither is profitable when both operate in the market. To understand the magnitudes of the market size coefficients, I report in Tables IX, X, and XI the changes in the number of each type of store when some market size variable changes using the estimates from the baseline specifications.44 For example, to derive the effect of population change on the number of Kmart stores, I fix Wal-Mart's and small stores' profits, increase Kmart's profit in accordance with a 10% increase in population, and resolve the full model to obtain the new equilibrium number for 300 simulations. For each of these counterfactual exercises, the columns labeled Favors Kmart use the equilibrium that is most favorable for Kmart, while the columns labeled Favors 39The numbers reported here are the average over 300 simulations. ^With the chain effect, all four cases- (Kmart out, Wal-Mart out), (Kmart out, Wal-Mart in), (Kmart in, Wal-Mart out), and (Kmart in, Wal-Mart in) - can be the equilibrium outcome for a given market. Consider an example with two markets. In market A, 77^ = -0.2 - 0.6ZH and 11* = -0.2+0.3D£ -0.7Z^; in market B, /7f = 0.1 -0.6Z)£ and 77* = 0.1 +0.3Z)£ -0.7Df . One can verify that there are two equilibria in this game. The first is (D£ = 0, D* = 0; Df = 1, D* = 0) and the second is (D* = 0, D£ = 1; DBk= 0, D%= 1). In this simple example, both (Kmart out, Wal-Mart out) and (Kmart out, Wal-Mart in) can be the equilibrium outcome for market A. 41The discussion on multiple equilibria has ignored the small stores, as the number of small stores is a well defined function of a given pair of (Kmart, Wal-Mart). 42In their study of banks' adoption of the automated clearinghouse electronic payment system, Ackerberg and Gowrisankaran (2007) also found that the issue of multiple equilibria is not economically significant. 43As one referee pointed out, multiple equilibria could potentially be more important if the sample is not restricted to small- and medium-sized counties. The exercise here has taken entry decisions and the benefit derived from stores located in the metropolitan areas as given. It is possible that multiple equilibria will occur more frequently once these entry decisions are endogenized. ^To save space, results from other specifications are not reported here. They are not very different from those of the baseline specification.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1299

TABLEIX Number of Kmart Stores When the Market Size Changes3 1988 Favors Kmart

Base case Populationincreases10% Retail sales increases10% Urban ratio increases10% Midwest= 0 for all counties Midwest= 1 for all counties

1997

Favors Wal-Mart

Favors Kmart

Favors Wal-Mart

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

100.0 110.5 116.8 107.2 82.7 123.7

437 482 510 468 361 540

100.0 110.9 117.4 107.6 81.8 124.0

413 458 485 445 338 512

100.0 113.1 118.8 105.4 84.6 118.7

393 445 467 415 333 467

100.0 113.5 119.4 105.6 84.5 119.2

362 411 432 382 306 432

aFor each of the simulation exercises in all Tables IX-XI, I fix other firms' profits and change only the profit of the target firm in accordance with the change in the market size. I resolve the entire game to obtain the new equilibrium numbers of firms. Columns labeled Favors Kmart use the equilibrium most profitable for Kmart, and columns labeled Favors Wal-Mart use the equilibrium most profitable for Wal-Mart. For example, in the second row of Table IX, I increase Kmart's profit according to a 10% increase in population while holding Wal-Mart'sand small firms' profit the same as before. Using this new set of profits and the equilibrium that favors Kmart most, the number of Kmart stores is 10.5% higher than in the base case in 1988.

Wal-Martuses the other extreme equilibrium.They provide an upper (lower) and lower (upper)boundfor the numberof Kmart(Wal-Mart)stores. It should not come as a surprisethat resultsof these two scenariosare quite similar,since TABLEX Number of Wal-Mart Stores When the Market Size Changes3 1997

1988 Favors Wal-Mart

Favors Kmart

Base case Population increases10% Retail sales increases10% Urbanratio increases10% Distance increases10% South = 0 for all counties South = 1 for all counties

Favors Kmart

Favors Wal-Mart

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

100.0

651

100.0

680

100.0

985

100.0

1016

108.6

707

108.2

736

107.4

1058

106.9

1086

110.3

718

109.9

747

107.3

1057

106.8

1085

105.4

686

105.2

715

102.2

1007

102.1

1037

91.2

594

91.5

622

96.0

946

96.3

978

63.6

414

65.5

445

83.8

825

85.0

863

135.7

884

134.9

917

117.8

1160

116.3

1182

aSee the footnote to Table IX for comments.

1300

PANLEJIA TABLEXI Number of Small Firms When the Market Size Changes3 1997

1988 Favors Kmart

Base case Population increases10% Retail sales increases10% Urban ratio increases10% South = 0 for all counties South = 1 for all counties Sunkcost increases10%

Favors Wal-Mart

Favors Kmart

Favors Wal-Mart

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

100.0

7808

100.0

7803

100.0

6995

100.0

6986

106.6

8319

106.6

8314

106.3

7437

106.3

7427

104.9

8191

104.9

8186

105.3

7365

105.3

7355

98.2

7665

98.2

7660

97.6

6827

97.6

6817

80.6

6290

80.6

6285

78.3

5476

78.3

5467

120.8

9431

120.8

9425

123.3

8625

123.3

8612

95.9

7485

95.9

7481

95.6

6689

95.6

6680

aSee the footnote to Table IX for comments.

the two equilibriaare not very different.In the followingdiscussion,I focus on the equilibriummost profitablefor Kmart. Market size variablesare importantfor big chains. In 1988, a 10% growth in population induces Kmartto enter 10.5% more markets and Wal-Martto enter 8.6% more markets.A similarincrementin retail sales attractsthe entry of Kmartand Wal-Martstores in 16.8%and 10.3%more markets,respectively. The resultsare similarfor 1997.These differencesindicatethat Kmartis much more likely to locate in biggermarkets,while Wal-Martthrivesin smallermarkets. Perhaps not surprisingly,the regional advantageis substantialfor both chains:controllingfor the marketsize, changingthe Midwestregionaldummy from 1 to 0 for all counties leads to 33.1% fewer Kmartstores, and changing the southernregionaldummyfrom 1 to 0 for all counties leads to 53.2%fewer Wal-Martstores. When distance increases by 10%, the number of Wal-Mart stores drops by 8.8%. Wal-Mart's"home advantage"is much smaller in 1997: everythingelse the same, changing the southern dummy from 1 to 0 for all counties leads to 29% fewer Wal-Martstores, and a 10% increase in distance reduces the numberof Wal-Martstores by only 4%. As the model is static in nature(all Kmartand Wal-Martstores are opened in one period), the regional dummiesand the distancevariableprovidea reduced-formway to capturethe path dependence of the expansionof chain stores. The market size variables have a relativelymodest impact on the number of small businesses. In 1988, a 10% increase in population attracted 6.6% more stores. The same increasein real retail sales per capita draws4.9% more

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1301

stores. The numberof small stores declines by about 1.8%when the percentage of urbanpopulationgoes up by 10%.In comparison,the regional dummy is much more important:everythingelse equal, changingthe southerndummy from 1 to 0 for all counties leads to 33.3% fewer small stores (6290 stores vs. 9431 stores). When the sunkcost increasesby 10%,the numberof small stores reducesby 4.1%. 7.2. The CompetitionEffectand the ChainEffect As shown in TablesIV and V, all competition effects in the profit function of the small stores and that of all other discountstores are preciselyestimated. The chain effect and the competition effect in Wal-Mart'sprofit function are also reasonablywell estimated.The results for Kmart'sprofit function appear to be the weakest: althoughthe size of the coefficients is similar,the standard errorsare large for some columns. For example, the chain effect is significant in 4 out of 6 specificationsin 1988 and in only two specificationsin 1997. The competition effect of Wal-Marton Kmartis big and significantin all cases in 1997,but insignificantin two specificationsin 1988. The impactof small stores on the chain stores is neververy significant.Withone exceptionin 1997,both r and the sunk cost are significantand sizeable, indicating the importance of historydependence. To assess the magnitudeof the competition effects for the chains,TableXII resolvesthe equilibriumnumberof Kmartand Wal-Martstores underdifferent assumptionsof the marketstructure.The negativeimpactof Kmart'spresence TABLEXII Competition Effect and Chain Effect for Kmart (Km)and Wal-Mart (Wm)3 1988 Number of

Kmartstores Base case Wm in each market Wm exits each market Not compete with small stores No chain effect Wal-Martstores Base case Km in each market Km exits each market Not compete with small stores No chain effect

1997

Percent

Total

Percent

Total

100.0 85.1 108.6 101.3 94.7

437 371 474 442 414

100.0 82.2 141.9 104.3 93.5

393 323 558 410 368

100.0 61.4 119.5 101.7 84.4

651 400 778 662 550

100.0 82.2 105.7 105.1 92.9

985 809 1042 1035 915

aBase case is the number of stores observed in the data. For each exercise, I resolve the full model under the specified assumptions. For the last two rows of both panels where the counterfactual exercise involves multiple equilibria, I solve the model using the equilibrium that is most profitable for Kmart.

1302

PANLEJIA

on Wal-Mart's profit is much stronger in 1988 than in 1997, while the opposite is true for the effect of Wal-Mart's presence on Kmart's profit. For example, in 1988, Wal-Mart would only enter 400 markets if there were a Kmart store in every county. When Kmart ceases to exist as a competitor, the number of markets with Wal-Mart stores rises to 778, a net increase of 94.5%. The same experiment in 1997 leads Wal-Mart to enter 28.8% more markets, from 809 to 1042. The pattern is reversed for Kmart. In 1988, Kmart would enter 27.8% more markets when there were no Wal-Mart stores compared with the case of one Wal-Mart store in every county (474 Kmart stores vs. 371 Kmart stores); in 1997, Kmart would enter 72.8% more markets for the same experiment (558 Kmart stores vs. 323 Kmart stores).45 These estimates are consistent with the observation that Wal-Mart grew stronger during the sample period and replaced Kmart as the largest discounter in 1991. Both a Cournot model and a Bertrand model with differentiated products predict that reduction in rivals' marginal costs drives down a firm's own profit. I do not observe firms' marginal costs, but these estimates are consistent with evidence that Wal-Mart's marginal cost was declining relative to Kmart's over the sample period. Wal-Mart is famous for its cost-sensitive culture; it is also keen on technology advancement. Holmes (2001) cited evidence that WalMart has been a leading investor in information technology. In contrast, Kmart struggled with its management failures that resulted in stagnant revenue sales, and it either delayed or abandoned store renovation plans throughout the 1990s. To investigate the importance of the chain effect for both chains, the last row of both panels in Table XII reports the equilibrium number of stores when there is no chain effect. I set 5l7= 0 for the targeted chain, but keep the rival's Sjj unchanged and resolve the model. The difference in the number of stores with or without 5/7captures the advantage of chains over single-unit retailers. In 1988, without the chain effect, the number of Kmart stores would have decreased by 5.3% and Wal-Mart would have entered 15.6% fewer markets. In 1997, Kmart would have entered 6.5% fewer markets, while Wal-Mart would have entered 7.1%. The decline in Wal-Mart's chain effect suggests that the benefit of scale economies does not grow proportionally. In fact there are good reasons to believe it might not be monotone because, as discussed in Section 6.2.3, when chains grow bigger and saturate the area, cannibalization among stores becomes a stronger concern. As I do not observe the stores' sales or profit, I cannot estimate the dollar value of these spillover benefits. However, given the low markup of these discount stores (the average gross markup was 20.9% from 1993 to 1997, see footnote 3), these estimates appear to be large. The results are consistent with Holmes (2005), who also found scale economies to be important. Given the 45In solving for the number of Wal-Mart (Kmart) stores when Kmart (Wal-Mart) exits, I allow the small firms to compete with the remaining chain.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1303

TABLEXIII Number of Small Stores With Different Market Structure3 Profit Positive

Profit Recovers Sunk Cost

Percent

Total

No Kmart or Wal-Mart Only Kmart in each Market Only Wal-Mart in each Market Both Kmart and Wal-Mart

100.0 76.2 77.5 56.1

9261 7057 7173 5195

No Kmart or Wal-Mart Only Kmart in each Market Only Wal-Mart in each Market Both Kmart and Wal-Mart

100.0 89.8 82.4 72.9

8053 7228 6634 5868

Percent

Total

47.9 49.1 31.6

4440 4542 2925

54.1 47.9 40.3

4357 3854 3244

1988

1997

a I fix the number of Kmart and Wal-Martstores as specified and solve for the equilibrium number of small stores. If stores have perfect foresight, the columns labeled Profit Recovers Sunk Cost would have been the number of stores that we observe, as they would not have entered in the pre-chain period if their profit after entry could not recover the sunk cost.

magnitudeof these spillovereffects, furtherresearchthat explainstheir mechanismwill help improveour understandingof the retail industry,in particular its productivitygains over the past several decades.46 TableXIII studies the competitioneffects of chainson small discountstores. Here I distinguishbetween two cases. The first two columns report the number of small stores predicted by the model, where small stores continue their business after the entry of Kmartand Wal-Martas long as their profit is positive, even if they cannot recover the sunk cost paid in the first stage. The second two columns report the numberof small stores whose post-chainprofit is higher than the sunk cost. If small stores had perfect foresight and could predict the entry of Kmartand Wal-Mart,these two columnswould be the number of stores that we observe.The resultssuggest that chainshave a substantial competition impact on small firms. In 1988, comparedwith the scenario with no chain stores, adding a Kmartstore to each market reduces the numberof small firmsby 23.8%or 1.07 stores per county. Of the remainingstores, more than one-thirdcould not recover their sunk cost of entry.Had they learned of the entry of the chains stores in the first stage, they would not have entered the market. Thus, adding a Kmart store makes 52.1% of the small stores or 2.33 stores per county either unprofitableor unable to recovertheir sunk cost. The story is similarfor the entry of Wal-Martstores. When both a Kmartand a Wal-Martstore enter, 68.4% of the small stores or 3.07 stores per county cannot recoup their sunk cost of entry. 46See Foster, Haltiwanger, and Krizan (2002) for a detailed study of the productivity growth in the retail industry.

1304

PANLEJIA

TABLEXIV Number of All Discount Stores (Except for Kmart and Wal-Mart Stores) With Different Market Structure3 Profit Recovers Sunk Cost

Profit Positive Percent

Total

No Kmart or Wal-Mart Only Kmart in each Market Only Wal-Mart in each Market Both Kmart and Wal-Mart

100.0 82.7 78.5 62.7

10,752 8890 8443 6741

No Kmart or Wal-Mart Only Kmart in each Market Only Wal-Mart in each Market Both Kmart and Wal-Mart

100.0 91.9 79.8 72.4

9623 8842 7683 6964

Percent

Total

47.1 43.6 31.5

5064 4692 3383

51.7 42.0 36.5

4976 4043 3508

1988

1997

aI fixthe numberof KmartandWal-Mart storesas specifiedandsolveforthe numberof all otherdiscountstores. See the additionalcommentsin the footnoteto TableXIII.

Looking at the discount industryas a whole, the impact of Kmartand WalMart remains significant,although Kmart's impact is slightly diminished in 1997. Table XIV shows that when a Wal-Martstore enters a market in 1988, 21.5%of the discountfirmswill exit the marketand 56.4%of the firmscannot recover their sunk cost. These numberstranslate to 1.1 stores and 2.9 stores per county,respectively. It is somewhatsurprisingthat the negative impact of Kmarton other firms' profit is comparableto Wal-Mart'simpact, consideringthe controversiesand media reports generated by Wal-Mart.The outcry about Wal-Martwas probably because Wal-Marthad more stores in small- to medium-sized markets where the effect of a big store entry was felt more acutely and because WalMart kept expanding,while Kmartwas consolidatingits existing stores with few net openings in these marketsover the sample period. 7.3. TheImpactof Wal-Mart's Expansionand RelatedPolicyIssues Consistentwith media reports about Wal-Mart'simpact on small retailers, the model predicts that Wal-Mart'sexpansioncontributesto a large percentage of the net decline in the numberof smallfirmsover the sampleperiod.The firstrow in TableXV recordsthe net decrease of 693 smallfirmsobservedover the sampleperiod or 0.34 per market.To evaluatethe impactof Wal-Mart'sexpansionon smallfirmsseparatelyfrom other factors(e.g., the changein market sizes or the change in Kmartstores), I resolve the model using the 1988 coefficients and the 1988 marketsize variablesfor Kmart'sand small firms'profit functions, but the 1997 coefficients and 1997 market size variables for WalMart'sprofitfunction.The experimentcorrespondsto holdingsmallstores and

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1305

TABLEXV The Impact of Wal-Mart's Expansion3

Observeddecrease in the numberof smallstores between 1988 and 1997 Predicteddecreasefrom the full model Percentageexplained Observeddecrease in the numberof all discountstores (except for Kmartand Wal-Martstores) between 1988 and 1997 Predicteddecreasefrom the full model Percentageexplained

1988

1997

693 380 55%

693 259 37%

1021 416 41%

1021 351 34%

aIn the top panel, the predicted 380 store exits in 1988 are obtained by simulating the change in the number of small stores using Kmart'sand the small stores' profit in 1988, but Wal-Mart'sprofit in 1997. The column of 1997 uses Kmart'sand small stores' profit in 1997, but Wal-Mart'sprofit in 1988. Similarly for the second panel.

Kmartthe same as in 1988, but allowingWal-Martto become more efficient and expand. The predicted number of small firms falls by 380. This accounts for 55%of the observeddecrease in the numberof smallfirms.Conductingthe same experimentbut using the 1997coefficientsand the 1997 marketsize variables for Kmart'sand small firms'profit functions, and the 1988 coefficients and 1988 marketsize variablesfor Wal-Mart'sprofit function, I find that WalMart'sexpansion accounts for 259 stores or 37% of the observed decrease in the numberof small firms. Repeating the same exercise using all discount stores, the predictionis similar: roughly30-40% of store exits can be attributedto the expansionof WalMart stores. Overall,the absolute impact of Wal-Mart'sentry seems modest. However, the exercise here only looks at firms in the discount sector. Both Kmartand Wal-Martcarrya large assortmentof productsand compete with a varietyof stores, like hardwarestores, housewarestores, and apparelstores, so their impacton local communitiesis conceivablymuch larger. I tried variousspecificationsthat group retailersin different sectors, for example, all retailers in the discount sector, the building materials sector, and the home-furnishingsector. None of these experimentswas successful,as the retailersin different sectors differ substantiallyand the simple model cannot match the data verywell. Perhapsa better approachis to use a separateprofit function for firms in each sector and estimate the system of profit functions jointly.This is beyond the scope of this paper and is left for future research. Governmentsubsidy has long been a policy instrumentto encourage firm investmentand to createjobs. To evaluatethe effectivenessof this policy in the discount retailing sector, I simulate the equilibriumnumbersof stores when variousfirmsare subsidized.The resultsin TableXVI indicate that direct subsidies do not seem to be effective in generatingjobs. In 1988, subsidizingWalMart stores 10% of their average profit increases the number of Wal-Mart

1306

PANLEJIA TABLEXVI The Impact of Government Subsidies: Changes in the Number of Jobs in the Discount Sector3

Subsidize Kmart's profit by 10% Increase in Kmart's employees Decrease in other stores' employees Subsidize Wal-Mart's profit by 10% Increase in Wal-Mart's employees Decrease in other stores' employees Subsidize small stores' profit by 100% Increase in small stores' employees Decrease in other stores' employees Subsidize all other discount stores' profit by 100% Increase in other discount stores' employees Decrease in Kmart and Wal-Mart stores' employees

1988

1997

4 -1

4 -1

7 -1

8 -1

13 0

12 -2

40 -6

34 -4

aFor each of these counterfactual exercises, I incorporate the change in the subsidized firm's profit as specified, solve for the equilibrium numbers of stores, and obtain the estimated change in employment assuming that (a) a Kmart or a Wal-Mart store employs 300 employees, (b) a small discount store employs 10 employees, and (c) an average discount store employs 25 employees.

stores per county from 0.32 to 0.34.4748With the averageWal-Martstore hiring fewer than 300 full- and part-time employees, the additional number of stores translatesto roughly7 new jobs. Wal-Mart'sexpansioncrowdsout other stores, which bringsthe net increase down to 6 jobs. Similarly,subsidizingall small firmsby 100% of their averageprofit increases their numberfrom 3.78 to 5.07, and generates 13 jobs if, on average,a small firm hires 10 employees. Repeating the exercise with subsidizingall discount stores (except for Kmart and Wal-Martstores) by 100%of their averageprofitleads to a net increaseof 34 jobs. Together,these exercises suggest that a direct subsidydoes not seem to be very effective in generating employment in this industry.These results reinforcethe concernsraisedby manypolicy observersregardingthe subsidies directed to big retail corporations.Perhapsless obvious is the conclusionthat subsidiestowardsmall retailersshould also be designed carefully. 47The average Wal-Mart store's net income in 1988 is about 1 million in 2004 dollars according to its Securities and Exchange Commission annual report. Using a discount rate of 10%, the discounted present value of a store's lifetime profit is about 10 million. A subsidy of 10% is roughly 1 million dollars. 48In this exercise, I first simulate the model 300 times, obtain the mean profit for all Wal-Mart stores for each simulation, and average it across simulations. Then I increase Wal-Mart's profit by 10% of this average (that is, I add this number to the constant of Wal-Mart's profit function) and simulate the model 300 times to obtain the number of Wal-Mart stores after the subsidy.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1307

8. CONCLUSIONAND FUTURE WORK

In this paper, I have examinedthe competitioneffect between Kmartstores, Wal-Martstores, and other discount stores, as well as the role of the chain effect in firms' entry decisions. The negative impact of Kmart'spresence on Wal-Mart'sprofit is much stronger in 1988 than in 1997, while the opposite is true for the effect of Wal-Mart'spresence on Kmart'sprofit. On average, entry by either a Kmartor a Wal-Martstore makes 48-58% of the discount stores (2-3 stores) either unprofitableor unable to recover their sunk cost. Wal-Mart'sexpansionfrom the late 1980sto the late 1990sexplains37-55% of the net change in the numberof small discount stores and 34-41% of the net change in the numberof all discountstores. Like Holmes (2005), I find that scale economies, as capturedby the chain effect, generate substantialbenefits. Withoutthe spillovereffect, the numberof Kmartstores would have decreased by 5.3% in 1988 and 6.5% in 1997, while Wal-Martwould have entered 15.6% fewer markets in 1988 and 7.1% fewer markets in 1997. Studyingthese scale economies in more detail is useful for guiding merger policies or other regulationsthat affect chains. A better understandingof the mechanismunderlyingthese spillovereffects will also help us to gain insightsto the productivitygains in the retail industryover the past severaldecades. Finally,the algorithmused in this paper can be applied to industrieswhere scale economies are important.One possible applicationis to industrieswith cost complementarityamong differentproducts.The algorithmhere is particularlysuitable for modeling firms'product choices when the product space is large. APPENDIX A: Data I went throughall the painstakingdetails to clean the data from the Directory of DiscountStores.After the manuallyentered datawere inspectedmanytimes with the hardcopy, the stores' cities were matchedto belongingcounties using census data.49Some city names listed in the directorycontainedtypos, so I first found possible spellingsusing the census data, then inspectedthe stores' street addresses and zip codes using various web sources to confirm the right city name spelling. The final data set appearsto be quite accurate.I compared it with Wal-Mart'sfirm data and found the difference to be quite small.50For the sample counties, only 30-60 stores were not matched between these two sources for either 1988 or 1997. 49Marie Pees from the Census Bureau kindly provided these data. 50I am very grateful to Emek Basker for sharing the Wal-Mart firm data with me.

1308

PANLEJIA

APPENDIX B: Definitions and Proofs B.I. Verification of the NecessaryCondition(3) Let D* = argmaxDeD II(D). The optimalityof D* impliesthe set of necessary conditions n(D\,...,

D*m_lt D*m,D*m+l,...,D*M)

>n(D\,...,D*m_vDm,D*m+v...,D*M)

Vm,D*m*Dm.

Let D = {D\, ..., D*m_x,Dm, ..., D*M). 77(Z>*)differs from 77(D) in two D*m+1, parts:the profit in market m and the profit in all other marketsthrough the chain effect:

+ sY^-] n(D*)-n(D) = (D*m-Dm)\xm

+s£^(f)-*£^(fL) where Zm/= Z/mdue to symmetry.Since II(D*) - II(D) > 0, D*m^Dm, it must be that D*m= 1 and Dm = 0 if and only if Xm+ 28 Y.\^DVzmi) > 0, = 0 and Dm= 1 if and only if Xm+ 25 £/#m(£>/7zm/)< °- Togetherwe and D*m = \[Xm + 28 Ei*m(D*/Zml)> 0].51 have D*m B.2. TheSet of FixedPointsof an IncreasingFunctionThatMaps a LatticeInto Itself Tarski'sfixed point theorem, stated in the main body of the paper as Theorem 1, establishes that the set of fixed points of an increasingfunction that maps from a lattice into itself is a nonempty complete lattice with a greatest element and a least element. For a counterexamplewhere a decreasingfunction's set of fixedpoints is empty,considerthe followingsimplifiedentrymodel where three firmscompete with each other and decide simultaneouslywhether to enter the market.The profitfunctionsare nk=Dk(0.5-Dw-0.25Ds), nw = Dw(l-0.5Dk-l.lDs), ns = D5(0.6 - 0.7Dk - 0.5DJ. 51I have implicitly assumed that when Xm + 25 J^¥m(D^ fZm{)= 0,D*m= 1.

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1309

Let D = {Dk,Dw,Ds} e D = {0, 1}3, let D_, denote rivals' strategies, let Vi(D-i) denote the best response function for player i, and let V(D) = {Vk(D_k),VW{D_W), VS(D_S)}denote the joint best responsefunction.It is easy to show that V(D) is a decreasingfunction that takes the values K(0, 0,0) = {1,1,1}; F(0, 1,0) = {0,1,1};

K(0, 0,1) = {1,0,1}; K(0, 1,1) = {0,0,1},

K(l, 0, 0) = {1, 1, 0}; K(l, 1,0) = {0,1,0};

F(l, 0, 1) = {1, 0, 0}; K(l, 1,1) = {0,0,0}.

The set of fixed points of V(D) is empty. B.3. A TighterLowerBound and UpperBoundfor the Optimal SolutionVectorD* In Section 5.1 I have shown that using inf(D) and sup(D) as starting points yields, respectively, a lower bound and an upper bound to D* = Here I introduce two bounds that are tighter. The lower argmaxDGD77(D). bound builds on the solution to a constrainedmaximizationproblem:

max n = Y\Dm*(xm + 8Y^-X\ s.t. if Dm= 1, then Zm+ 8y^>0. The solution to this constrained maximizationproblem belongs to the set of fixed points of the vector function V(D) = [VX(D),..., VM(D)},where Vm(D)= l[Xm + 8j:¥m(Dl/Zml) > 0]. When S > 0, the function K(.) is increasingand maps from D into itself: V :D - D. Let D denote the convergent vector using sup(D) as the startingpoint for the iterationon V: V{D) = D. Using argumentssimilarto those in Section 5.1, one can show that D is the greatest element among the set of V's fixed points. Further,D achieves a higher profit than any other fixed point of F(), since by constructioneach nonzero element of the vector D adds to the total profit. Changingany nonzero elements) of D to zero reduces the total profit. To show that D 77(D). Therefore, D* cannot be strictly smaller

1310

PANLEJIA

than D, because anyvector strictlysmallerthan D deliversa lower profit.Suppose D* and D are unordered.Let D**= D* vD (where v definesthe elementby-elementmax operation). The change from D* to D**increasestotal profit, = 1 does not decrease after the change, and because profitat marketswith D*m = profitat marketswith D*m 0 but Dm= 1 is positive by construction.This contradictsthe definitionof D*, so D < D*. Note that V(D) > V(D) = D, where K() is defined in Section 5.1. As in Section 5.1, iterating V on both sides of the inequality V(D) > D generates an increasingsequence. Denote the convergentvector as DT. This is a tighter lowerbound of D* than DL (discussedin Section 5.1) because DT = VTT(D)> K77(inf(D)) = DL,with TT = max{T, T'}9where T is the numberof iterations from D to DT and T is the numberof iterationsfrom inf(D) to DL. Since the chain effect is bounded by zero and SJ2l¥:m j~, it is never optimal to enter markets that contribute a negative element to the total profit even with the largest conceivable chain effect. Let D = {Dm:Dm= 0 if Xm+ 28 E/#m(l/ zmi) < 0; Dm= 1 otherwise}.We know that D > D*. Using the argument above, the convergentvector DT from iterating V on D is a tighter upper bound to D* than Du .

If

B.4. VerificationThatthe Chains'ProfitFunctionsAre SupermodularWith DecreasingDifferences Definition 3: Suppose that Y(X) is a real-valuedfunction on a lattice X.

(7)

Y(Xf) + Y(X") < Y{X' v X") + Y(X' a X")

for all X1 and X" in X, then Y (X) is supermodularon X.52 Definition 4: Supposethat X and K are partiallyorderedsets and Y (X, k) is a real-valuedfunction on X x K. If Y(X, k") - Y(X, k') is increasing,decreasing,strictlyincreasing,or strictlydecreasingin X on X for all k' < k"in K, then Y(X, k) has, respectively,increasingdifferences,decreasingdifferences, strictlyincreasingdifferences,or strictlydecreasingdifferencesin (X, k) on X. Now let us verify that chain i's profit function in the equation system (2) is supermodularin its own strategyDt e D. For ease of notation, the firm sub+ 1) + Jl - p2em+ p^m is scripti is omitted and Xmfit+ 8i}Dum+ 8isln(NStfn absorbedinto Xm.The profit function is simplifiedto 77 = YH=ADm* (Xm+ 8 J2i^m(Di/zmi))l Firstit is easy to show that D' v D" = (Df - min(Dr,D")) + 52Both definitions are taken from Chapter 2 of Topkis (1998).

WHENWAL-MART COMESTOTOWN

1311

(D" - min(D',D")) + min(D',D") and Df a D" = min(D',D"). Let D' min(D',D") be denoted as Du denote D" - mm{D\D") as D2, and denote min(D', D") as D3. The left-handside of the inequality(7) is

n(D) + TI{D")

= Y,[(D'm- min(Zym, + min(D'm> D"m)) D"m)] m

+min(Z)'/' D'!» ^)]1 *\xm+sT^-M - min(^/. + min(/yB,Z^)] + Y\Wm - min(^». D"m)) m

* [zm + 5 Y" ^- [(D'/- min(D',,£>;'))+ min(D;,Z^)]l Zm/ J L

/#m

= T(Dltm+ DXm)(xm + 8 V J-(DW + D3,/))

Similarly,the right-handside of the inequality(7) is J7(Z)'vD") + i7(Z)'AD")

+ £(D>D;)rzm + s£J-(D;AJD;)l J L V ^Zm/ = £(D1)m + s£J-(Dw + 02,,+ Z>3,/)1 + D3,m)[zm +Z)2>m

=

mm

+

mo-)

+

gfe

E

DijmDlJr

DumDv\

1312

PANLEJIA

The profit function is supermodularin its own strategyif the chain effect 8 is nonnegative.Toverifythat the profitfunction 27,has decreasingdifferencesin (£>,,£>,-),write ni(DhD';)-ni(DhDj)

m=l

The differenceis decreasingin Dt for all D'}< Dj as long as 8,y< 0. B.5. ComputationalIssues The main computationalburden of this exercise is the search for the best responsesK(DW)and W(Dk). In Section 5.1, 1 have proposed two bounds Du and DL that help to reduce the numberof profit evaluations.AppendixB.3 illustratesa tighterupperbound and lowerbound thatworkwell in the empirical implementation. When the chain effect Su is sufficientlybig, it is conceivablethat the upper bound and lower bound are far apart from each other. If this happens, computationalburdenonce again becomes an issue, as there will be manyvectors between these two bounds. Two observationswork in favor of the algorithm.First, recall that the chain effect is assumed to take place among counties whose centroids are within 50 miles. Markets that are farther away are not directly "connected":conditioning on the entrydecisions in other markets,the entrydecisions in group A do not depend on the entry decisions in group B if all marketsin group A are at least 50 miles awayfrom any marketin group B. Therefore,what mattersis the size of the largestconnected marketsdifferentbetween Du and DL, rather than the total numberof elements differentbetween Du and DL. To illustrate this point, suppose there are 10 markets:

1 I 2 13 4

5

6

9

10

7

8

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1313

where

1 1D2 I 1 Du

=^T_ 1

D6

11

and

0 I D2 I 0 DL=[T 0 A> 0 0 £>91£>i7 Du and DL are the same in markets2, 6, 9, and 10, but differ for the rest. If markets 1, 4, and 5 (group A) are at least 50 miles away from markets 3, 7, and 8 (group £), one only needs to evaluate 23+ 23 = 16 vectors, ratherthan 26= 64 vectors to find the profit-maximizingvector. The second observationis that even with a sizable chain effect, the event of havingDu and DL differentin a largeconnected area is extremelyunlikely.Let N denote the size of such an area CN.Let £mdenote the randomshocks in the = l[Xm+ 25 T,i#n,ieBm(D¥ / z>m)+ U > 0] profitfunction.By construction,Dum and DLm= l[Xm + 28 Ei*m,izBm(Di/ Zmi) + U > 0]. The probability of Dum= = 0 for every market in the size-Af connected area CN is 1, DLm Pr(Dum= l,DLm= 0,VmzCN) N

i

/

\

+ £*<0,*m+ £m+ 2S J] 7^-°)'
E(f\Pr(Xm+ Zm<0)\=Ema-®(Xm))\ =

Y\[l-E((Xm))]

m=\

= l-\ ^ '

.

1314

PANLEJIA

Therefore,even in the worst scenariothat the chain effect 8 approachesinfinity, the probabilityof having a large connected area that differs between Du and DL decreases exponentiallywith the size of the area. In the currentapplication, the size of the largest connected area that differsbetween DL and Du is seldom biggerthan seven or eight markets. REFERENCES Ackerberg, D., and G. Gowrisankaran (2007): "Quantifying Equilibrium Network Externalities in the ACH Banking Industry," RAND Journal of Economics, 37, 738-761. [1267,1298] Andrews, D., S. Berry, and P. Jia (2004): "Confidence Regions for Parameters in Discrete Games With Multiple Equilibria," Unpublished Manuscript, Yale University. [1267,12881 Archer, J., and D. Taylor (1994): Up Against the Wai-Marts (How YourBusiness Can Survive in the Shadow of the Retail Giants). New York: American Management Association. [1263] Athey, S. (2002): "Monotone Comparative Statics Under Uncertainty," QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 117, 187-223. [1267] Bajari, P., and J. Fox (2005): "Complementarities and Collusion in an FCC Spectrum Auction," Unpublished Manuscript, University of Chicago. [1276] Bajari, P., H. Hong, and S. Ryan (2007): "Identification and Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information," Unpublished Manuscript, Duke University. [1267] Basker, E. (2005a): "Job Creation or Destruction? Labor-Market Effects of Wal-Mart Expansion," Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 174-183. [1268,12701 (2005b): "Selling a Cheaper Mousetrap: Wal-Mart's Effect on Retail Prices," Journal of Urban Economics, 58, 203-229. [1268] Berry, S. (1992): "Estimation of a Model of Entry in the Airline Industry," Econometrica, 60, 889-917. [1267,1287,1288] Bresnahan, T., and P. Reiss (1990): "Entry Into Monopoly Markets," Review of Economic Studies, 57, 531-553. [1267,1287] (1991): "Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets," Journal of Political Economy, 95, 57-81. [1267,1287] Chain Store Guide (1988-1997): Directory of Discount Department Stores. New York: Business Guides Inc. [1270-1272,1291] Chernozhukov, V, H. Hong, and E. Tamer (2007): "Estimation and Confidence Regions for Parameter Sets in Econometric Models," Econometrica, 75, 1243-1284. [1267,12881 Ciliberto, F, and E. Tamer (2006): "Market Structure and Multiple Equilibria in Airline Markets," Unpublished Manuscript, Northwestern University. [1267] Conley, T. (1999): "GMM Estimation With Cross Sectional Dependence," Journal of Econometrics, 92, 1-45. [1265,1284-1286] Conley, T, and E. Ligon (2002): "Economic Distance and Cross Country Spillovers," Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 157-187. [1286] Davis, P. (2006): "Spatial Competition in Retail Markets: Movie Theaters," RAND Journal of Economics, 37, 964-994. [12671 Discount Merchandiser (1988-1997). New York: Schwartz Publications. [1264] and C. J. Krizan (2002): "The Link Between Aggregate and Foster, L., J. Haltiwanger, Micro Productivity Growth: Evidence From Retail Trade," Working Paper 9120, NBER. [13031 Hausman, J., and E. Leibtag (2005): "Consumer Benefits From Increased Competition in Shopping Outlets: Measuring the Effect of Wal-Mart," Working Paper 11809, NBER. [1268] Hess, S., and J. Polak (2003): "A Comparison of Scrambled and Shuffled Halton Sequences for Simulation Based Estimation," Unpublished Manuscript, Imperial College London. [1287] Holmes, T. (2001): "Barcodes Lead to Frequent Deliveries and Superstores," RAND Journal of Economics, 32, 708-725. [1302]

WHEN WAL-MARTCOMESTO TOWN

1315

(2005): "The Diffusion of Wal-Martand Economies of Density,"UnpublishedManuscript,Universityof Minnesota.[1265,1266,1289,1302,1307] House Committee on Small Business (1994): "Impactof Discount Superstoreson Small Businessand Local Communities,"Committee Serial No. 103-99,CongressionalInformation Services,Inc. [1269] Jia, P. (2008): "Supplementto 'What Happens When Wal-MartComes to Town:An Empirical Analysisof the Discount RetailingIndustry',"EconometricaSupplementalMaterial,76, http:// and programs.zip.[1268] www.econometricsociety.org/ecta/Supmat/6649_data Kmart Inc. (1988-2000):Annual Report. [12931 Mazzeo, M. (2002): "ProductChoice and OligopolyMarketStructure,"RANDJournalof Economics,33, 1-22. [1267] McFadden, D. (1989): "AMethod of SimulatedMomentsfor Estimationof Discrete Response Models WithoutNumericalIntegration,"Econometrica,57, 995-1026. [1284] MlLGROM, P., and C. Shannon (1994): "Monotone ComparativeStatics,"Econometrica,62, 157-180. [1267,1280] Neumark, D., J. Zhang, and S. Ciccarella (2005):"TheEffects of Wal-Marton Local Labor Markets,"WorkingPaper 11782,NBER. [1268] Newey, W, and K. West (1987): "A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticityand AutocorrelationConsistentCovarianceMatrix,"Econometrica,55, 703-708. [1286] Nishida, M. (2008): "Estimatinga Model of StrategicStore NetworkChoice With PolicySimulation,"UnpublishedManuscript,Universityof Chicago.[1266] Pakes, A., and D. Pollard (1989): "Simulationand the Asymptoticsof OptimizationEstimators,"Econometrica,57, 1027-1057. [1284] Pakes, A., J. Porter, K. Ho, and J. Ishii (2005):"MomentInequalitiesand TheirApplication," UnpublishedManuscript,HarvardUniversity.[1267,1288] Pinkse, J., M. Slade, and C. Brett (2002): "SpatialPrice Competition:A Semiparametric Approach,"Econometrica,70, 1111-1153. [1267] Romano, J., and A. Shaikh (2006): "Inferencefor the Identified Set in PartiallyIdentified EconometricModels,"UnpublishedManuscript,Universityof Chicago.[1267,1288] Seim, K. (2006): "AnEmpiricalModel of Firm EntryWith EndogenousProduct-TypeChoices," RANDJournalof Economics,37, 619-640. [1267] Shils, E. B. (1997): The Shils Report:Measuringthe Econometricand SociologicalImpactof the in Urban,SuburbanandRuralCommunities. DiscountChainson SmallEnterprises Mega-Retailer. Philadelphia,PA:WhartonSchool, Universityof Pennsylvania.[1264] Smith, H. (2004):"SupermarketChoice and SupermarketCompetitionin MarketEquilibrium," Reviewof EconomicStudies,71, 235-263. [1265,12671 STONE,K. (1995): "Impactof Wal-MartStores on Iowa Communities:1983-93,"EconomicDevelopmentReview,13, 60-69. [1268] Tamer, E. (2003): "IncompleteSimultaneousDiscrete Response Model With MultipleEquilibria,"Reviewof EconomicStudies,70, 147-165. [1267] Tarski, A. (1955):"ALattice-TheoreticalFixpointand Its Applications,"PacificJournalof Mathematics,5, 285-309. [1267,1279] Topkis, D. (1978): "Minimizinga SubmodularFunctionon a Lattice,"OperationsResearch,26, 305-321. [1267,1280,1281] and Complementarity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University (1998): Supermodularity Press. [1281,1310] Train, K. (2000): "HaltonSequencesfor MixedLogit,"UnpublishedManuscript,UC Berkeley. [1287] (2003):DiscreteChoiceMethodsWithSimulation.Cambridge,U.K.: CambridgeUniverPress. sity [1287] Bureau (1993-1997):AnnualBenchmarkReportfor RetailTradeand Food Services. U.S. CENSUS Washington,DC: U.S. GovernmentPrintingOffice. [1264]

1316

PANLEJIA

( 1997) : Establishment and Firm Size (Including Legal Form of Organization), Economics Census Retail Trade Series. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. [1264] VANCE, S., and R. SCOTT(1994): A History of Sam Walton's Retail Phenomenon. New York: Twayne Publishers. [1269,1271] Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. (1970-2000): Annual Report. [1293] Zhou, L. (1994): "The Set of Nash Equilibria of a Supermodular Game Is a Complete Lattice," Games and Economic Behavior, 7, 295-300. [12811 Zhu, T, and V. Singh (2007): "Spatial Competition With Endogenous Location Choices: An Application to Discount Retailing," Unpublished Manuscript, University of Chicago. [1268]

50 MemorialDrive, Dept.of Economics,MassachusettsInstituteof Technology, MA and NBER;[email protected]. Cambridge, 02142, U.SA. Manuscript received August, 2006; final revision received January, 2008.

What Happens When Wal-Mart Comes to Town: An ...

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students .... local communities has become a matter of public concern.5 My first goal in this ..... the directory lists its name, size, street address, telephone number, store for-.

6MB Sizes 1 Downloads 143 Views

Recommend Documents

What Happens When Wal-Mart Comes to Town: An ...
There is ample evidence that a small business need not fail in the face of competition from large discount .... modeling chains' entry decisions in a large number of markets. The model has two key ..... 800 stores in 1997. Most of them were ...

Online PDF Empower: What Happens When Students ...
span class news dt 12 08 2017 span nbsp 0183 32 When Apple products are in ... children’s online privacy The company allegedly allowed Exciting lesson ...

What Happens When a Water Treatment Plant Fails.pdf
p.m. Monday, the DEP and City of Trenton. issued a “system wide” water conservation. notice for all Trenton Water Works. customers, asking them to “limit all water uses, and refrain from any nonessential uses of water to. help available water s

What happens when cognitive terminals compete for a ...
amplification gain is fixed; the IRC direct links are negligible. We show how ... system where two cognitive transmitters, each of them communicat- ing with their ...

What happens when cognitive terminals compete for a ...
In [6] the authors study the same channel but ... propose a way of making this assumption reasonable in Sec. 5) and subject to the ... To conclude this section note that will call the state of the .... ios where they do not vary rapidly over time, it

What Comes from Plants
It's simple. We cannot live without green plants. In fact, no animals can live without green plants. Why? There are two reasons. First, green plants give us food. They give us food because they can make their own food. No other living thing can do th

What image comes to mind when you think about making a vow ...
Of course, I also see these students ... kept them as best they could. Some people .... but it all remains in computer files and has never been shared with anyone.

What image comes to mind when you think about making a vow ...
wholly dedicated to Christ, in which the material world becomes secondary to the inner life of the .... Despite all odds, she managed to complete high school and ...

AAM Museum Mag When Slavery Comes to Stay.pdf
Page 2 of 8. Page 3 of 8. Page 3 of 8. AAM Museum Mag When Slavery Comes to Stay.pdf. AAM Museum Mag When Slavery Comes to Stay.pdf. Open. Extract.

When-the-Oilpatch-Comes-to-Your-Backyard.pdf
Page 3 of 10. i. Acknowledgements and Disclaimer. The author would like to thank and acknowledge the persons who have made the. publication of this citizens' guide possible. The Pembina Institute for Appropriate. Development in Alberta generously sup

Book god is stranger what happens when god turns up? pdf free download
Book god is stranger what happens when god turns up? pdf free download

What to Do When You've Blown It
Name someone whom you have observed to be humble. .... Fanny J. Crosby, “Let Me Cling to Thee,” public domain. BIBLICAL ... or call USA 1-800-772-8888 • AUSTRALIA +61 3 9762 6613 • CANADA 1-800-663-7639 • UK +44 1306 640156.