A Note on Cyclical Discount Factors and Labor Market Volatility Toshihiko Mukoyama∗ September 2009

Abstract In this paper, I examine how time-varying discount factors can contribute to labor market volatility in a Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides matching model. I find that the procyclical discount factor of either entrepreneurs or workers can magnify labor market volatility. Quantitatively, the entrepreneur’s discount factor has a larger effect than the worker’s discount factor. To account for the observed labor market volatility, an extremely large variation in discount factors is necessary. Keywords: cyclical discount factors, Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides model, labor market volatility JEL Classifications: E24, E32, J64



University of Virginia and CIREQ. P.O. Box 400182, Charlottesville, VA 22904-4182. Tel: +1-434-924-6751, E-mail: [email protected].

1

1

Introduction

Since the seminal work of Shimer (2005), many solutions have been proposed to resolve the so-called labor market volatility puzzle. Shimer observed that a standard Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides (DMP henceforth) model cannot account for the quantitative variation in vacancy and unemployment during the business cycle.1 Potential solutions to this puzzle include: (i) sticky wages (Hall (2005), Shimer (2005), and Gertler and Trigari (2008)), (ii) different calibration strategies (Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008)), (iii) on-the-job search (Nagyp´al (2007)), and (iv) incomplete markets and long-term contracts (Rudanko (2008, 2009)), to name a few. This paper contributes to this literature. In this paper, I consider the variation in discount factors over the business cycle. In particular, I assume that the discount factors of either entrepreneurs (who own the firms and post vacancies) or workers (who work at the firm) are procyclical. I find that procyclical discount factors can magnify the labor market volatility. Quantitatively, entrepreneurs’ discount factors have a larger effect than workers’ discount factors. However, to account for the volatility observed in the data, an extremely large degree of variation is required. I offer two interpretations of the entrepreneur’s procyclical discount factor: (i) a cyclical financial constraint, and (ii) a cyclical stochastic discount factor by the entrepreneurs/investors. These interpretations represent a link between financial market volatility and labor market volatility. Similarly to (ii), the worker’s procyclical discount factor can be interpreted as a cyclical stochastic discount factor by the workers. From this viewpoint, cyclical discount factors of entrepreneurs seem empirically more relevant considering the recent studies by Guvenen (2007) and Parker and VissingJørgensen (2009). In particular, Guvenen suggests that stockholders’ income risks are less insured than non-stockholders’ income risks. Parker and Vissing-Jørgensen show that wealthy households’ consumption is more volatile than that of non-wealthy households. Hall and Woodward (2008) document that entrepreneurs bear a large non-diversifyable risk. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model and calibration. Section 3 1

See also Andolfatto (1996) for an earlier observation.

2

presents the result. Section 4 concludes.

2

Model

I employ a standard DMP model with exogenous separation (Pissarides (1985)). The calibration largely follows Shimer (2005).

2.1

Model setup

Time is discrete. The economy is made up of entrepreneurs and workers, with a each population equal to 1. Entrepreneurs own the firm and post vacancies optimally so that their utility is Uf =

∞ X

Btf cft ,

t=0

where cft is the consumption of the entrepreneurs (a superscript or subscript f represents “firm”) at time t. The cumulative discount factor Btf evolves according to f Bt+1 = Btf βf (zt ),

where zt is the aggregate state at time t. The aggregate state is assumed to take one of two values: zt ∈ {g, b}. The output of a job-worker match, y, is affected by the aggregate state. In particular, we assume that y(g) > y(b). zt follows a Markov process and the transition probability from state z to state z 0 is represented by πzz 0 . Workers supply labor and maximize Uw =

∞ X

Btw cw t ,

t=0

where cw t is the consumption of the workers (a superscript or subscript w represents “worker”) at time t. The cumulative discount factor Btw evolves according to w Bt+1 = Btw βw (zt ).

The entrepreneurs post vt amount of vacancies at time t. It costs ξ units of consumption goods to post one unit of vacancy. Vacancies and unemployed workers meet according to the matching 3

function M (vt , ut ) = χvt1−η uηt , where ut is the number of unemployed workers. From this matching function, the probability that a vacancy finds a worker is λf (θt ) =

M (vt , ut ) = χθt1−η vt

and the probability that an unemployed worker finds a vacant job is λw (θt ) =

M (vt , ut ) = χθt−η . ut

Here, θt = vt /ut is the vacancy-unemployment ratio. I solve the model using a recursive formulation.2 It turns out that for all of the endogenous variables, I can use z as the state variable. The value of a filled job, J(z) is J(z) = y(z) − w(z) + βf (z)E[σV (z 0 ) + (1 − σ)J(z 0 )|z], where w(z) is the wage in state z and E[·|z] is the conditional expectation given the current state z. The value of a vacancy is V (z) = −ξ + βf (z)E[λf (θ)J(z 0 ) + (1 − λf (θ)V (z 0 )|z].

(1)

Since the entrepreneurs can optimally choose the amount of vacancy, the free-entry condition V (z) = 0 has to hold in equilibrium. This condition determines θ, and therefore θ is a function of z: θ(z). The value functions for the workers are W (z) = w(z) + βw (z)E[σU (z 0 ) + (1 − σ)W (z 0 )|z] for employed workers and U (z) = h + βw (z)E[(1 − λw (θ(z)))U (z 0 ) + λw (θ(z))W (z 0 )|z] for unemployed workers. Here, I assume that an unemployed worker can receive h units of consumption goods. 2

A similar formulation is used in Krusell, Mukoyama, and S ¸ ahin (2009).

4

I assume that the wage is determined by a generalized Nash barganing solution: w(z) is chosen to maximize (W (z) − U (z))γ (J(z) − V (z))1−γ . Since W (z) − U (z) and J(z) − V (z) are linear in w(z), the Nash bargaining solution results in the simple surplus-sharing rules W (z) − U (z) = γS(z) and J(z) − V (z) = (1 − γ)S(z),

(2)

S(z) = (W (z) − U (z)) + (J(z) − V (z))

(3)

where

is the total surplus. Therefore, w is indeed a function of z. From (1), (2), and V (z) = 0, it follows that ξ = βf (z)[πzg λf (θ(z))(1 − γ)S(g) + πzb λf (θ(z))(1 − γ)S(b)].

(4)

There are two equations (for each z) here. These two equations can be rewritten as S(g) =

πbb X(g) − πgb X(b) P

(5)

S(b) =

πgg X(b) − πbg X(g) , P

(6)

and

where X(z) = ξ/(βf (z)λf (θ(z))(1 − γ)) and P = πgg πbb − πbg πgb = πbb − πgb . From (3) and the value functions, S(z) = y(z) − h + (πzg S(g) + πzb S(b))[βf (z)(1 − σ)(1 − γ) + βw (z)(1 − σ − λw (z))γ]

(7)

holds (there are two equations here). Therefore, the four equations (5), (6), and (7) can be solved for four unknowns: S(z) and θ(z) for each z. Once these are found, we can calculate the wage as w(z) = y(z) − (1 − γ)S(z) + βf (z)(1 − σ)(πzg (1 − γ)S(g) + πzb (1 − γ)S(b)). 5

Unemployment follows u0 = u + σ(1 − u) − λw (θ(z))u. Vacancy can be calculated as v = θ(z)u.

2.2

Calibration

A large part of calibration follows Shimer (2005). In particular, I assume that η = 0.72, γ = 0.72, and h = 0.4. I set one period as 6 weeks. For the business cycles, I set y(g) = 1.02, y(b) = 0.98, and πgg = πbb = 0.9375. ξ is set so that θ = 1 holds in the deterministic steady state (that is, all the cyclical parameters are set at their average values) of the model. In particular, from (4) and (7), ξ=

βf λf (1 − γ)(y − h) 1 − βf (1 − σ)(1 − γ) − βw (1 − σ − λw )γ

(8)

has to be satisfied in the deterministic steady state. Noting that λw = λf = χ when θ = 1, this equation (with average values of parameters βf , βw , and y) pins down the value of ξ. The baseline value of βf and βw are set at 0.995, but these will be changed in the experiments.

3

Results

In the first experiment, I make βf procyclical. In particular, I keep βf (g) = 0.995 and vary βf (b). βw (g) and βw (b) are also set at 0.995. Figure 1 shows the differences in the unemployment rates (the average when z = g and the average when z = b) for various values of βf (b). For each βf (b), ξ is set so that (8) is satisfied. βf (b) = 0.995 is the standard model with constant and homogeneous discount factors. As is shown in Shimer (2005), the standard model does not generate high volatility in the labor market. It can be seen that lowering βf (b) helps to increase labor market volatility, although to attain a significant effect an extremely low βf (g) is necessary. What does a low βf (b) mean? I offer two interpretations here. First, it can represent the financial constraints faced by the entrepreneurs. If an entrepreneur depends on outside funds, and if 1 + r is the gross cost of the funds, then she discounts the future profit by βf = 1/(1 + r). If r is 6

0.09

average u when z=b 0.085

u

0.08

average u when z=g 0.075

0.07 0.5

0.6

0.7

βf(b)

0.8

0.9

0.995

Figure 1: Average unemployment rates when z = g and z = b. cyclical, it shows up in a cyclical βf . A low βf (b) means that the entrepreneur’s cost of raising funds is high during recessions. Second, if the entrepreneur has to self-finance and has a concave utility function U (cft ), the stochastic discount factor of the entrepreneur/investor is βf U 0 (cft+1 )/U 0 (cft ) and the future is discounted more heavily when cft is low. For example, when U (c) = c1−ν /(1 − ν) for ν > 0, βf U 0 (cft+1 )/U 0 (cft ) = βf (ct+1 /ct )−ν and 1% change in consumption is translated into ν% change in the stochastic discount factor. Although a linear utility is assumed here, the stochastic βf can be seen as a shortcut in analyzing a stochastic discount factor with concave utility. Figure 2 shows a case where βf is constant at 0.995 and βw (b) is changed instead. It can be seen that lowering βw (b) magnifies labor-market volatility but the quantitative impact is smaller than the case of cyclical βf (b). Recent empirical evidence in Guvenen (2007) and Parker and Vissing-Jørgensen (2009) seems to suggest that a cyclical βf (b) is more important in light of the second interpretation above. Guvenen’s result suggests that stockholders’ income shocks are less insured than those of non-stockholders. This implies that it is more likely that the marginal utility of stockholders3 fluctuates more than that of non-stockholders. 3

As Hall and Woodward (2008) argue, in the standard venture capital contract, entrepreneurs retain a large

7

0.09

0.085

average u when z=b u

0.08

0.075

average u when z=g 0.07 0.5

0.6

0.7

βw(b)

0.8

0.9

0.995

Figure 2: Average unemployment rates when z = g and z = b.

4

Conclusion

This paper analyzes the effects of cyclical discount factors on labor market dynamics. It is shown that procyclical discount factors, of either entrepreneurs or workers, magnify unemployment volatility. Quantitatively, the entrepreneur’s discount factor has a larger impact than the worker’s discount factor. To achieve a realistic labor market volatility, an extreme amount of variation in discount factors is necessary.

fraction of equity ownership in the companies they found.

8

References [1] Andolfatto, David (1996). “Business Cycles and Labor Market Search,” American Economic Review 86, 112-132. [2] Gertler, Mark and Antonella Trigari (2006). “Unemployment Fluctuations with Staggered Nash Wage Bargaining,” New York University and IGIER, Universit` a Bocconi. [3] Guvenen, Fatih (2007) “Do Stockholders Share Risk More Effectively than Non-stockholders?” Review of Economics and Statistics 89, 275-288. [4] Hagedorn, Marcus and Iourii Manovskii (2008). “The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies Revisited,” American Economic Review, 1692-1706. [5] Hall, Robert E. (2005). “Employment Fluctuations with Equilibrium Wage Stickiness,” American Economic Review 95, 50-65. [6] Hall, Robert E. and Susan Woodward (2008). “The Burden of the Nondiversifiable Risk of Entrepreneurship,” NBER Working Paper 14219. ul S¸ahin (2009). “Labor-Market Matching with [7] Krusell, Per; Toshihiko Mukoyama; and Ay¸seg¨ Precautionary Savings and Aggregate Fluctuations,” mimeo. Princeton University, University of Virginia, and Federal Reserve Bank of New York. ´ (2007). “Labor-Market Fluctuations and On-the-Job Search,” mimeo. Northwest[8] Nagyp´al, Eva ern University. [9] Pissarides, Christopher A. (1985). “Short-Run Equilibrium Dynamics of Unemployment, Vancancies, and Real Wages,” American Economic Review 75, 676-690. [10] Parker, Jonathan A. and Annette Vissing-Jørgensen (2009). “Who Bears Aggregate Fluctuations? Estimates and Implications for Consumption Inequality,” American Economic Review 99, 399-405.

9

[11] Rudanko, Leena (2008). “Idiosyncratic and Aggregate Risk in a Frictional Labor Market,” mimeo. Boston University. [12] Rudanko, Leena (2009). “Labor Market Dynamics under Long Term Wage Contracting,” Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 170-183. [13] Shimer, Robert J. (2005). “The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies,” American Economic Review 95, 25-49.

10

A Note on Cyclical Discount Factors and Labor Market ...

ment during the business cycle.1 Potential solutions to this puzzle include: (i) sticky ... The aggregate state is assumed to take one of two values: ... I solve the model using a recursive formulation.2 It turns out that for all of the endogenous.

132KB Sizes 1 Downloads 137 Views

Recommend Documents

A Note on Cyclical Discount Factors and Labor Market ...
To account for the observed labor market volatility, an extremely large variation in discount ..... Precautionary Savings and Aggregate Fluctuations,” mimeo.

Structural and Cyclical Forces in the Labor Market ...
Source: FRED database, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Deflated .... Kimball, Miles S. (1995), “The quantitative analytics of the basic neomonetarist model,”.

A Field Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination
possibility of African-American to get a job, and there are others who think that there is ... telephone numbers, postal addresses, and (possibly) e-mail addresses.

Parental Influence on the Labor Market Outcomes and ...
Nov 14, 2014 - their job match quality if they have a bad realization in their current location. The model also includes large moving costs which are subject to idiosyncratic shocks, which means agents also may wait to move until they receive favorab

A Note on Marriage Market Clearing
∗We thank Berthold Herrendorf, Larry E. Jones, John Knowles, Narayana Kocher- lakota ... careful measurement cannot take into account that the marriage age may ..... Tertilt, M., 2005, Polygyny, fertility, and savings, Journal of Political Econ-.

A Note on Entrepreneurial Risk, Capital Market ...
Nov 8, 2008 - The Fortran code solving the benchmark model is available from the ..... (2006), “Approximate Aggregation,” manuscript, University of Virginia.

Financial Disruptions and the Cyclical Upgrading of Labor
Apr 17, 2017 - Keywords: Business cycles, financial frictions, labor search frictions, ... eral equilibrium version of the canonical model this degree of wage ...

Hiring Policies, Labor Market Institutions, and Labor ...
workers across existing jobs to obtain better matches between workers ... Arizona State, Maryland, Wharton, Toronto, California at San Diego, Texas, and. Rice for comments. Rogerson acknowledges support from the National Science. Foundation. ... ploy

Trade and Labor Market Dynamics - CiteSeerX
Aug 25, 2015 - Taking a dynamic trade model with all these features to the data, and ...... Appliance (c14); Transportation Equipment (c15); Furniture and ...

Heterogeneous Information and Labor Market ...
†Email: [email protected]. 1 .... 4In the benchmark calibration, firm-specific shocks are also slightly more persistent than aggregate shocks. Since hiring decisions ...

Labor and Market Economy.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Labor and ...

Labor market and search through personal contacts
May 3, 2012 - Keywords: Labor market; unemployment; job search; social network. ..... link between workers in time period t is formed with probability. 10 ...

Heterogeneous Information and Labor Market ...
eliminate this discrepancy between the data and model-predicted movements. ..... Substituting in (5), integrating over all i and ignoring the constant terms ...... In practice, the ability of an individual firm to forecast conditions in the labor mar

Growth and Labor Market Composition
Sep 11, 2017 - workers earn a positive return for staying at the same firm for additional .... from the Labor Force Survey, whose survey design is similar to that of the .... They conclude that in Japan starting a career as a temporary worker has a.

Fraternities and Labor Market Outcomes
Jan 7, 2011 - Estimation. Conclusion. Fraternities. We study the situation where productivity irrelevant activity is job market relevant. Fraternity membership is more than "club good": too expensive; many people mention them on resumes. Sergey V. Po

Optimal Redistributive Policy in a Labor Market with Search and ...
∗Email addresses: [email protected] and [email protected]. ... Our baseline optimization in the benchmark case suggests that applying the.

Monetary Policy and Labor Market Frictions: a Tax ...
Dec 6, 2011 - matching of unemployed workers with job vacancies, replicating the flexible price allocation, even. 5 if feasible, is generally not desirable.

Growth and Labor Market Composition
Sep 16, 2017 - 3. contract workers .... Results. Moments comparison under two regimes. (1). (2) ... Labor contracts and flexibility: evidence from a labor market.

Optimal Redistributive Policy in a Labor Market with Search and ...
Heterogeneous, risk-averse agents look for a job in a labor market characterized by an aggregate ... ∗Email addresses: [email protected] and [email protected]. ...... E. Stiglitz, McGraw-Hill Book Co., London, New York.

HB ON Labor Market Test FINAL.pdf
PRESCRIBED PERIOD. Whoops! There was a problem loading this page. Retrying... Main menu. Displaying HB ON Labor Market Test FINAL.pdf. Page 1 of 5.

Valuating payoff streams under unequal discount factors
c Turku School of Economics, Finland. Received 12 June ... 1 The reason for this is that player's trade-off between consuming today versus later differ ... beneficial “payoff trades”. ... of other repeated games are provided in the final section.

Effect Of Ecological Factors On The Growth And Chlorophyll A ...
Effect Of Ecological Factors On The Growth And Chlor ... ed Kappaphycus alvarezii In Coral Reef Ecosystem.pdf. Effect Of Ecological Factors On The Growth And ...

Efficient Firm Dynamics in a Frictional Labor Market
Holloway, SAET (Faro), SED (Montreal, Seoul), SITE, St. Gallen, St. Louis Fed, Tor Vergata. Rome, Toulouse, UC Los Angeles, UC San Diego, UC Santa Barbara, University of Penn- sylvania, Verein fuer Socialpolitik, Vienna Macroeconomics Workshop (Rome)

Unions in a Frictional Labor Market
Apr 7, 2012 - take these adjustment costs into account in deciding on their wage .... In addition to the market production technology, unemployed workers also have access to a ..... t=0 determines, at each instant, the present value of wages workers