Does Yuan Appreciation Weaken the Increase in Exporters due to Trade Liberalization? Evidence from Chinese Firm-Product Data Zhe Chen∗

Yoshinori Kurokawa†

Preliminary Draft: September 8, 2017

Abstract Using Chinese firm-product data from 2000 to 2006, this paper empirically tests whether or not the appreciation (depreciation) of Chinese Yuan weakens (strengthens) the effect of trade liberalization on the extensive margin of China’s exports to 170 countries. Based on regressions, we have four main empirical findings. First, reductions in tariffs, charged by China’s trade partners, increased China’s exporter numbers and export value/quantity per exporter at the product level while the appreciation (depreciation) of Chinese Yuan decreased (increased) them—the effect of exchange rates is larger than that of tariffs in all cases. Second, reductions in tariffs, charged by trade partners, do not affect the entry or exit of China’s exporters while Chinese Yuan appreciation/depreciation does affect entry but does not affect exit. Third, processing trade firms are more affected by tariffs and exchange rates than ordinary trade firms are. Fourth, the effects are more significant if export destinations are non-OECD countries.

JEL classification: F12, F14, F31 Keywords: Melitz model, exchange rates, tariffs, extensive margin, exports



School of International Trade and Economics, University of International Business and Economics. 1302 Boxue Building, 10 Huixin Dongjie, Chaoyang District, Beijing 100029, China. E-mail: [email protected]. † Faculty of Humanities and Social Sciences, University of Tsukuba. 1-1-1 Tennodai, Tsukuba, Ibaraki 305-8571, Japan. E-mail: [email protected].

1

1

Introduction

One of the most notable works in the recent history of international trade is the Melitz (2003) model of heterogeneous firm trade. The model theoretically shows that a reduction in trade costs decreases the export cutoff productivity level, increasing the number of exporters—the extensive margin (henceforth EM) of exports. In fact, it has been empirically documented that the EM indeed increased after trade liberalization (e.g., Kehoe and Ruhl, 2013). Little attention, however, has been paid to the effects of nominal exchange rates in this literature.1 This is probably because the Melitz model of trade is a real model and thus does not explicitly deal with the monetary aspects of trade such as changes in nominal exchange rates, although it is possible to extend the discussion of the Melitz model to analyze the effect of nominal exchange rates. In fact, introducing nominal exchange rates (the price of the foreign currency in the home currency) into the Melitz model implies the following:2 Under the fixed exchange rate regime (say, nominal exchange rates are constant), the model is the same as the original the Melitz model. Thus, as is well-known, a reduction in trade costs decreases the export cutoff productivity level, increasing the EM of exports. Under the flexible exchange rate regime, however, if a reduction in trade costs is weakened by a change in nominal exchange rates (appreciation), the export cutoff moves less and thus the EM increases less than if only trade costs reduce. On the other hand, if the effect of a reduction in trade costs is strengthened by a change in nominal exchange rates (depreciation), the export cutoff moves more and thus the EM increases more than if only trade costs reduce.3 Thus, while it has been empirically documented that the EM indeed increased after trade liberalization, the observed changes in EM after trade liberalization might have been the results weakened or strengthened by changes in nominal exchange rates. In other words, they might have been stronger or weaker without changes in nominal exchange rates. 1

As will be mentioned later, Bergin and Lin (2008) examine the effect of exchange rate regimes on the EM of trade. 2 Deriving the implications on the EM from the Melitz model with nominal exchange rates is simple and has been relegated to Appendix A.1. Note that although they derive a different empirical question from ours, Baggs et al. (2009) also introduce exchange rates into the Melitz model. Their question is whether the effects of real exchange rates on firm survival/exit and sales are different for firms with different productivity. 3 Feenstra (1989) theoretically argues that the effects of tariffs and exchange rates on the price of imports are symmetric, and empirically tests whether their effects on U.S. prices of Japanese cars, trucks, and motorcycles are symmetric.

2

This is important particularly for empirical studies on trade liberalization and the EM because they might have underestimated or overestimated the pure effect of trade liberalization on the EM. To the best of our knowledge, however, no previous studies have empirically tested the above implications from the Melitz model.4 We now fill this void. We use Chinese firm-product data from 2000 to 2006 to test whether or not the appreciation (depreciation) of Chinese Yuan weakens (strengthens) the effect of trade liberalization on the EM of China’s exports to 170 countries. The benchmark regression results suggest that reductions in tariffs that are charged by China’s trade partners increased China’s exporter numbers at the product level while the appreciation (depreciation) of Chinese Yuan decreased (increased) them. The results thus support the theoretical implication that an increase in the EM of exports due to trade liberalization can be weakened by currency appreciation or strengthened by currency depreciation. The regression results are similar for the export value and quantity per exporter—the intensive margin of exports—at the product level. In all cases, the impact of nominal exchange rates is larger than that of tariffs. When we investigate the effects on the entry and exit of China’s exporters, the regression results suggest that reductions in tariffs, charged by trade partners, do not affect the entry or exit of exporters while Chinese Yuan appreciation/depreciation does affect entry but does not affect exit. We also perform several robustness checks regarding trade modes (ordinary vs. processing trade), export destinations (OECD vs. non-OECD countries), and real exchange rates. Thus, we make the following contributions to the literature on the EM of trade. One set of studies (e.g., Melitz, 2003) focus on the effect of trade liberalization on the EM of trade. Another set of studies (e.g., Bergin and Lin, 2008) focus on the effect of exchange rates on the EM of trade. In this line of studies, we focus on the effects of these two factors on the EM of trade, in particular, using Chinese firm-product data we empirically investigate whether or not the effect of trade liberalization on the EM of China’s exports is weakened (strengthened) by Chinese Yuan appreciation (depreciation). Baggs et al. (2009) (henceforth BBF) also look at both liberalization and exchange rates, but they empirically test, using Canadian industry4

Note that as mentioned by Baggs et al. (2009), most empirical studies that examine tariff changes/trade liberalization include exchange rates as a control variable; however, the analysis is at the industry-level, not at the firm-level.

3

firm data, if tariffs and real (not nominal) exchange rates symmetrically affect Canadian firm survival/exit (not the EM of exports). Moreover, we have recently found Fitzgerald and Hallerz (2017) (henceforth FH), who empirically test, using Irish firm-product data, if tariffs and real exchange rates symmetrically affect Irish exporters. Their paper is close to BBF in that both empirically test the equivalence between tariffs and real exchange rates; however, it is also close to our paper in that both focus on the effects on exporters. FH are thus somewhere in the middle of BBF and our paper. There are four major differences among our paper, BBF, and FH. The first difference is that while BBF and FH both focus on real exchange rates, our paper focuses on nominal exchange rates, although we also do robustness checks with real ones. The second is that while BBF use industry-firm data, our paper and FH both use more detailed data, that is, firm-product data. The third is that while BBF and FH, respectively, cover the United States and 30 countries as trade partners, our paper covers much more countries, 170 countries. The fourth is that all of the three studies show different results: the effect of exchange rates is larger than that of tariffs in China (our paper), similar in Canada (BBF), and smaller in Ireland (FH). Therefore, these three papers are very good complements. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 documents the regression specification and data. We report regression results in Section 3. Section 4 concludes.

2 2.1 2.1.1

Regression Specification and Data Regression Specification Exporter Numbers and Export Value/Quantity per Exporter

As has mentioned in the introduction, the Melitz model with nominal exchange rates implies that an increase in the EM of exports due to trade liberalization can be weakened by currency appreciation or strengthened by currency depreciation. Guided by this theoretical implication, we empirically investigate the impact of tariffs and exchange rates on exporter numbers at the product level. The benchmark regression is as follows: ln(Eijt ) = α0 + α1 ln(T arif fijt ) + α2 ln(N ERjt ) + Other Controls + ijt

4

(2.1)

Here, Eijt is the number of exporters of product i from China to country j at time t. T arif fijt is the tariff of product i charged by country j at time t. N ERjt is the nominal exchange rate, which is defined as Chinese Yuan per currency of country j at time t. Thus, when N ER increases, Chinese Yuan depreciates. Some inputs that are used by Chinese firms are imported, and thus we control China’s import tariffs within the same industry (HS2 level). Finally, we also control the product, country and time fixed effects. If α1 is negative and α2 is positive, then the implication from the Melitz model is supported. When T arif f decreases, the EM of exports increases. When Chinese Yuan appreciates (depreciates), the EM of exports decreases (increases). That is, the increase in EM of exports due to tariff reductions is weakened by currency appreciation or strengthened by currency depreciation. We also empirically investigate the impact on export value/quantity per exporter—the intensive margin of exports—at the product level. Then Eijt is the export value/quantity per exporter of product i from China to country j at time t. 2.1.2

Entry and Exit of Exporters

In the previous section, we have seen a change in exporter numbers which is the result of entry and exit. Thus we also investigate the impacts of tariffs and exchange rates on the entry and exit of exporters. The benchmark regression is as follows: ln(ENijt )d = β0 + β1 ln(T arif fijt )d + β2 ln(N ERjt )d + Other Controls + ηijt

(2.2)

Here, ln(ENijf t )d is the log difference of new exporter numbers or exit exporter numbers of product i to country j between year t − 1 and t. ln(T arif fijt )d is the log difference of tariff of product i charged by country j between year t − 1 and t. ln(N ERjt )d is the log difference of Chinese Yuan per currency of country j between year t − 1 and t. Hence, when ln(N ERjt )d increases, Chinese Yuan depreciates. We control the log difference of China’s import tariffs within the same industry (HS2 level). Finally, we also control the product, country and time fixed effects. When EN is new exporter numbers, if β1 is negative and β2 is positive, then a decrease in T arif f causes more Chinese firms to enter foreign markets while Chinese Yuan appreciation (depreciation) causes less (more) Chinese firms to enter. When EN is exit exporter numbers, if β1 is positive and β2 is negative, then a decrease in T arif f causes less

5

Chinese firms to quit foreign markets while Chinese Yuan appreciation (depreciation) causes more (less) Chinese firms to quit.

2.2

Data

The exchange rate and CPI data are from the IMF at the quarterly level.5 The tariff

6

data

is from the UNCTAD - Trade Analysis Information System (TRAINS). We have the import tariffs of each HS 6-digit level product for each country at the annual level. The Chinese export data is from Chinese Customs at the quarterly level. We have the number of exporters and the export value/quantity of each HS6 product. The sample period is from 2000/01 to 2006/12. The data summary is shown in Table 1 and Figure 1. The first part of Table 1 shows that the exporter and destination numbers increased over time. From 2000 to 2006, exporter numbers increased by 174.5% and destination numbers increased by 43%. Product numbers are almost constant. The second part of Table 1 shows that the tariffs, charged by partners, decreased over time. In 2000 the simple average tariffs are 9.6%, and in 2006 the tariffs are 8.1%. In addition, the simple average tariffs of OECD countries remained robust, and that of non-OECD countries decreased almost 30% from 2000 to 2006. The last part of Table 1 shows that China’s import tariffs also decreased from 2000 to 2006. Especially, when China became a WTO member in 2002, China’s average import tariffs decreased about 27% in that year. Figure 1 shows the time trend of China’s nominal effective exchange rates (NEERs) from 2000 to 2016. After China entered WTO in 2002, the NEERs decreased until 2005— depreciation. On July 21, 2005, the People’s Bank of China announced a revaluation of Chinese Yuan and a reform of the exchange rate regime. After 2005, the NEERs began to increase—appreciation—and increased until 2015. Note that here, an increase (decrease) in NEERs means China’s appreciation (depreciation) while an increase (decrease) in the independent variable N ER—defined as Chinese Yuan per a foreign currency—means Yuan depreciation (appreciation). 5 6

We also show results with monthly data in Appendix A.3. The tariff is the effectively applied tariff (AHS) which is defined as the lowest available tariff.

6

2.3

Tariffs and Exchange Rates

In this section, we present more detailed data for tariffs and nominal exchange rates, in particular, the time trends of tariffs and nominal exchange rates for China’s top 10 trade partners from 2000 to 2006, as shown in Figures 2 - 3. The top 10 partners are the euro area, the United States, Hong Kong, Japan, South Korea, the United Kingdom, Singapore, Taiwan, Canada, and India. Here, the tariff data is at the annual level, and the exchange rate data is at the monthly level. The figures imply that both tariffs and nominal exchange rates might be important factors contributing to changes in the EM of China’s exports. They also imply that the increase in EM due to tariff reductions might be weakened by currency appreciation or strengthened by currency depreciation. In the case of the euro area, for example, tariffs, charged by the euro area, decreased and Yuan depreciated from 2002 to 2004, implying that currency depreciation might have strengthened the increase in EM due to tariff reductions. In the case of Japan, tariffs, charged by Japan, decreased and Yuan first appreciated and next depreciated during the period 2001 to 2005, implying that currency appreciation and depreciation, respectively, might have weakened and strengthened the increase in EM due to tariff reductions.

3 3.1

Regression Results Exporter Numbers and Export Value/Quantity per Exporter

The column 1 of Table 2 shows the extensive margin effects of tariffs and nominal exchange rates. According to the Melitz model, a reduction in tariffs that are charged by foreign countries would encourage more Chinese firms entering foreign markets while the appreciation (depreciation) of Chinese Yuan would discourage (encourage). Our results verify this hypothesis. If the tariffs decrease by one percent, exporter numbers would increase by 0.04 percent. If Chinese Yuan appreciates by one percent, exporter numbers would decrease by 0.07 percent. From 2000 to 2005, the tariffs decreased and Chinese Yuan depreciated, and thus both two effects could stimulate the EM of exports. But after 2005, Chinese Yuan began to appreciate, which could weaken the effect of tariffs reductions. Especially, the impact of nominal exchange rates is larger than that of tariffs.

7

In addition, the column 1 of Table 2 also shows that the reductions in tariffs, charged by foreign countries, stimulate the intensive margin of exports from China and the appreciation (depreciation) of Chinese Yuan would weaken (strengthen) this effect. If the tariffs decrease by one percent, the export value per exporter would increase by 0.06 percent. Although the impact of tariff reduction is significant, the size is small. On the other hand, the impact of exchange rate fluctuations on exports is larger. If Chinese Yuan appreciates by one percent, the export value per exporter would decrease by 0.10 percent. The effects are similar for export quantity per exporter. If the tariffs decrease by one percent, export quantity per exporter would increase by 0.07 percent. If Chinese Yuan appreciates by one percent, export quantity per exporter would decrease by 0.09 percent. In the column 2, we additionally control the import tariffs charged by China. The effects of tariff reductions and exchange rate fluctuations remain robust. We also find that the import tariff reductions stimulate exports from China, at both the intensive and extensive margins. The reductions of import tariffs could decrease the input costs of Chinese firms, which improves their competitiveness in foreign markets. In sum, from 2000 to 2005, the reductions of tariffs charged by partners, the Chinese Yuan depreciation, and China’s import tariff reductions could all stimulate the exports of China, at both the intensive and extensive margins. But after 2005, the Chinese Yuan appreciation could weaken the benefits from trade liberalization.

3.2

Entry and Exit of Exporters

In this section, we investigate exporter dynamics in more details. Exporter numbers depend on both entry and exit of exporters. The tariffs and exchange rates might have heterogeneous effects on exporters’ entry and exit decisions. Thus, we separately examine the impacts. The column 1 of Table 3 shows that the reductions in tariffs, charged by foreign countries, would not affect the entry or exit of exporters. The Chinese Yuan appreciation (depreciation), on the other hand, would prevent (encourage) new firms entering foreign markets but has no effect on the exit of exporters. If Chinese Yuan appreciates by one percent, new exporter numbers would decrease by 0.32 percent. In the column 2, we additionally control China’s import tariffs, and the above pattern remains robust.

8

3.3

Robustness Checks

In this section, we examine whether trade modes, export destinations and real exchange rates would affect the benchmark results. Trade Modes: Processing trade refers to the activity of importing all or part of the raw and auxiliary materials from abroad, and re-exporting the finished products after processing or assembly by firms within the mainland. Thus, processing trade firms are more likely to be affected by the tariff and nominal exchange rate fluctuations. We thus divide firms into two groups: ordinary and processing trade firms. The columns 3 and 4 of Table 2 show that the effects on exporter numbers and export value/quantity per exporter of tariffs and nominal exchange rates are indeed larger for processing trade firms. However, the columns 3 and 4 of Table 3 show that effects on entry and exit are not clear. As can be seen, the effect of nominal exchange rates on new exporter numbers is more significant for ordinary trade while the effect on exit exporter numbers is more significant for processing trade. Export Destinations: After China became a WTO member in 2002, the tariffs charged by foreign countries, especially by developing countries, decreased a lot. For example, it can be seen by comparing India with developed countries (see Figures 2 and 3). Thus, we divide the export destinations into two groups: OECD and non-OECD countries. The columns 5 and 6 in Tables 2 and 3 show that the effects are more significant for non-OECD countries. Real Exchange Rates: Nominal and real exchange rates show very different movements in the United States over 2000-2006 (see Figure A1 in Appendix A.2). Motivated by this observation, we perform robustness checks with real exchange rates. Tables 4 and 5 show the results with real exchange rates. As can be seen, the results remain robust.

4

Conclusion

We have empirically tested the implications from the Melitz model with nominal exchange rates. Specifically, using Chinese firm-product data from 2000 to 2006 with 170 trade partners, we have tested whether or not the effect of trade liberalization on the EM of China’s exports is weakened (strengthened) by Chinese Yuan appreciation (depreciation). Based on regressions, we have four main empirical findings. First, reductions in tariffs, charged by China’s trade partners, increased China’s exporter numbers and export value/quantity 9

per exporter at the product level while the appreciation (depreciation) of Chinese Yuan decreased (increased) them—the latter effect is larger than the former one in all cases. Second, reductions in tariffs, charged by trade partners, do not affect the entry or exit of China’s exporters while Chinese Yuan appreciation/depreciation does affect entry but does not affect exit. Third, processing trade firms are more affected by tariffs and exchange rates than ordinary trade firms are. Fourth, the effects are more significant if export destinations are non-OECD countries. The results presented in this paper are important particularly for empirical studies on trade liberalization and the EM of trade. Because the results indicate that the observed increases in EM after trade liberalization could be the results weakened by currency appreciation or strengthened by currency depreciation, past studies might have under- or overestimated the pure effect of trade liberalization on the EM. Thus future studies will need to more carefully control exchange rates when investigating the changes in EM using firm data. Finally, our empirical results pose a challenge to theorists developing models that can explain why the effect of exchange rates on Chinese exporters is larger than that of tariffs. We leave it to future research.

10

References Baggs, Jen, Eugene Beaulieu, and Loretta Fung (2009) ‘Firm survival, performance, and the exchange rate.’ Canadian Journal of Economics 42(2), 393–421 Bergin, Paul R., and Ching-Yi Lin (2008) ‘Exchange rate regimes and the extensive margin of trade.’ NBER Working Paper 14126 Feenstra, Robert C. (1989) ‘Symmetric pass-through of tariffs and exchange rates under imperfect competition: An empirical test.’ Journal of International Economics 27(1-2), 25– 45 Fitzgerald, Doireann, and Stefanie Hallerz (2017) ‘Exporters and shocks.’ Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff Report 549 Kehoe, Timothy, and Kim Ruhl (2013) ‘How important is the new goods margin in international trade?’ Journal of Political Economy 121(2), 358–392 Melitz, Marc J. (2003) ‘The impact of trade on aggregate industry productivity and intraindustry reallocation.’ Econometrica 71(6), 1695–1725

11

Table 1: Data Summary Year Variables

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

Exporter Numbers

59,709

65,505

74,882

90,705

114,768

138,881

163,923

Product Numbers

4,789

4,809

4,778

4,816

4,853

4,879

4,894

104

134

141

124

125

135

149

(mean)

9.60

9.54

9.97

8.86

7.89

8.11

8.10

Exporter, Product and Destination

Destination Numbers Tariffs Charged by Partners —All Countries (sd)

16.14

14.87

35.45

15.37

18.86

11.90

12.35

—OECD Countries (mean)

4.91

5.01

5.12

4.98

3.93

4.63

4.75

(sd)

15.58

15.52

14.29

15.56

13.36

12.37

13.34

(mean)

14.86

13.74

14.45

12.43

11.30

10.72

10.42

(sd)

15.12

12.90

46.76

14.28

21.99

10.83

11.04

(mean)

19.16

18.19

13.20

12.01

11.45

9.56

10.02

(sd)

16.52

17.11

9.34

8.16

9.15

5.54

7.29

—Non-OECD Countries

China’s Import Tariffs

12

Table 2: Nominal Exchange Rates, Tariffs and Exports (Quarterly) Full Sample ln(Tariff) ln(NER) Processing Trade

Ordinary Trade Processing Trade ln(Exporter Numbers) -0.0346*** -0.0445** (0.0127) (0.0197) 0.101*** 0.117***

OECD

Non-OECD

-0.00783 (0.0241) 0.0100

-0.0322** (0.0145) 0.0958*** (0.0325) -0.794*** (0.0407) -0.0305*** (0.00960)

-0.0385*** (0.0132) 0.0721***

-0.0384*** (0.0132) 0.0730***

(0.0220) -0.812*** (0.0271)

(0.0219) -0.812*** (0.0271) -0.0475*** (0.00707)

(0.0279)

(0.0201)

-0.0655*** (0.00754)

-0.0987*** (0.0148)

(0.0791) -0.878*** (0.0378) -0.0760*** (0.00853)

1,082,827 0.552

2,100,039 0.595

2,016,485 0.446

ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

4,116,652 0.507

4,116,652 0.507

3,033,655 0.559

ln(Tariff)

-0.0590*** (0.0194) 0.0999** (0.0438)

-0.0588*** (0.0195) 0.101** (0.0437)

ln(Export Value per Exporter) -0.0445** -0.0868*** (0.0186) (0.0302) 0.117** 0.256*** (0.0476) (0.0492)

-0.0232 (0.0357) -0.0404 (0.112)

-0.0349 (0.0241) 0.188*** (0.0582)

-0.372*** (0.0514)

-0.372*** (0.0514) -0.0810*** (0.0138)

-0.113*** (0.0146)

-0.168*** (0.0295)

-0.417*** (0.0714) -0.134*** (0.0158)

-0.445*** (0.0672) -0.0506** (0.0239)

3,033,654 0.408

1,082,827 0.428

2,100,038 0.415

2,016,485 0.342

-0.0412 (0.0409) -0.0304 (0.133)

-0.0345 (0.0234) 0.155** (0.0602) -0.616*** (0.0704) -0.0198 (0.0253)

ln(NER) Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

4,116,651 0.363

4,116,651 0.363

ln(Tariff)

-0.0720*** (0.0219) 0.0867* (0.0440)

-0.0719*** (0.0219) 0.0874** (0.0439)

-0.507*** (0.0479)

-0.507*** (0.0479) -0.0388** (0.0157)

-0.0837*** (0.0161)

-0.151*** (0.0332)

-0.525*** (0.0575) -0.0996*** (0.0179)

4,111,494 0.581

4,111,494 0.581

3,030,170 0.626

1,081,154 0.584

2,096,878 0.596

2,014,488 0.604

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

ln(NER) Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared Product FE Country FE Time FE Cluster by Country

ln(Export Quantity per Exporter) -0.0514** -0.110*** (0.0205) (0.0323) 0.115** 0.252*** (0.0483) (0.0554)

Notes: (1) Since the tariffs charged by Hong Kong are zero, we exclude Hong Kong from the sample. (2) *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

13

Table 3: Nominal Exchange Rates, Tariffs and Exporter Dynamics (Quarterly) Full Sample ln(Tariff)d ln(NER)d Processing Trade

ln(Tariff)d ln(NER)d Processing Trade

Product FE Country FE Time FE Cluster by Country

Non-OECD

-0.0141** (0.00687) 0.00255

-0.0106* (0.00628) 0.384*** (0.123) -0.0541*** (0.00672) -0.00795 (0.00788)

-0.00462 (0.00452) 0.322***

(0.106) -0.0716*** (0.00383)

(0.106) -0.0715*** (0.00384) -0.0199*** (0.00698)

(0.112)

(0.0938)

-0.0236*** (0.00797)

-0.00735 (0.0145)

(0.0980) -0.0794*** (0.00385) -0.0300*** (0.00979)

993,407 0.040

993,407 0.040

713,503 0.048

279,676 0.041

506,763 0.048

486,461 0.042

-0.00736 (0.00893) -0.0456 (0.0748)

-0.00752 (0.00895) -0.0456 (0.0748)

Numbers)d -0.0107** (0.00519) -0.164*** (0.0599)

0.000731 (0.00592) -0.0689 (0.165)

-0.0167 (0.0262) -0.0187 (0.0924)

-0.0940*** (0.00930)

-0.0940*** (0.00930) 0.0120 (0.00871)

0.0218** (0.0105)

-0.0189 (0.0115)

-0.0645*** (0.00480) 0.00983 (0.00991)

-0.127*** (0.0200) 0.0145 (0.0145)

939,768 0.087

939,768 0.087

675,358 0.101

264,165 0.052

481,770 0.050

457,789 0.107

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

ln(China’s Import Tariff)d Observations R-squared

OECD

-0.00488 (0.00453) 0.321***

ln(China’s Import Tariff)d Observations R-squared

Ordinary Trade Processing Trade ln(New Exporter Numbers)d -0.00359 -0.00778 (0.00511) (0.00516) 0.334*** 0.276***

ln(Exit Exporter -0.00646 (0.0112) -0.00570 (0.0843)

Notes: (1) Since the tariffs charged by Hong Kong are zero, we exclude Hong Kong from the sample. (2) *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

14

Table 4: Real Exchange Rates, Tariffs and Exports (Quarterly) Full Sample

Ordinary Trade Processing Trade ln(Exporter Numbers) -0.0345*** -0.0451** (0.0132) (0.0201)

OECD

Non-OECD

-0.00765 (0.0250)

-0.0333** (0.0151) 0.126** (0.0591) -0.798*** (0.0420) -0.0292***

ln(Tariff)

-0.0390*** (0.0136)

-0.0389*** (0.0137)

ln(RER)

0.139*** (0.0444) -0.812*** (0.0278)

0.139*** (0.0443) -0.812*** (0.0278) -0.0474***

0.140*** (0.0523)

0.179*** (0.0348)

-0.0654***

-0.0971***

0.184* (0.101) -0.873*** (0.0387) -0.0763***

(0.00729)

(0.00785)

(0.0150)

(0.00803)

(0.0100)

1,049,190 0.554

2,047,058 0.598

1,902,943 0.446

-0.0184 (0.0372)

-0.0353 (0.0251) 0.236** (0.0957) -0.437*** (0.0696) -0.0464* (0.0249)

Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

3,950,129 0.508

3,950,129 0.508

2,900,765 0.560

ln(Tariff)

-0.0574*** (0.0202)

-0.0572*** (0.0202)

ln(Export Value per Exporter) -0.0425** -0.0847*** (0.0193) (0.0311)

ln(RER)

0.200*** (0.0707) -0.358*** (0.0514)

0.200*** (0.0707) -0.358*** (0.0514) -0.0804*** (0.0142)

0.190** (0.0823)

0.345*** (0.0710)

-0.112*** (0.0151)

-0.163*** (0.0297)

0.228 (0.138) -0.401*** (0.0699) -0.136*** (0.0153)

2,900,764 0.408

1,049,190 0.428

2,047,057 0.417

1,902,943 0.340

-0.0364 (0.0428) 0.251

-0.0372 (0.0242) 0.207** (0.0925) -0.611*** (0.0732) -0.0202 (0.0262)

Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

3,950,128 0.363

3,950,128 0.363

ln(Tariff)

-0.0715*** (0.0227) 0.193**

-0.0714*** (0.0227) 0.193**

(0.0749) -0.493*** (0.0480)

(0.0748) -0.493*** (0.0480) -0.0404** (0.0161)

(0.0850)

(0.0804)

-0.0856*** (0.0165)

-0.146*** (0.0336)

(0.177) -0.508*** (0.0556) -0.102*** (0.0174)

3,945,113 0.580

3,945,113 0.580

2,897,382 0.626

1,047,557 0.585

2,043,952 0.597

1,901,033 0.605

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

ln(RER) Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared Product FE Country FE Time FE Cluster by Country

ln(Export Quantity per Exporter) -0.0506** -0.108*** (0.0214) (0.0333) 0.183** 0.351***

Notes: (1) Since the tariffs charged by Hong Kong are zero, we exclude Hong Kong from the sample. (2) *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

15

Table 5: Real Exchange Rates, Tariffs and Exporter Dynamics (Quarterly) Full Sample ln(Tariff)d ln(RER)d Processing Trade

ln(Tariff)d ln(RER)d Processing Trade

Product FE Country FE Time FE Cluster by Country

Non-OECD

-0.0108 (0.00741) 0.0446

-0.0120* (0.00615) 0.466*** (0.148) -0.0562*** (0.00683) -0.00892 (0.00825)

-0.00311 (0.00432) 0.373***

(0.123) -0.0729*** (0.00385)

(0.123) -0.0729*** (0.00385) -0.0204*** (0.00717)

(0.128)

(0.114)

-0.0248*** (0.00817)

-0.00599 (0.0150)

(0.0584) -0.0798*** (0.00389) -0.0300*** (0.0101)

954,007 0.041

954,007 0.041

683,307 0.048

270,472 0.041

493,880 0.048

459,945 0.042

-0.00726 (0.00936) -0.148 (0.0953)

-0.00746 (0.00938) -0.148 (0.0953)

Numbers)d -0.0112** (0.00545) -0.241*** (0.0644)

-0.000400 (0.00635) -0.215 (0.144)

-0.0211 (0.0263) -0.102 (0.118)

-0.0943*** (0.00944)

-0.0943*** (0.00944) 0.0142 (0.00884)

0.0237** (0.0107)

-0.0165 (0.0117)

-0.0655*** (0.00482) 0.0107 (0.0101)

-0.127*** (0.0207) 0.0192 (0.0145)

902,532 0.087

902,532 0.087

646,872 0.103

255,414 0.052

469,421 0.050

432,903 0.110

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

ln(China’s Import Tariff)d Observations R-squared

OECD

-0.00338 (0.00433) 0.373***

ln(China’s Import Tariff)d Observations R-squared

Ordinary Trade Processing Trade ln(New Exporter Numbers)d -0.00196 -0.00680 (0.00486) (0.00535) 0.393*** 0.302***

ln(Exit Exporter -0.00612 (0.0117) -0.112 (0.112)

Notes: (1) Since the tariffs charged by Hong Kong are zero, we exclude Hong Kong from the sample. (2) *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

16

Figure 1: Nominal Effective Exchange Rates China's NEER 130

125

120

115

NEER

110

105

100

95

90

85

80 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

Note: An increase (decrease) in nominal effective exchange rates means China’s appreciation (depreciation).

17

Figure 2: Tariffs and Nominal Exchange Rates Tariffs by Euro Area and NER Yuan/Euro 2000

2001

2003 Tariffs

2002

NER 2004

Tariffs by USA and NER Yuan/USD

2005

2006

2000

4

12

2001

2003 Tariffs

2002

NER 2004

2005

2006

4.3

8.4

4.1

8.3

3.9

8.2

3.7

8.1

3.5

8

3.3

7.9

3.1

7.8

11 3.5

10

NER

NER

9

Tariffs

Tariffs

3

2.5 8

2 7

1.5

6 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2.9

7.7

2006

2000

2001

Tariffs by HKG and NER Yuan/HKD Tariffs 2000

2001

2002

2003

2002

2000

NER

2001

2002

2003

5.5

2004

2003

2004

2005

2006

Tariffs by JPN and NER Yuan/Yen

2005

Tariffs

2004 NER

2005

2006 0.085

2006

1

1.08

0.9

1.07

0.08 5

0.8

1.06 0.075

0.7 1.05 4.5

Tariffs

NER

Tariffs

1.04 0.5 1.03

0.07

NER

0.6

4

0.4 0.065

1.02 0.3 1.01

0.2

3.5 0.06

1

0.1

0

0.99 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

3

0.055

2006

2000

2001

Tariffs by KOR and NER Yuan/Won Tariffs 2000

2001

2002

2003

2003

2004

2005

2006

Tariffs by GBR and NER Yuan/Pound 2000

NER 2004

2002

2005

2001

2002

2003 Tariffs

4

2006

35

2004 NER

2005

2006 17

0.009

16 0.0085 30

3.5

15

0.008 25 3

14

NER

20

Tariffs

NER

Tariffs

0.0075

13

0.007 2.5 15 0.0065

12

2

10 0.006

5

11

0.0055 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

1.5

2006

10 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

Note: A decrease (increase) in nominal exchange rates means Yuan appreciation (depreciation).

18

2006

Figure 3: Tariffs and Nominal Exchange Rates (Continued) Tariffs by SGP and NER Yuan/SGD 2000

2001

2002

2003 Tariffs

0.03

2004 NER

Tariffs by TWN and NER Yuan/TWD 2005

2006

2000 5.2

2001

2002

2003

4

Tariffs

2004 NER

2005

2006 0.28

5.1 0.025

0.27 3.5 5

0.02

4.9

0.26 3

0.015

0.25

NER

Tariffs

NER

Tariffs

4.8

4.7 2.5 0.01

4.6

0.24

4.5 2 0.005

0.23 4.4

0

4.3 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

1.5

0.22

2006

2000

2001

Tariffs by CAN and NER Yuan/CAD 2000

2001

2002

2003 Tariffs

6.5

2004 NER

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

Tariffs by IND and NER Yuan/INR

2005

2006

2000 7.5

2001

2002

2003

30

Tariffs

2004 NER

2005

2006 0.195

6 7

0.19 25

5.5 6.5

0.185 20

0.18

4.5 15 5.5

0.175

4

10 5

0.17

3.5

3

4.5 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

5

2006

0.165 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

Note: A decrease (increase) in nominal exchange rates means Yuan appreciation (depreciation).

19

NER

Tariffs

6

NER

Tariffs

5

A

Appendix

A.1

Theoretical Motivation

In this appendix, we simply derive implications on the EM from key equations in the Melitz (2003) model. See equations (20) and (19) defining the zero cutoff profit (ZCP) condition in Melitz (2003). These are equations about the relationship between τ , φ∗ , and φ∗x , where τ = 1 + trade costs (tariffs on the home’s exports), φ∗ is the domestic productivity cutoff, and φ∗x is the export productivity cutoff. Then, as shown in Section 8.2 in Melitz (2003), a reduction in τ shifts up the ZCP curve and increases the domestic cutoff φ∗ , which decreases the export cutoff φ∗x and thus increases the EM. Here, let us introduce a nominal exchange rate denoted by e (the price of the foreign currency in the home currency). In the original Melitz model, the export price px = τ ∗ pd = τ /(ρ ∗ φ). In the model with e, on the other hand, px = (τ /e) ∗ pd = (τ /e)/(ρ ∗ φ). So, in the model with e, τ is replaced by (τ /e). Then, under the fixed regime, the argument with (20) and (19) remains unchanged. Under the flexible regime, however, a decrease in τ can be weakened by a decrease in e (domestic appreciation), weakening the effect on the export cutoff φ∗x . Or, a decrease in τ can be strengthened by an increase in e (domestic depreciation), strengthening the effect on the export cutoff φ∗x . Hence, a decrease in τ itself increases the EM, but it can be weakened by a decrease in e (appreciation) or strengthened by an increase in e (depreciation).

A.2

Nominal and Real Exchange Rates

Figures A1 - A2 show the relationship between nominal and real exchange rates for China’s top 10 trade partners from 2000/01 to 2006/12. Note that due to data constraints, to calculate real exchange rates for the euro area we use producer prices for the euro area’s CPI.

A.3

Monthly Results

Tables A1 and A2 show the results of regressions (2.1) and (2.2) at the monthly level.

20

Table A1: Nominal Exchange Rates, Tariffs and Exports (Monthly) Full Sample ln(Tariff) ln(NER) Processing Trade

Ordinary Trade Processing Trade ln(Exporter Numbers) -0.0274** -0.0332 (0.0122) (0.0217) 0.119*** 0.103***

OECD

Non-OECD

-0.00131 (0.0237) 0.00453

-0.0221* (0.0125) 0.0929*** (0.0283) -0.540*** (0.0337) -0.0272*** (0.00998)

-0.0299** (0.0132) 0.0833***

-0.0298** (0.0132) 0.0839***

(0.0214) -0.568*** (0.0228)

(0.0214) -0.568*** (0.0228) -0.0358*** (0.00687)

(0.0289)

(0.0187)

-0.0521*** (0.00693)

-0.105*** (0.0154)

(0.0670) -0.627*** (0.0321) -0.0563*** (0.00838)

2,287,144 0.521

4,716,024 0.544

3,912,478 0.387

ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

8,628,627 0.465

8,628,627 0.465

6,341,341 0.510

ln(Tariff)

-0.0529** (0.0204) 0.119*** (0.0425)

-0.0528** (0.0205) 0.120*** (0.0424)

ln(Export Value per Exporter) -0.0393** -0.0764** (0.0186) (0.0339) 0.149*** 0.239*** (0.0495) (0.0443)

-0.0171 (0.0362) -0.0593 (0.102)

-0.0190 (0.0243) 0.195*** (0.0551)

-0.0483 (0.0559)

-0.0482 (0.0559) -0.0654*** (0.0144)

-0.101*** (0.0141)

-0.182*** (0.0302)

-0.103 (0.0747) -0.109*** (0.0149)

-0.0950 (0.0781) -0.0424 (0.0283)

6,341,340 0.374

2,287,144 0.411

4,716,023 0.382

3,912,478 0.321

-0.0348 (0.0421) -0.0569 (0.131)

-0.0191 (0.0235) 0.154*** (0.0571) -0.263*** (0.0751) -0.0154 (0.0288)

ln(NER) Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

8,628,626 0.343

8,628,626 0.343

ln(Tariff)

-0.0662*** (0.0230) 0.103** (0.0450)

-0.0661*** (0.0230) 0.104** (0.0450)

-0.168*** (0.0486)

-0.168*** (0.0486) -0.0184 (0.0159)

-0.0672*** (0.0149)

-0.175*** (0.0332)

-0.195*** (0.0570) -0.0636*** (0.0176)

8,616,071 0.551

8,616,071 0.551

6,332,627 0.593

2,283,302 0.555

4,708,097 0.559

3,907,849 0.581

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

ln(NER) Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared Product FE Country FE Time FE Cluster by Country

ln(Export Quantity per Exporter) -0.0461** -0.101*** (0.0209) (0.0363) 0.148*** 0.224*** (0.0528) (0.0534)

Notes: (1) Since the tariffs charged by Hong Kong are zero, we exclude Hong Kong from the sample. (2) *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

21

Table A2: Real Exchange Rates, Tariffs and Exports (Monthly) Full Sample ln(Tariff) ln(RER) Processing Trade

Ordinary Trade Processing Trade ln(Exporter Numbers) -0.0268** -0.0334 (0.0125) (0.0220) 0.124*** 0.141***

OECD

Non-OECD

-0.000979 (0.0245) 0.132

-0.0223* (0.0129) 0.104** (0.0475) -0.543*** (0.0346) -0.0263** (0.0104)

-0.0299** (0.0135) 0.120***

-0.0298** (0.0136) 0.120***

(0.0371) -0.568*** (0.0233)

(0.0370) -0.567*** (0.0233) -0.0360*** (0.00700)

(0.0444)

(0.0303)

-0.0517*** (0.00718)

-0.105*** (0.0153)

(0.0904) -0.625*** (0.0328) -0.0572*** (0.00776)

2,228,403 0.524

4,605,377 0.546

3,711,847 0.387

ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

8,317,348 0.466

8,317,348 0.466

6,088,802 0.511

ln(Tariff)

-0.0504** (0.0211) 0.172*** (0.0654)

-0.0502** (0.0211) 0.172*** (0.0654)

ln(Export Value per Exporter) -0.0366* -0.0734** (0.0192) (0.0347) 0.165** 0.285*** (0.0775) (0.0676)

-0.0118 (0.0374) 0.141 (0.136)

-0.0179 (0.0251) 0.210** (0.0861)

-0.0344 (0.0558)

-0.0343 (0.0558) -0.0649*** (0.0148)

-0.0993*** (0.0145)

-0.181*** (0.0300)

-0.0894 (0.0735) -0.112*** (0.0144)

-0.0834 (0.0803) -0.0386 (0.0293)

6,088,801 0.374

2,228,403 0.411

4,605,376 0.383

3,711,847 0.319

-0.0295 (0.0437) 0.159 (0.172)

-0.0202 (0.0242) 0.176** (0.0838) -0.254*** (0.0776) -0.0158 (0.0298)

ln(RER) Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared

8,317,347 0.343

8,317,347 0.343

ln(Tariff)

-0.0644*** (0.0237) 0.165** (0.0718)

-0.0644*** (0.0237) 0.165** (0.0718)

-0.155*** (0.0483)

-0.155*** (0.0483) -0.0199 (0.0162)

-0.0678*** (0.0153)

-0.173*** (0.0332)

-0.180*** (0.0552) -0.0669*** (0.0170)

8,305,104 0.550

8,305,104 0.550

6,080,329 0.593

2,224,632 0.556

4,597,585 0.560

3,707,395 0.581

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes

ln(RER) Processing Trade ln(China’s Import Tariff) Observations R-squared Product FE Country FE Time FE Cluster by Country

ln(Export Quantity per Exporter) -0.0443** -0.0986*** (0.0216) (0.0371) 0.162** 0.282*** (0.0820) (0.0828)

Notes: (1) Since the tariffs charged by Hong Kong are zero, we exclude Hong Kong from the sample. (2) *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

22

Figure A1: Nominal and Real Exchange Rates China and Euro Area: NER (Yuan/Euro) and RER 12

NER

China and USA: NER (Yuan/USD) and RER 12

RER

8.4

NER

8.6

RER

8.3 11

11

10

10

8.4

8.2 8.2

8

RER

9

NER

9

RER

NER

8.1

8

8

8

7.8

7.9

7

7

7.6 7.8

6

6 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

7.7

2006

7.4 2000

2001

China and HKG: NER (Yuan/HKD) and RER 1.08

NER

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

China and JPN: NER (Yuan/Yen) and RER 1.3

RER

0.085

NER

0.09

RER

1.07 1.25 0.08

0.085

0.075

0.08

0.07

0.075

0.065

0.07

0.06

0.065

1.06 1.2 1.05

1.03

RER

RER

NER

NER

1.15

1.04

1.1

1.02

1.05 1.01

1 1

0.99

0.95 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

0.055

2006

0.06 2000

2001

China and KOR: NER (Yuan/Won) and RER

2003

2004

2005

2006

China and GBR: NER (Yuan/Pound) and RER 0.009

17

0.0085

0.0085

16

16

0.008

0.008

15

15

0.0075

0.0075

14

14

0.007

0.007

13

13

0.0065

0.0065

12

12

0.006

0.006

11

11

0.0055

10

RER 0.0055 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

NER

17

RER

2006

RER

RER

NER

NER

NER

0.009

2002

10 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

Note: A decrease (increase) in nominal/real exchange rates means China’s appreciation (depreciation).

23

Figure A2: Nominal and Real Exchange Rates (Continued) China and SGP: NER (Yuan/SGD) and RER 5.2

NER

China and TWN: NER (Yuan/TWD) and RER 5.2

RER

5.1

0.28

NER

0.29

RER

5.1 0.27

0.28

0.26

0.27

0.25

0.26

0.24

0.25

0.23

0.24

4.9

4.8

4.8

4.7

4.7

4.6

4.6

4.5

4.5

4.4

4.4

RER

NER

4.9

4.3

4.3 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

0.22

2006

0.23 2000

2001

China and CAN: NER (Yuan/CAD) and RER 7.5

NER

RER

5

NER

5

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

China and IND: NER (Yuan/INR) and RER 7.5

RER

0.195

NER

0.195

RER

0.19 7

7

0.19

0.185

6.5

6.5

0.185

0.18

RER

NER

6

RER

NER

0.175 6

0.18 0.17

5.5

5.5

0.175

0.165

0.16 5

5

0.17 0.155

4.5

4.5 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

0.165

2006

0.15 2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

Note: A decrease (increase) in nominal/real exchange rates means China’s appreciation (depreciation).

24

Does Yuan Appreciation Weaken the Increase in ...

in tariffs, charged by China's trade partners, increased China's exporter numbers ..... be seen by comparing India with developed countries (see Figures 2 and 3).

4MB Sizes 0 Downloads 143 Views

Recommend Documents

Does Easing Monetary Policy Increase Financial Instability?
Annual Meeting of the International Banking and Finance Association. The information and ... rate implied by the Taylor rule is well above the actual federal funds rate, starting from ..... taking into account the elasticity of demand for their varie

Does Financial Innovation Increase Inequality?: A ...
Jun 1, 2017 - 1063; webpage: https://sites.google.com/site/paulhyunlee; email: ... the relative mass of “good” investment banks compared to the mass of “bad” ...

Does Real Exchange Rate Depreciation Increase ...
Analysis using Korean Firm-Level Data. *. Bo-Young Choi .... Our year-by-year analysis finds the positive effect of RER depreciation on productivity. ...... of Economics, Simon Fraser University, Canadian Institute for Advanced Research. Kancs ...

Does social/cultural learning increase human adaptability? Rogers's ...
90 (1988) 819] challenged this common view by a simple analytic model. ..... A further analysis revealed that the data were better .... An outline of Kameda and Nakanishi's (2002) simulation algorithm about ..... These bigger issues are beyond the ..

Does Easing Monetary Policy Increase Financial ...
2Johns Hopkins Carey Business School. “IFABS 2016”. 1 ... Is there a trade off between macroeconomic and financial stability in the conduct of monetary policy?

RECTENWALD - AN APPRENTICE'S APPRECIATION LEARNING ...
Access World News.pdf. RECTENWALD - AN APPRENTICE'S APPRECIATION LE ... SBERG FOR A GUIDE... - Access World News.pdf. Open. Extract.

Appreciation-another chance.pdf
Page 1 of 2. Appreciation of the poem 'Another chance'. Another Chance is a beautifully crafted motivational poem from America's. poet laureate of inspirational verse.The poet lifts up the otherwise low spirits of. her fellow beings through this shor

pdf-0939\flowers-in-the-mirror-jing-hua-yuan ...
... apps below to open or edit this item. pdf-0939\flowers-in-the-mirror-jing-hua-yuan-traditional-chinese-edition-bookdna-chinese-classics-by-li-ruzhen.pdf.

Engagement and Appreciation in a Time of Crisis - Maritz
with a safe place (such as a call center or designated. HR representative) where they can discuss ethical or compliance concerns is also a great way to not only.

Black-White Appreciation of Owner-Occupied Homes in ...
Aug 25, 2011 - crime rates and poverty rates are positively correlated, and school test ... Coate and Vanderhoff (1993) using the annual housing survey data did not find ..... Map le wo od an d. M o ntcla ir,. N .J .,. 199. 0. –. 20. 00 and. 197. 0

Increase The Shine And Look With Floor Sanding In Melbourne.pdf ...
Page 1 of 1. Increase The Shine And Look With Floor Sanding In Melbourne.pdf. Increase The Shine And Look With Floor Sanding In Melbourne.pdf. Open.

Increase The Shine And Look With Floor Sanding In Melbourne.pdf ...
Page 1 of 1. Increase The Shine And Look With Floor Sanding In Melbourne.pdf. Increase The Shine And Look With Floor Sanding In Melbourne.pdf. Open.

increase-the-longevity-with-car-service-in-mount-waverley.pdf ...
increase-the-longevity-with-car-service-in-mount-waverley.pdf. increase-the-longevity-with-car-service-in-mount-waverley.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In.

Statement of Accomplishment SHICHAO YUAN - GitHub
Dec 1, 2013 - This advanced undergraduate programming course covers the ... PROFESSOR OF COMPUTER SCIENCE. ÉCOLE POLYTECHNIQUE FÉDÉRALE DE LAUSANNE. DISCLAIMER : THIS ONLINE OFFERING DOES NOT REFLECT THE ... A ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE FÉDÉRALE DE LAU

Contextual learning induces an increase in the number ...
campus following behavioral training in a contextual fear conditioning (CFC) ..... Third, if the selected area within the CA1 cell layer exceeded 126 pixels (ca. 50 μm2, half of the ..... Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 101,.

Music: An Appreciation
Song around the world.The notebook .pdf.Music:AnAppreciation.582680261207. ... Puppy linux 2.12.San jun lee.DIVERTIDAMENTE xvid.You, methem.

RECTENWALD - AN APPRENTICE'S APPRECIATION LEARNING ...
Whoops! There was a problem loading this page. RECTENWALD - AN APPRENTICE'S APPRECIATION LE ... SBERG FOR A GUIDE... - Access World News.pdf.

Donut Hole Appreciation Tag.pdf
We appreciate our. teachers a HOLE lot! Enjoy your donut holes! Page 1 of 1. Donut Hole Appreciation Tag.pdf. Donut Hole Appreciation Tag.pdf. Open. Extract.