How Limiting Deceptive Practices Harms Consumers

Salvatore Piccolo†

Piero Tedeschi†

Giovanni Ursino∗

October 19, 2014

ONLINE APPENDIX



Department of Economics and Finance, Universit` a Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Milan.

1

Equilibrium and welfare for high quality differentials.

By imposing assumption A1 we have restricted the analysis to the range of parameters in which vl >

∆ 2.

This section provides the equilibrium analysis for the opposite case in which the differential between the sellers’ qualities is not small. Section 1.1 deals with the basic model while Section 1.2 assumes that the buyer is more sophisticated as in Section 5 of the paper.

1.1

Basic model

Take the baseline model of the paper and assume that A1 does not hold. Consider first the separating equilibrium of Proposition 1. The arguments which pin down prices ph = ∆ and pl = 0 are still valid. What needs to be checked anew is the no-mimicking condition. Start observing that, if f is larger than ∆, mimicking cannot be profitable because it implies a penalty larger than the price if the buyer purchases. Thus, in the region in which f ≥ ∆ the separating equilibrium exists even if A1 does not hold. Focus next on the area in which the sanction f is smaller than the separating price ∆. Notice that, if vl ≤

∆ 2

and the low-quality seller mimics the high-quality seller charging a price ∆, the buyer

expects quality vl + ∆ 2 ≤ ∆ and abstains from purchasing. Thus, the separating equilibrium exists in this region.1 Summing up, the separating equilibrium of Proposition 1 exists for any level of the sanction f as long as vl ≤

∆ 2.

Consider now pooling equilibria. The buyer’s off-equilibrium beliefs are still those of A3. Notice first that nothing changes on the sellers’ side: their no-deviation incentives are the same as those of the main text and do not depend on vl . Hence, sellers do not deviate as long as the participation constraint and the no-deviation constraint of the low-quality seller are satisfied — i.e., (3) and (4) are met. The substantial difference with respect to the analysis of the main text rests with the buyer participation constraint. In particular, it is no longer true that the buyer’s participation constraint (2) is satisfied at the minimum price f whenever the low-quality seller’s participation and no-deviation constraints, (3) and (4), are met. As a consequence, the sellers’ incentives might be satisfied for prices which violate the buyer’s participation constraint. This simply means that, when A1 does not hold, the buyer’s participation constraint (2) must be explicitly accounted for. While, as before, (3) and (4) are jointly 1 For simplicity, we assume the buyer does not purchase in the non generic case vl = ∆ — e.g., because there is a minimal 2 cost of shopping. Assuming that he buys would not change the main welfare and policy implications of the paper.

2

satisfied only if f ≤ ∆, (2) and (3) are jointly satisfied only if f ≤ vl + ∆ 2 . The latter is a new constraint imposed on the model’s parameters for the existence of a pooling equilibrium and is clearly stricter than the former. It reflects the fact that, because A1 does not hold, the buyer’s participation constraint is tighter. Summing up, it is immediate to verify that the following result holds: Proposition I. If assumption A1 does not hold: (i) assuming A2 the separating equilibrium of Proposition 1 exists for any f ; (ii) assuming A3 the most competitive pooling equilibrium with price f exists if and only if f ≤ vl +

∆ 2.

Beyond the appearance of the participation constraint in the existence condition of the pooling equilibrium, the main addition of Proposition I to the analysis of Section 2.1 regards the separating outcome. If A1 is relaxed the separating equilibrium of Proposition 1 extends its range of application. Indeed, when the quality differential is sufficiently large — i.e., vl ≤

∆ 2

— this equilibrium exists for any

enforcement level. The intuition is simple. In this region of parameters, if the low-quality seller mimics the high-quality one and both advertise, the quality expected by the buyer under A2 (vl +

∆ 2)

is lower

than the price of the high-quality good at the separating equilibrium (∆). Hence, the buyer does not purchase off-equilibrium and the low-quality seller has no incentives to deviate. A comment on welfare is due. When multiple equilibria exist, we bear with the selection criterion that sellers most likely coordinate on the one which maximizes their ex-ante profit — i.e., before learning their type. When vl ≤

∆ 2,

the pooling and the separating equilibria coexist for f ≤ vl + ∆ 2 while only the

separating exists for larger levels of the sanction. It is then immediate to verify that a seller’s expected profits are, respectively,

f 2

in the pooling equilibrium and

∆ 2

in the separating one. Hence, the latter

dominates the former and sellers coordinate on the separating equilibrium for any value of f . In this scenario, the conflict of interest between the buyer and the sellers is the most severe: while the buyer would like sellers to coordinate on the most competitive pooling equilibrium with zero enforcement, sellers are never willing to do so. Clearly, because sellers coordinate on the separating outcome no matter f , the Authority cannot affect the buyer-surplus, which is stuck at vl . Indeed, the Authority could benefit the buyer only by inducing sellers to coordinate on a pooling equilibrium and then setting the fine at the minimum level f = 0 — replicating, in fact, the result of Proposition 3. To do so the Authority should 3

implement a price-cap p sufficiently low to induce a low-quality seller to deviate from her separating price of zero and mimic the high-quality seller, thereby destroying the separating equilibrium. It is easy to see that p will be optimally set at vl + ∆ 2 — i.e., the buyer’s maximum willingness to pay off-equilibrium implied by assumption A3. Then, the policy of the buyer-oriented Authority requires banning any price p ≥ p and setting a fine f = 0.

1.2

Sophisticated buyer

We now assume that the buyer is more sophisticated and realizes that a high-quality seller can credibly signal her type by pricing below f and advertising. Note first that the analysis of the separating equilibrium of Section 1.1 holds unchanged when the buyer is more sophisticated. Hence, point (ii) of Proposition I applies here as well. This is relevant for the welfare analysis at the end of the subsection. Second, consider pooling equilibria. The analysis is almost identical to that developed in the main text of the paper. The buyer’s off-equilibrium beliefs are still those of A4. The incentives to be satisfied are, again, the buyer’s participation constraint (2), the no-self-revealing condition of the high-quality seller (5) and the no-deviation constraint of the low-quality seller (4).2 Again, (4) and (5) are jointly  satisfied only if f ≤ 23 ∆, while (2) and (5) are jointly met only if f ≤ 12 vl + ∆ 2 . Notice that, because A1 does not hold and vl ≤

∆ 2,

the latter condition is stricter than the former. This is the only difference

with respect to Proposition 7, in which there is no straight implication between the necessary conditions just mentioned. Hence, a necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of a pooling equilibrium with sophisticated buyer and minimum price p∗ = 2f is: 1 f ≤ fˆ ≡ 2



∆ vl + 2

 .

Finally, consider the separating equilibrium of Proposition 8. Notice first that, assuming A5 and considering an equilibrium in which sellers price at f and separate on the advertising strategy, the incentives to deviate of either seller are unaffected by the relationship between vl and ∆. In particular, 2

The participation constraint of the low-quality seller (3) is implied by (5) and the no-deviation constraint of the high-quality seller (6) is implied by (4).

4

this is so because, independently of vl , the low-quality seller earns zero profits by mimicking the rival. As to the buyer, he is clearly willing to purchase the high-quality good at price f < ∆ in equilibrium, which is the (unchanged) existence condition of this separating outcome. Hence, the separating equilibrium of Proposition 8 is unaffected by dropping A1. We summarize the analysis of Section 1.2 up to this point in the following result. Proposition II. If assumption A1 does not hold, then: (i) assuming A4 the most competitive pooling equilibrium with price p∗ = 2f exists if and only if f ≤ fˆ; (ii) assuming A5 the separating equilibrium of Proposition 8 exists under the same condition f ≤ ∆. Hence, the only change vis-` a -vis the analysis of Section 5 is the simplified existence condition of the pooling equilibrium. The welfare analysis closely parallels that of Section 5. The only difference is that now the separating equilibrium with price ph = ∆ exists for any f . The consequence of this is that the separating equilibrium with price ph = f is never played by the sellers, who obviously prefer playing the separating equilibrium with the higher price. Hence, whenever they coexist — i.e., if f < fˆ — the relevant comparison is between the pooling outcome and the separating with price ∆. In the former a seller expects profits equal to 43 f while she expects profits equal to

∆ 2

in the latter. Notice that

∆ 2

≥ 34 f if and only if f ≤ 32 ∆,

which is always true whenever the pooling equilibrium of Proposition II exists and A1 does not hold. Hence, sellers always coordinate on the separating when they have a choice. Therefore, the same logic of Section 1.1 applies here and a price cap p capable of disrupting the separating equilibrium with price ∆ should be implemented. As a consequence, sellers are left with a choice between the separating at price f and the pooling equilibrium at price 2f . Hence, the analysis developed for the case v> ∆ 2 applies. Summarizing, the optimal policy of a buyer-concerned Authority when the buyer is sophisticated is to set f = 0 and, if vl <

∆ 2

a price cap p = vl +

∆ 2.

5

How Limiting Deceptive Practices Harms Consumers

Oct 19, 2014 - 1 Equilibrium and welfare for high quality differentials. ... the high-quality one and both advertise, the quality expected by the buyer under A2 (vl ...

206KB Sizes 2 Downloads 142 Views

Recommend Documents

Uncovering Harms: States, corporations and ... - WordPress.com
Call for papers: The European Group for the Study of Deviance and Social Control 45th. Annual Conference. Uncovering Harms: States, corporations and.

Deceptive Brain and Mind_Final Programme.pdf
... is advised (please send an e-mail to [email protected]). Whoops! There was a problem loading this page. Deceptive Brain and Mind_Final Programme.pdf.

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers - Giovanni Ursino
Sep 19, 2016 - quality of a credence good, while this may be verifiable by a third party with some probability. ... 3See the USDA Agricultural Marketing Service Report. ... Pennzoil Company and Pennzoil Products Company, 987 F.2d 939 (3rd Cir. .... F

ORGANIC PRACTITIONER Consumers
LaTOP Organic Stall # 32, Public Market, La Trinidad, Benguet,. Baguio City vegetable ... Kalinga State College (KSC); Ifugao State University (IFSU and other.

Trickle: Rate Limiting YouTube Video Streaming - Usenix
uses two phases: a startup phase and a throttling phase. The startup phase .... demo of. Trickle is available at http://www.cs.toronto.edu/~monia/tcptrickle.html. 2 ...

Selling to Overconfident Consumers - CiteSeerX
Nov 7, 2006 - Graduate School of Business .... by customers on a plan with a large number of included minutes strictly first ..... cell phone customer is small. ..... 800. 1000. 1200 quantity. 20. 40. 60. 80. 100. $. FC = $25; c = $0.035; D= 0.25.

Surplus Update Report - Consumers Union
component of rate review, MLR is an imperfect tool for keeping rate ..... closed health system that includes the health plan, providers, and infrastructure, making.

Context-Sensitive Consumers
Oct 13, 2017 - present evidence of up-selling in the online retail market for computer parts. .... evidence on down-selling, which mainly associates retailers of ... 8Christina Binkley makes a convincing case for this marketing ...... of rational con

Selling to Overconfident Consumers - CiteSeerX
Nov 7, 2006 - 2 According to a pricing manager at a top US cellular phone service .... Their motivating example relates to airline ticket pricing, so assumes ...... two-part tariffs to be included in corporate rate packages, but not be offered to the

Deceptive Answer Prediction with User Preference Graph
Aug 9, 2013 - David M. Blei, Andrew Y. Ng, and Michael I. Jordan. 2003. ... Fangtao Li, Minlie Huang, Yi Yang, and Xiaoyan Zhu. 2011. Learning to identify ...

Volatility harms growth OEPFinalCopy
run growth should be negatively related to the amplitude of the business cycle.4 ..... trade, and its disadvantages of being relatively more landlocked. 6. .... Ramey, G. and Ramey, V.A. (1991) Technology commitment and the cost of economic.

Uncovering Harms: States, corporations and ... - WordPress.com
Call for papers: The European Group for the Study of Deviance and Social Control 45th. Annual Conference. Uncovering Harms: States, corporations and.

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers - Giovanni Ursino
Sep 19, 2016 - brand in an ad was illegal in many countries. ... Inc., case # 1:08-cv-00236, in the U.S. District Court for the Northern District of Ohio.

Deceptive Answer Prediction with User Preference Graph
Aug 9, 2013 - ence graph is incorporated into traditional super- ..... deceptive answers with traditional classification method. Two types of features, including ...

Activity 7 Limiting Reactants.pdf
Sign in. Page. 1. /. 6. Loading… Page 1 of 6. Page 1 of 6. Page 2 of 6. Page 2 of 6. Page 3 of 6. Page 3 of 6. Activity 7 Limiting Reactants.pdf. Activity 7 Limiting ...

Uncovering Harms: States, corporations and organizations as criminals
public meetings and media engagement to highlight the harms of the prisons and to discover where the other new prisons are likely to be situated. Local groups have risen up across the UK wherever plans for new mega prisons have been mooted. We would