JULY 2013 • Number 122

Inclusive Growth Revisited: Measurement and Determinants Rahul Anand, Saurabh Mishra, and Shanaka J. Peiris

The call for inclusive growth has been unanimously broadcasted by policy makers across the world. The Arab Spring, the growing divide between Main Street and Wall Street in advanced economies, and the “three-speed” world economy have placed inclusive growth at the forefront of policy debates. However, efforts to measure and assess the determinants of inclusive growth have remained limited. What is inclusive growth? How can the micro and macro dimensions of inequality and growth be integrated to reflect both the pace and distribution of economic growth? What has driven inclusive growth in emerging markets? What Is Inclusive Growth? Inclusive growth refers to both the pace and distribution of economic growth. For growth to be sustainable and effective in reducing poverty, it needs to be inclusive (Berg and Ostry 2011a; Kraay 2004). The Commission on Growth and Development (2008) notes that inclusiveness—a concept that encompasses equity, equality of opportunity, and protection in market and employment transitions—is an essential ingredient of any successful growth strategy. However, attempts to measure inclusive growth have remained limited. Traditionally, poverty (or inequality) and economic growth analyses have been conducted separately. Recent work indicates that there may not be a trade-off between equity and efficiency, as suggested by Okun (1975), and “that it would be a big mistake to separate analyses of growth and income distribution” (Berg and Ostry 2011b). This paper attempts to integrate the two strands of analyses by developing a unified measure of inclusive growth. Ianchovichina and Gable (2012) describe inclusive growth as raising the pace of growth and enlarging the size of the economy by providing a level playing field for investment and increasing productive employment opportunities.

This note presents a measure of inclusive growth that is in line with the absolute definition of pro-poor growth, but not the relative definition. Under the absolute definition, growth is considered to be pro-poor as long as poor people benefit in absolute terms, as reflected in some agreed measures of poverty (Ravallion and Chen 2003). In contrast, under the relative definition, growth is pro-poor if and only if the incomes of poor people grow faster than those of the population as a whole; that is, inequality declines (Dollar and Kraay 2002; IMF 2011). By focusing on inequality, the relative definition could lead to suboptimal outcomes for both poor and nonpoor households. For example, a society attempting to achieve pro-poor growth under the relative definition would favor an outcome characterized by average income growth of 2 percent, where the income of poor households grew by 3 percent over an outcome where average growth was 6 percent, but the incomes of poor households grew by only 4 percent. The dynamic measure of inclusive growth proposed here allows an analysis of income distribution that can distinguish between countries where per capita income growth was the same for

1 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK    www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

the top and the bottom of the pyramid by accounting for the pace of growth. A recent flurry of media and political attention toward rising inequality across the globe has generated a tremendous amount of interest on its causes and consequences. While the rise in inequality in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and some emerging markets is well documented, there is debate on the causes and even more controversy on the consequences and what should be done about it. A number of recent papers have associated the rising inequality with technological change, financial deepening, and certain aspects of globalization (Acemoglu and Autor 2011; Aizeman, Lee, and Park 2012; IMF 2007). Foreign trade can exacerbate inequality by rewarding industries and firms that are able to compete in the global marketplace, while punishing those that cannot. Technological progress has also been widely put forth as a structural driver of inequality. Skilled workers are better able to adopt and use new and improved technology than other unskilled workers, thereby increasing the skill premium and widening the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers. The divide between Main Street and Wall Street epitomizes the recent thinking on the role of financial deepening in fueling inequity. Welfare considerations of high inequality extend beyond the effect on growth and macroeconomic stability, but they remain relevant to understanding whether macroeconomic fundamentals and structural change (broadly defined) affect inclusive growth. For example, current debate on austerity and growth, or recent calls to slow the pace of financial deepening and globalization, may reduce income inequality, but could slow inclusive growth as well. It is vital to assess the dynamics and determinants of inclusive growth, keeping in mind that the goal of reducing inequality is not to hurt the rich at the expense of the poor.1 A unified measure of inclusive growth allows researchers and policy makers to identify growth determinants and prioritize country-specific constraints to build inclusive growth. To do this, the next section develops a measure of inclusive growth using a macro social mobility function following the micro literature on income distribution. This note also documents the evolution of inclusive growth, focusing on emerging markets and low-income countries. Lastly, this note examines the sources of inclusive growth in emerging markets and low-income countries. Measuring Inclusive Growth To integrate equity and growth in a unified measure, this note proposes a measure of inclusive growth based on a utilitarian social welfare function drawn from consumer choice literature, where inclusive growth depends on two factors: (i) in-

come growth and (ii) income distribution. Similar to the consumer theory where the indifference curves represent the changes over time in aggregate demand, this analysis decomposes the income and substitution effect into growth and distributional components. The underlying social welfare function must satisfy two properties to capture these features: (i) it is increasing in its argument (to capture growth dimension) and (ii) it satisfies the transfer property—any transfer of income from a poor person to a richer person reduces the value of the function (to capture distributional dimension). The macro measure of inclusiveness is based on the micro concept of a generalized concentration curve following Ali and Son (2007). The population is arranged in the ascending order of their income, called the social mobility curve. Let yi be the average income of the bottom i percent of the population, where i varies from 0 to 100 and y is the mean income. yi is plotted for different values of i (curve AB in figure 1). Since a higher curve implies greater social mobility, growth is inclusive if the social mobility curve moves upward at all points. However, there may be degrees of inclusive growth depending on: (i) how much the curve moves up (growth) and (ii) how the distribution of income changes (equity), that is, how the curvature of the social mobility curve changes. This feature of the social mobility curve is the basis of the proposed integrated measure of inclusive growth. Thus, if two generalized concentration curves do not intersect, they could be ranked on social mobility, that is, inclusive growth. To illustrate the point made above, figure 1 depicts two social mobility curves with the same average income (y), but different degrees of inclusiveness, that is, different income distribution. Social mobility curve A1B is more inclusive than the social mobility curve AB, because the average income of the bottom segment of the society is higher. If both terms are positive (d y > 0, dω < 0), growth is unambiguously inclusive (AB shifting to A1B1 in figure 2); similarly, if both terms are negative (d y < 0, dω < 0), growth is unambiguously noninclusive (AB shifting to A4B4). However, there could be a trade-off between y and ω. If the first term is positive but the second term is negative, higher social mobility is achieved at the expense of reduction in equity. In figure 1, this case can be illustrated by the shift of the social mobility curves from AB to A2B2. Similarly, if the first term is negative but the second term is positive, then higher social mobility is achieved at the cost of contraction in average income—in figure 1, this case can be illustrated by the shift of the social mobility curve from AB to A3B3. To capture the magnitude of the change in income distribution, this analysis uses a simple form of the social mobility function by calculating an index (or social mobility index) from the area under the social mobility curve:

2 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK    www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

income per capita (y)

Figure 1. Shifts in Social Mobility Curve dy > 0, dω > 0: AB dy > 0, dω < 0: AB dy < 0, dω > 0: AB dy < 0, dω < 0: AB

Table 1. Inclusiveness Matrix dy>0 dω>0 Unambiguously inclusive

A1B1 A2B2 A3B3 A4B4

B2

dy>0

dω<0

Higher per capita income at the expense of equity (could be inclusive if the percentage change in y > the percent change in ω

dy<0

dω>0

Equity objective is achieved at the cost of average income contraction

dy<0

dω<0

Unambiguously noninclusive

B1 B B4

A1

B3 A2 A A3

Source: Authors’ calculations.

A4 cumulative share of population, 0 ≤ i ≤ 1

i = 100 (when the entire population is covered)

Source: Authors' illustration.

Figure 2. Distribution of Emerging Markets on Inclusiveness Matrix average gdppc_ppp 12

420 5,000 10,000 14,621

AZE

11

region

AFR APD EUR MCD WHD

10 ARM 9

MNE

CHN 8

growth in GDP per capita

TJK 7 LVA BIH

MOZ BLR RWA

BWA

IND

LKA

4

BGD BGR

HRV

GUY KAZ PAN

IDN

3 2

EST

VNM

6 5

BTN

GEO

BFA ETH NPL MLI JOR N AM BRA SWZ KGZ CMR ECU MRT GMB JAM YEM SEN GTM GIN MEX FJI NER PRY VEN KEN BLZ CIV ZMB MDG CAF

MKD

ARG

TZA

BOL

1 0 -1

THA

UZB

MWI

UKR TLS

DZA

-2

GNB

BDI

-3 2.5

2.0

1.5

1.0

0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

equity growth (omega)

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

Source: Authors’ calculations. Note: The chart measures proportionate average annual change. The period used is the early 1990s to the latest available data. Size represents the initial size of the economy (GDP per capita), that is, the legend represents countries with purchasing power parity (PPP) GDP per capita below 420; 5,000; 10,000; and 14,621, respectively. Different regional codes are denoted by different colors.

3 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK    www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

ture the magnitude of the change in income distribution, this analysis uses a simple f the social mobility function by calculating an index (or social mobility index) from a under the social mobility curve:

in others. A decomposition of inclusiveness following table 1 shows that there is a wide dispersion of possible outcomes. �� � � ��� �� � These dispersions are depicted in figure 2, where most countries fall into the two quadrants that show higher per capita The greater the y,* the greater the measure of inclusive income and a lower/or higher level of inequity, suggesting that the greater measure of inclusive growth. If theisincome of everyone in eater the��� ∗ ,growth. If thethe income of everyone in the population the there ∗ is no simple trade-off between growth and equality. In pulation is same incomedistribution distributionis is completely equitable), then �� will be same(that (that is, is, ifif income completely equitable), most cases, economic growth shifted the indifference curves o �� . If �� ∗ isthen lower than � �, it implies that the distribution of income is inequitable. So, y* will be equal to y. If y* is lower than y, it implies that upward, and there have been very few intersections of social viation of �� ∗the from �� is an indication of inequality in income distribution, which is distribution of income is inequitable. So, the deviation of mobility curves, suggesting unambiguous gains in inclusivented by�� (unlike Gini, a higher value of omega represents higher income equality). y* from y is an indication of inequality in income distribuness. However, the relative magnitude of shift and curvature ly, � is defined as follows: tion, which is represented by ω (unlike Gini, a higher value of of indifference 4 curves both matter. 4 inclusive growth is primarily a growth story. Rapomega represents higher income equality). Formally, ω is deChina’s 4 fined as follows: id growth in per capita income has benefitted everyone, but ∗ � � the gains have been much greater for the rich (as depicted by �∗ � � . � �� � � . ∗ negative value on equity [omega] and steepening of the social �� �� � � �. mobility curve). Thus, in China, high growth has eclipsed the � For asociety, completely equitable � � ��inequality Thus, higher valuea large of omega For a completely equitable ω = 1. Thus, highersociety, growing to produce upward(closer shift of to theone) soFor a completely equitable society, � � �� Thus, higher value of omega (closer to one) value of omega (closer to one) represents higher income equalrepresents income equality. Rearranging, cialomega mobility(closer curve and higher inclusive growth. A similar For a completely equitable society, � higher �income �� Thus, higher value of to one) represents higher equality. Rearranging, ity. Rearranging, story holds for India, where high growth has benefitted everyrepresents higher income equality. Rearranging, ∗ one, but equity has gone down. On other hand, the increase in � � � � ∗ � �. �� ∗ � � ∗ ��. inclusiveness in Brazil, Mexico, Malaysia, and Thailand has �� ∗ � � ∗ ��. ∗ come growth as well improvement in equity (positive which could be as achieved by: (i) increasing ��, that is, Inclusive growth requires increasing � � ,from which but could be achieved by:fast (i)enough increasing ��, that is, growth requires increasing � � ∗ , omega), Inclusive growthInclusive requires increasing y,* which could be growth has not been to benefit the ∗ increasing�average income through growth; (ii)increasing increasing��,equity through �; or (iii) a , which could be achieved by: (i) that is, Inclusive growth requires increasing � increasing income through (ii)population increasing equity or (iii) a achieved by: (i) increasing y, thataverage is, increasing average in- growth; entire as much as inthrough �; China. combination of (i) and (ii). Differentiating the above equation: increasing averagegrowth; income growth; (ii) equitythe through �; or (iii) a as a whole, the heterogeneity in come through (ii)through increasing equity ω; or combination of (i) andthrough (ii).increasing Differentiating above equation: Across emerging markets combination of (i) andof(ii). Differentiating the above equation: economic growth performance and income distribution out(iii) a combination (i) and (ii). Differentiating the ∗ above �� � � � ∗ ��� � �� ∗ � � ∗ equation: provide insight to the growth-equity trade-off. Conven ��� � � ∗ ��� � �� ∗ comes �� ��� ∗ � � ∗ ��� � �� ∗ �� tional wisdom suggests that iigrowth comes at the price of riswhere � ∗ is the change in the degree of inclusivebutgrowth. Growth more inclusive if ii ∗ �� inequality, differ in is their growth-equity of ing inclusive growth.regions Growth is more inclusive if where �� � is the change in the degree ∗ ii � degree � �. of inclusive ∗ �� trade-off. In some instances, strong growth has been achieved where ��� ∗ is the change in the growth. Growth is more inclusive if ��� � �. without compromising equity. ��� ∗ �where �. d y is the change in the degree of inclusive growth.2 Growth is more inclusive if d y* > 0. Sources of Inclusive Growth ∗

���

Tracking the Evolution of Inclusive Growth

While there is broad agreement on the basic policies important Ifor growth and reducing poverty, little is known about Tachieved RACKING THE EVOLUTION OF NCLUSIVE GROWTH Relatively few countries have strong growth. OF INCLUSIVE TRACKING THE inclusive EVOLUTION Ginclusive ROWTH what may foster growth. Rapid growth is unquesPrevious studies have focused on the (or lack TRACKING THE E VOLUTION OFconvergence INCLUSIVE GROWTH tionably necessary for substantial poverty reduction (see Relatively few countries have achieved strong inclusive growth. Previous studies have thereof) of the distribution of income across the world (see Relatively few countries have achieved strong inclusive growth. Previous studies have Kraay [2004] and Lopez and Servén [2004]), but for inclufocused on the convergence (or lack thereof) of the distribution of income across the Relatively countries have achieved strong growth. Previous studies haveof income across the worldworld Dollar few and Kraay [2003] and Sala-i-Martin [2006])inclusive or the focused on the convergence (orrislack thereof) of thetodistribution sive growth be sustainable the long run,of it inequality should be (see (see Dollar andnote Kraay and Sala-i-Martin [2006]) thein rising level focused on the convergence (or[2007]). lack ofsheds the[2006] distribution of income across theorrising world ing level of inequality (see Dollar IMF This light (see andthereof) Kraay [2006] and Sala-i-Martin [2006]) or the level (see of inequality (see broad-based across sectors and equitable Berg and Ostry IMF This note shedsorlight on bothlevel of those aspects by mapping out the change in on bothand of those aspects by[2007]). mapping out change in inclu(see Dollar Kraay [2006] and[2007]). Sala-i-Martin [2006]) rising of inequality (see IMF Thisthenote sheds light onthe both of those aspects by mapping out the change in [2011a]). This is even more important because some of the inclusiveness or social mobility across countries over the lastinfew decades. While crosssiveness orThis socialnote mobility across countries over the last fewacross IMF [2007]). sheds light on of those aspects bycountries mapping out the theoflast change inclusiveness or both social mobility over few(for decades. While crosskey generally determinants growth example,of education, country comparisons of inequality are plagued by problems poor dataopenreliability, decades. While cross-country comparisons of inequality are inclusiveness or social mobility across countries over the last few decades. While crosscountry comparisons of inequality are generally by problems ofinpoor data reliability, ness, and plagued financial depth) established the literature (Barro lackofof coverage, andplagued inconsistent methodology, this analysis relies on income distribution generally plagued byof problems poor reliability, lack of by problems country comparisons inequality aredata generally poor data reliability, lack of coverage, and inconsistent methodology, this analysis relies income distribution and Lee of 2000; Dollar and Kraayon 2003; Levine 2005) have data from the latest World Bank Povcal database constructed by Chen and Ravallion (2004) coverage, and inconsistent methodology, this analysis relies on lack of coverage, and inconsistent methodology, this analysis relies on income distribution been associated with higher inequality (Barro 2000; IMF data fromthe thelatest latest World Bank Povcal database constructed by Chen and Ravallion (2004) income data from World Bank Povcal for a large number of emerging markets using more the rigorous approach to filtering data from thedistribution latest World Bank Povcal database constructed by Chen andabegging Ravallion (2004) 2007), thus question, what proximate factors for a large number of emerging markets using a more rigorous approach to filtering database constructed by Ravallion and Chen (2003) a large individual income and consumption data for differences in quality than other commonly used for a large number of emerging markets using afor more rigorous approach to filtering inclusive growth? income and consumption datasupport for differences in quality than other commonly used number of emergingindividual markets using a more rigorous approach databases. individual income anddatabases. consumption data for differences in quality Panel than other commonly used measure of inclusive regressions of the unique to filtering individual income and consumption data for difgrowth on a broad sample of emerging markets provide indatabases. ferences in quality than other commonly databases. The limitedused gains in inclusiveness are explained by relatively low growth in some sights intoby therelatively proximate determinants of inclusive The limited gains in inclusiveness are explained low growth in some growth. The limited gains in inclusiveness are explained by relacountries and widening in others. A in decomposition oforinclusiveness The measure of inclusive ∂y,* is explainedfollowing by a set The limited gains inininclusiveness explained byinequality relatively low growth some growth, countries andare widening in others. A decomposition of inclusiveness following tively low growth some countries and wideninginequality inequality table 1 shows that there is a wide dispersion of possible outcomes. These dispersions of standard control variables used in cross-country growthare countries and widening inequality in others. A decomposition of inclusiveness following

table 1 shows that there is a wide dispersion of possible outcomes. These dispersions are in figureof2,possible where most countries fall dispersions into the twoare quadrants that show higher per table 1 shows that there is adepicted wide outcomes. depicted in dispersion figure 2, where most countries fallThese into the two quadrants that show higher per capita income and a lower/or higher level of inequity, suggesting that there is no simple 4 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENTfall (PREM) NETWORK     www.worldbank.org/economicpremise depicted in figure 2, where most countries into the two quadrants that show higher per capita income and a lower/or higher level of inequity, suggesting that there is no simple trade-off between growth and equality.that In most economic growth shifted the capita income and a lower/or levelgrowth of inequity, suggesting therecases, iseconomic no simple trade-offhigher between and equality. In most cases, growth shifted the indifference curves upward, and there have been very few intersections of social mobility trade-off between growth and equality. In most cases, economic growth shifted the indifference curves upward, and there have been very few intersections of social mobility suggesting unambiguous gains in inclusiveness. However, the relative magnitude of indifference curves upward,curves, and there have been very few intersections of social mobility

Table 2. Panel Regression: Emerging Markets Dependent variable: growth in inclusive growth 1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Lag GDP per capita (logs)

-0.211** (0.0904)

-0.203* (0.107)

-0.300*** (0.101)

-0.468*** (0.139)

-0.605*** (0.184)

-0.528** (0.198)

-0.558*** (0.145)

Education

0.397** (0.149)

0.309* (0.180)

0.120 (0.205)

0.261* (0.151)

0.783*** (0.280)

0.173 (0.220)

0.560** (0.235)

Trade openness

0.246** (0.1000)

0.194* (0.114)

-0.0442 (0.120)

0.418*** (0.133)

0.223 (0.240)

0.0130 (0.0970)

-0.00118 (0.0943)

Credit to GDP

-0.160 (0.144)

-0.164 (0.174)

-0.0390 (0.171)

-0.0176 (0.186)

-0.0822 (0.0946)

0.112 (0.146)

-0.137 (0.184)

Government consumption

-0.718 (0.866)

-0.340 (0.956)

-0.394 (0.731)

0.367 (0.616)

-2.849*** (0.571)

-0.00748 (1.003)

-1.250 (0.905)

Investment

0.949** (0.438)

1.030 (0.646)

0.945 (0.582)

0.786 (0.650)

-0.141 (1.102)

0.439 (0.781)

1.018** (0.485)

Inflation

-0.0275* (0.0143)

-0.0280* (0.0143)

-0.0227* (0.0129)

-0.0830*** (0.0110)

-0.0524*** (0.00326)

-0.00349 (0.00270)

-0.00129 (0.00313)

GDP volatility

-2.126** (1.065)

-2.175** (1.076)

-0.991 (0.875)

0.223 (1.781)

-1.604 (2.065)

-0.788 (1.066)

-1.235 (1.042)

0.000547** (0.000274)

Financial openness

0.0101*** (0.00248)

FDI

-0.718 (0.432)

ICT

-0.00245*** (0.000779)

REER deviations

0.131*** (0.0385)

Infrastructure quality Service export sophistication (logs)

0.500*** (0.165)

Goods export sophistication (logs)

0.390* (0.216)

Constant

Observations R-squared Number of countries

5.123** (2.167)

4.899** (2.587)

7.453*** (2.443)

12.06*** (3.579)

15.43*** (4.370)

12.46** (4.902)

5.816** (2.573)

261

234

234

111

98

139

146

0.263

0.284

0.376

0.285

0.514

0.150

0.288

99

89

89

36

63

49

58

Source: Authors' compilation. Notes: Both country and time effects are included. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent level, respectively. Robust t-statistics are in parentheses. Openness is trade openness; investments are fixed investments (percent of GDP), followed by government consumption (percent of GDP). Financial deepening is private sector credit to domestic sector (percent of GDP); education is Barro-Lee years of schooling above age 15; ICT is the total stock of ICT software- and hardware-related investments as a share of total capital stock; FDI is total FDI (liabilities) capital stock; infrastructure quality is the database developed by World Bank; inflation is consumer price index annual percentage change. Export sophistication uses United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Comtrade data for manufactured goods and balance of payments, IMF for service exports.

and inequality literature in a non-over-lapping, unbalanced five-year panel of 143 countries from 1970–2010. Consistent with results in Barro and Lee (2000) and Dollar and Kraay (2003), table 2 shows that lower initial incomes (conditional convergence), trade openness, fixed investment,

moderate inflation and output volatility, and a better-educated workforce have helped countries achieve more inclusive growth. Foreign direct investment (FDI) has a significantly positive impact on inclusive growth, as in IMF (2007), while information and communication technologies (ICTs) in the

5 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK    www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

total capital stock do not have a discernible impact; the latter could also reflect the lack of data on ICT investment in many emerging markets and low-income countries. Financial openness more generally also shows a positive association with inclusive growth. Interestingly, financial deepening, measured by the credit-to–gross domestic product (GDP) ratio, has a negative impact, as in IMF (2007), but is not statistically significant. This could be because inclusive growth encompasses both the pace and distribution of growth, while previous findings, such as Levine (2005), positively linked financial development to growth, while IMF (2007) associated it with greater inequity. Structural transformation and moving up the value chain in both goods and services have also attracted lot of attention in terms of driving economic growth (Anand, Mishra, and Spatafora 2012; Hausmann, Hwang, and Rodrik 2007). In addition to modernizing manufacturing, the globalization of services is increasingly a driver of economic growth in emerging markets (Mishra, Lundstrom, and Anand 2011). The results in this note illustrate that countries that upgraded either manufacturing or service sophistication had higher inclusive growth. Sophistication in service exports, driven by forces of globalization in computing and information networks, seems to have a greater impact on inclusive growth. The deviation of the Real Effective Exchange Rate (REER) from its purchasing power parity (PPP)–implied level is negatively associated with inclusive growth, suggesting a role for competitiveness. Infrastructure quality, as measured by Calderon and Servén (2004) and Seneviratne and Sun (2013), also plays a positive role in fostering inclusive growth, possibly by reducing the cost of doing business and creating employment.3 The importance of competitiveness through indicators such as the deviation of the REER from its PPPimplied level and infrastructure quality should be interpreted with caution given the limited observations. What Should Policy Makers Take Away and Do? This note quantifies and integrates two strands of literature to define inclusive growth. This approach is in line with the absolute definition of pro-poor growth and goes beyond just focusing on distribution issues. The integrated measure developed in this paper is useful to delve deeper into the patterns of and study the sources of inclusive growth. The methodology here directly links the micro and macro dimensions of inequality and growth to reflect both the pace and distribution of income growth. Macroeconomic stability, human capital, and structural changes are key determinants of inclusive growth in emerging markets. The standard economic growth drivers in the literature, such as conditional convergence, education levels, and

fixed investment are important, while the role of technological change emphasized in the literature has a less discernible impact. The weak data on technology and research and development spending in emerging markets may explain the indiscernible impact; however, these transitions in production capabilities are mirrored through product and service sophistication measures that foster inclusive growth. Moving up the value chain in both goods and services exports helps foster inclusive growth, so the focus should not only be on export promotion, but the quality of exports, including services. This could be even more important in the future, as technological changes are increasingly making service activities more productive, digitally tradable, and integrated across global supply chains. In terms of structural change and globalization, trade openness and FDI foster inclusive growth, with a potentially positive role played by financial openness, which warrants further analysis. However, financial deepening could have a negative impact, as in IMF (2007), possibly related to its association with financial crises, although the impact is not statistically significant. Macroeconomic stability is reinforced as a key ingredient for inclusive growth. Drivers of connectivity, business creation, and job growth measured as quality of infrastructure and competitiveness (REER deviations from PPP) are also important for inclusive growth. Looking forward, there are a number of unresolved issues and areas for future research. Many countries responded to the global financial crisis through large fiscal stimuli and/or bank bailouts, which are being withdrawn or met with austerity. The relationship between fiscal consolidation and inclusive growth is an area worthy of study. The availability of more granular data will be important to analyze the evolution of inclusive growth at the national and subnational levels by providing a local lens to view inclusive growth. Secondly, regarding job creation, it will be important to understand the links between unemployment and labor market institutions that foster inclusive growth; for example, the design of collective bargaining programs and rights for workers might play crucial roles in reaching inclusive growth goals in both advanced and emerging markets. Lastly, the speed of technological advancement, its reach and access, and the channels through which it can foster or hinder inclusive growth, are additional areas for future research. Policy makers at national and regional agencies, as well as global strategies such as program design for post-2015 Millennium Development Goals, must target and track the evolution of inclusive growth. Latest developments in technology, open data, and open government initiatives may offer greater government transparency, economic capabilities, and civic participation. The aspirant for inclusion must keep growth as a primer, since inclusive growth is about both the pace and distribution of growth.

6 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK    www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

About the Authors Rahul Anand is Senior Economist working on India at the International Monetary Fund’s (IMF) Asia Pacific Department (APD). Saurabh Mishra is with the Research Department of the IMF working on jobs and growth, and previously also worked at the World Bank on economic policy, public expenditures, and open governments. Shanaka J. Peiris is the IMF’s Resident Representative to the Philippines and previously also worked in APD and Monetary and Capital Markets Department of the IMF, covering the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and South Asia, respectively. Notes 1. Inclusive growth can also conceptually go beyond traditional lines of poverty change and should also reflect changes in the size and distribution of the middle class (Birdsall 2010). 2. Inclusive growth is defined as the change in the social mobility index d y,* which is used here interchangeably. 3. The lack of consistent historical (un)employment data in emerging markets precluded the estimation of a link between employment and inclusive growth, as stressed by Ianchovichina and Gable (2012). References Acemoglu, Daron, and David Autor. 2011. “Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Earnings.” NBER Working Paper No. 16082, Cambridge, Massachusetts. ADB (Asian Development Bank). 2002. “Growth and Poverty: Lessons from the East Asian Miracle Revisited.” ADB Institute Research Paper No. 33, Manila. Aizenman, Joshua, Minsoo Lee, and Donghyun Park. 2012. “The Relationship between Structural Change and Inequality: A Conceptual Overview with Special Reference to Developing Asia.” ADBI Working Paper No. 2012. Ali, Ifzal, and H. Hwa Son. 2007. “Measuring Inclusive Growth.”Asian Development Review 24 (1): 11–31. Anand, Rahul, Saurabh Mishra, and Shanaka J. Peiris. 2013. “Inclusive Growth: Measurement and Determinants.” IMF Working Paper No. 135, Washington, DC. Anand, Rahul, Saurabh Mishra, and Nikola Spatafora. 2012. “Structural Transformation and the Sophistication of Production.” IMF Working Paper No. 59, Washington, DC. ———. 2013. “Inclusive Growth: Measurement and Determinants” IMF Working Paper No. 135, Washington, DC. Barro, Robert J. 1996. “Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study.” NBER Working Paper No. 5698. ———. 2000. “Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries.” Journal of Economic Growth 5 (1): 5–32. Barro, Robert J., and Jong-Wha Lee. 2000. “International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications.” Center for

International Development Working Paper No. 042, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Berg, Andrew, and Jonathan D. Ostry. 2011a. “Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of the Same Coin?” IMF Staff Discussion Note 11/08, Washington, DC. ———. 2011b. “Equality and Efficiency.” Finance & Development 48 (3). Birdsall, Nancy. 2010. “The (Indispensable) Middle Class in Developing Countries; or, The Rich and the Rest, Not the Poor and the Rest.” Center for Global Development Working Paper 207. Calderon, C., and L. Servén. 2004. “The Effects of Infrastructure Development on Growth and Income Distribution.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3400, Washington, DC. Commission on Growth and Development. 2008. Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Dollar, D., and A. Kraay. 2002. “Growth Is Good for the Poor.” Journal of Economic Growth 7 (3): 195−225. ———. 2003. “Institutions, Trade, and Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (1): 3–39. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2007. “Globalization and Inequality.” In World Economic Outlook, chapter 4. Washington, DC. ———. 2011. “Regional Economic Outlook: Asia and Pacific.” October, Washington, DC. Hausmann, Ricardo, Jason Hwang, and Dani Rodrik. 2007. “What You Export Matters.” Journal of Economic Growth 12 (1): 1–25. Ianchovichina, Elena, and S. Lundstrom Gable. 2012. “What Is Inclusive Growth?” In Commodity Prices and Inclusive Growth in Low-Income Countries, ed. by Rabah Arezki, Catherine Pattillo, Marc Quintyn, and Min Zhu. International Monetary Fund. Kakwani, N. 1980. Income Inequality and Poverty: Methods of Estimation and Policy Applications. New York: Oxford University Press. Kanbur, Ravi, and Michael Spence (eds.). 2010. Equity in a Globalizing World. World Bank. Kraay, A. 2004. “When Is Growth Pro-Poor? Cross-Country Evidence.” IMF Working Paper No. 04/47, Washington, DC. Levine, Ross. 2005. “Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence” (chapter 12). In Handbook of Economic Growth, First Edition, ed. Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf, 865–934. North Holland. Lopez, H., and L. Servén. 2004. “The Mechanics of Growth-Poverty-Inequality Relationship.” Mimeo, World Bank, Washington, DC. Mishra, Saurabh, Susanna Lundstrom, and Rahul Anand. 2011. “Service Export Sophistication and Economic Growth.” World Bank Policy Working Paper No. 5606, Washington, DC. Okun, Arthur. 1975. Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. Ravallion, M., and S. Chen. 2003. “Measuring Pro-Poor Growth.” Economics Letters 78: 93−99. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 2006. “The World Distribution of Income: Falling Poverty and Convergence Period.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics CXXI (2). Seneviratne, D., and Yan Sun. 2013. “Infrastructure and Income Distribution in ASEAN-5: What Are the Links?” IMF Working Paper No. 41, Washington, DC.

The Economic Premise note series is intended to summarize good practices and key policy findings on topics related to economic policy. They are produced by the Poverty Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) Network Vice-Presidency of the World Bank. The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank. The notes are available at: www.worldbank.org/economicpremise.

7 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK    www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

Inclusive Growth Revisited: Measurement and ... - World Bank Group

terized by average income growth of 2 percent, where the ..... where d y is the change in the degree of inclusive growth.2 ... five-year panel of 143 countries from 1970–2010. ... information and communication technologies (ICTs) in the. Table 2 ...

1MB Sizes 4 Downloads 222 Views

Recommend Documents

Economic Premise - World Bank Group
Trade costs measure the trade-depressing effect of separation between countries. .... exogenous. Source: Authors' illustration. Figure 1. ... 50. 100. 150. 200. 250. 300 high income upper-middle income lower-middle income low income. 1996.

Economic Premise - World Bank Group
1 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/ ... will be able to build a public sector that can deliver services, and thus hope ..... allocated within influential public-private elite networks.

Japan Indonesia Presidential Scholarships ... - World Bank Group
Mar 26, 2010 - Impairment, Students with Intellectual. Disability, Physical Impairment) .... Standard Tests. Test. Date. Score. TOEFL. GRE. GMAT. IELTs.

Demystifying the Chinese Economy - World Bank Group
Interest among academics in China's transition and development experience has ... technology and industry, and to reduce the transaction costs and share risks ...

Japan Indonesia Presidential Scholarships ... - World Bank Group
technology, Business and commercialization ... must have completed and been awarded a master's degree, or equivalent, at the time of application however ... Excellence of their choice using the contact information provided in Attachment B.

Agricultural Innovation Systems - ISBN ... - World Bank Group
finding and its widespread application. Potential .... biotechnology tools; intellectual property and patents. □ ... tion in rural areas; monitoring system. Source: ...

Agricultural Innovation Systems - ISBN ... - World Bank Group
to information and technology, logistics, and trade agree- ments, to mention just ... competitive advantages of its agricultural sector, and drew the implications for ...

Africa's Silk Road - World Bank Group
Sep 24, 2006 - Africa's Silk Road. China and India's New Economic Frontier. Harry G. Broadman with Gozde Isik, Sonia Plaza, Xiao Ye and Yutaka Yoshino ... Emerging Market Focus (Pty) Ltd. (South Africa), Economic and Social Research ...... http://www

Cover Sheet - Independent Evaluation Group - World Bank Group
Dec 16, 2013 - Source: PovcalNet: the online tool for poverty measurement ... threshold, though China accounts for more than three-quarters of this reduction. ..... international forums on poverty (where the Bank is a leader) will also be ...

Jobless growth to inclusive growth
representing the exogenous factors, became most important source of growth, defying the .... would recruit historians and they would be just as good at software ..... as literacy campaigns with lifelong learning opportunities and open schools.

Jobless growth to inclusive growth
3 Human capital is measured by modern firms like Infosys (see Infosys Annual Report, 2005-06, p 143). 4 One such ..... Planning Commission, New Delhi, India.

Emerging Dairy Genetics Products, Markets, and ... - World Bank Group
NEW TECHNOLOGY DRIVING. MAJOR ... ✓Technology improving, but still challenges. ✓Not all bulls can be ... efficiency. • AI business is undergoing significant.

Emerging Dairy Genetics Products, Markets, and ... - World Bank Group
VP, Dairy Genetics & Global Alliance Development. Cooperative Resources ... ✓Technology improving, but still challenges. ✓Not all bulls can be sorted.

Early Life Nutrition and Subsequent Education ... - World Bank Group
Jul 24, 2008 - explore and discuss economic issues it thought relevant for growth and ... saving resources over the life cycle and into the next generation and may have benefits ..... energy drink, Atole, as a dietary supplement. ..... alternative to

Competition, Information, and Development Jean ... - World Bank Group
Apr 20, 1998 - competition is introduced in the business district while the former monopoly still must .... Consider a procurement auction where firms differ in.

Competition, Information, and Development Jean ... - World Bank Group
Apr 20, 1998 - informational asymmetries, complete markets, no natural monopolies or, more generally, convexity of ... countries. To study the problem of competition in developing countries, one approach is to examine .... including a timely and effi

Driving Growth With Measurement in a Mobile World Services
It's producing actionable recommendations and helping align leaders with well-framed business ... effective when it is flexible and actionable, with a focus on business outcomes. Driving growth ..... approaching problems in a way that is nimble and e

Briefing: Measurement and Growth Services
or any information storage and retrieval system, without prior permission in writing .... Companies excited about building long-term relationships with high-value consumers organize internal teams with this in ... research, market data, best practice

Making Roads Safer - Independent Evaluation Group - World Bank ...
crash prevention measures (measures to limit travel speeds, to alert drivers to road ...... the project invested in road safety monitoring systems and tools.

Making Trade Policy More Transparent: A New ... - World Bank Group
50. 60. 70. 80. June 2009–. May 2010. June 2010–. May 2011. June 2011–. May 2012. June 2012– ... thus have no observable effect on trade (for example, lower- ing the quantities traded ... Source: Authors' illustration. Note: Color coded by ..

Regional trade agreements in sub-Saharan Africa - World Bank Group
Mar 1, 2011 - World Bank Group or its Executive Directors. ... around regulations, their impact on trade and .... compliance by members with the provisions.

Successful business models for delivery of dairy ... - World Bank Group
services. - Provide AI service at farmers' door-step. - Maintain LN system. - Use best semen & follow SOP. - Identify inseminated animal & record all events.