1

Income and Well-being across European Provinces

2

Adam Okulicz-Kozaryn

3

Draft: September 2, 2012

4

Abstract

5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

13

The majority of studies investigate the effect of income on life satisfaction at either individual or country level. This study contributes with analysis at the (sub-national) province level across West European countries. I use a unique dataset Eurobarometer 44.2 Bis that is representative of province populations in a multilevel model. Provinces are defined according to The Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics at second level (NUTS II). Living conditions measured by regional income increase life satisfaction beyond personal income and national income. There is larger life satisfaction inequality between the rich and the poor in poor provinces than in rich provinces. Personal income matters more for life satisfaction in poor provinces than in rich provinces.

keywords: Life Satisfaction, Income, European Provinces, Livability Theory

14

Introduction

15

A key topic in the life satisfaction literature1 is the relationship between income and well-being. This

16

relationship is important for people: Will making more money make me happier? And it is important for

17

policy makers: Should taxation encourage longer working hours or more leisure?

18

How income relates to life satisfaction? A major theory that explains this relationship across countries is

19

called livability theory (Veenhoven and Ehrhardt, 1995)2 . Livability theory, as the name indicates, proposes

20

that “livable” conditions result in life satisfaction – if human needs are satisfied life satisfaction follows.

21

Livability theory predicts that the objective quality of life is associated with life satisfaction. Diener et al.

22

(1993), Veenhoven (1991), and Veenhoven and Ehrhardt (1995) find support for livability theory analyzing

23

country level data. This study innovates using province level data.

24

Diener and Biswas-Diener (2002) review literature with major finding that personal income is more

25

important for life satisfaction in poor nations and that those who prize material goals are less happy than

26

others. Objective life quality or societal environment matters for life satisfaction. Yet, perceptions of the 1 Literature uses different labels: well-being, subjective well-being, happiness or life satisfaction. Well-being is a general concept encompassing happiness and life satisfaction; subjective well-being is self-reported. Life satisfaction and happiness are conceptually different. The former refers to cognition while the latter refers to affect. This study investigates life satisfaction. 2 Veenhoven and Ehrhardt (1995) also discuss comparison theory and folklore theory. Comparison theory is a part of Multiple Discrepancy Theory (MDT) (Michalos, 1985). According to comparison theory, people compare themselves to other people, for a review see Clark et al. (2008). Under folklore theory, life satisfaction is determined by the “widely held notions about life” or “national character”. Folklore theory, however, has not been widely discussed in the literature.

1

27

objective quality of life matter irrespective of the objective circumstances and they matter more in countries

28

with poor objective quality of life; in countries with good objective quality of life private support matters

29

more (Bohnke, 2008). Life satisfaction is lowest in Eastern Europe (Delhey, 2005, Somarriba and Pena, 2009).

30

East Europeans value material goods more than West Europeans. On the other hand, West Europeans value

31

more postmaterial goods (e.g. self-actualization and freedom) than East Europeans. There is a bigger gap

32

in satisfaction between the rich and the poor in Eastern Europe (Delhey, 2005). Also, other indicators of life

33

quality are the lowest in Eastern Europe (Somarriba and Pena, 2009).

34

There are two levels of observation involved: personal and national. Income is an attribute of persons

35

(personal income) and of societies (national income). Why is level of analysis important? National income

36

is a highly aggregated measure. The higher the level of aggregation, the less precise is a measure. It is

37

the average income of the locality where a person lives that determines his quality of life, not the national

38

average. In the extant literature the implicit assumption is that national income reflects local income. Local

39

income provides context for personal income and thus can be called “contextual income”. Contextual income

40

is a property of the place where person lives, not of a country. National income measures wealth of society,

41

but wealth of society is not distributed equally within countries. Italy is one example – rich north but poor

42

south (Putnam et al., 1993). Using national income researchers commit so called ecological fallacy. Robinson

43

(1950) demonstrated that the correlations between aggregates and between attributes of the units of analysis

44

can be very different. This study uses province level income to measure wealth of society more precisely. I

45

hypothesize that a similar relationship to that at the country level is observed at province level: there is a

46

positive relationship between regional income and happiness. European provinces are defined according to

47

the Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics. There are 3 levels of aggregation: level 1 (NUTS I) is the

48

highest level of aggregation (the biggest provinces) and level 3 (NUTS III) is the lowest level of aggregation

49

(the smallest provinces).

50

There were two attempts to analyze life satisfaction at province level across European countries3 . Yet,

51

both studies use data that may not be representative at NUTS I level. Pittau et al. (2010) use Eurobarometer

52

Mannheim trend data, which is meant to be representative at the country level, not at province level (NUTS

53

I)4 , and divide 15 countries into 70 provinces (authors do not report the sample size). This study uses data

54

from 188 provinces (NUTS II). Aslam and Corrado (2007) use European Social Survey with a sample of

55

about 20,000 people across 15 countries (most provinces are NUTS I), while this study uses a sample of more 3 There are few studies analyzing life satisfaction across (sub-national) provinces, but within one country only, and these are following: Frey and Stutzer (2000) analyze institutions in Switzerland; Clark (2003) analyze comparison groups in Great Britain; and Rampichini and Schifini D’Andrea (1998) find that both personal and province level incomes increase life satisfaction in Italy. 4 Authors somewhat overcome this problem by pooling data from multiple years.

2

56

than 30,000 people in 9 countries. Aslam and Corrado (2007) find that both, national and regional incomes

57

increase life satisfaction, but the relationship is not consistent. Pittau et al. (2010) find that personal income

58

matters more in poor provinces. There are obvious advantages of using NUTS II regions over NUTS I regions.

59

They provide finer geographic representation, and hence, the data aggregation problem is smaller. Again,

60

what is true at a disaggregated level is not necessarily true at higher level (Robinson, 1950). Eurobarometers,

61

including Mannheim trend, were designed to be representative at country level.

62

Data

63

This study uses Eurobarometer 44.2 Bis Mega-Survey: “Policies and Practices in Building Europe and the

64

European Union”, collected between January and March 19965 , thereafter EB. As noted in the codebook,

65

which is quoted in the next paragraph, the

66

“Eurobarometer 44.2bis covers the population of the respective nationality of the European Union member

67

countries, aged 15 years and over, resident in each of the Member States. The basic sample size of the

68

44.2bis MEGA-survey is about 3000 respondents in Belgium, Denmark, East Germany, Greece, Ireland, the

69

Netherlands, Austria, Portugal, Finland, and Sweden; about 6000 respondents in West Germany, Spain,

70

France, Italy and Great Britain; about 600 and 1000 respondents in Northern Ireland and Luxembourg

71

respectively. Next to this basic sample an oversample of people working in the sector of agriculture, fishery

72

or forestry was carried out. A minimum number of such interviews per region was imposed. A multistage,

73

random (probability) basic sample design was applied in all Member States. In each EU country, a number

74

of sampling points was drawn with probability proportional to population size (for a total coverage of the

75

country) and to population density. For drawing the basic sample, sampling points were drawn systematically

76

from all ”administrative regional units”, after stratification by individual unit and type of area. They thus

77

represent the whole territory of the Member States according to the EUROSTAT-NUTS II and according to

78

the distribution of the national resident population of the respective EU-nationalities in terms of metropolitan,

79

urban, and rural areas. In each of the selected sampling points a starting address was drawn at random.

80

Further addresses were selected as every Nth address from the initial address by standard random route

81

procedures. In each household the respondent was drawn at random.”

82

Eurobarometer 44.2 Bis has not yet been used for the study of subjective wellbeing at province level6 .

83

EB dataset has a great advantage over other datasets. As discussed above, it is representative of NUTS II

84

provinces. For details about NUTS classification see http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/ramon/nuts. 5 Data

is available at http://www.icpsr.umich.edu/icpsrweb/ICPSR/studies/6748 and Oswald (2004) use it to study satisfaction at country level. Okulicz-Kozaryn (2010) use it to show life satisfaction variation across European provinces but does not estimate any models. 6 Blanchflower

3

Table 1: Countries in the sample. country code AT BE DE DK ES FI FR IT LU PT SE UK

country name Austria Belgium Germany Denmark Spain Finland France Italy Luxembourg Portugal Sweden United Kingdom

85

EB life satisfaction question reads: “On the whole are you very satisfied, fairly satisfied, or not at all

86

satisfied with life you lead?”. Responses were coded on a scale from 1(not at all satisfied) to 4(very satisfied).

87

Diener and Biswas-Diener (2002) urge to use better measures of income, and the best measures, they argue,

88

are at the societal level because measures of income at person level may be inaccurate. People misreport their

89

income, and income varies over time – people are temporarily poor or rich. I use two measures of income at

90

province level7 :

91

92

93

94

• regional income; Gross Domestic Product (GDP) at current market prices, Purchasing Power Standard, euro per inhabitant8 • regional disposable income; Disposable income based on final consumption, Purchasing Power Standard based on final consumption per inhabitant

95

The choice of control variables is dictated by the literature (for a review see Diener and Biswas-Diener (2002),

96

Diener et al. (1993), Clark et al. (2008)). The set of variables used in this study is somewhat limited due to

97

data availability. All person level variables come from EB. All province level variables come from Eurostat9 .

98

There are about 30,000 observations10 , across 188 provinces. Counts and means of life satisfaction and

99

regional income levels are set in table ?? in the appendix A. All results include full sample unless data are

100

missing – there are some provinces with missing income – see table ?? in the appendix A.

101

Literature finds higher correlation between income and and life satisfaction at country level than at person

102

level and that richer countries are happier than rich people (Diener and Biswas-Diener, 2002, Schyns, 2002). 7 Stiglitz et al. (2009) recommend the following: “Recommendation 1: When evaluating material well-being, look at income and consumption rather than production [...] GDP mainly measures market production [...] Material living standards are more closely associated with measures of net national income, real household income and consumption – production can expand while income decreases or vice versa.” Province level income data for this study come from Eurostat http://epp.eurostat.ec. europa.eu 8 For data sources see appendix C. 9 For details see appendix A, table 4 and figure 5. For data sources see appendix C. 10 Due to missing province level data on income the sample used in this study excludes Denmark, Finland and Sweden in regression models.

4

103

Income and life satisfaction correlations in EB data are following:11

104

• personal income: .18

105

• regional income: .34

106

• national income: .52

107

Province level correlations fall between country and person levels. At higher levels of aggregation corre-

108

lations may be higher because higher national income also captures other good things such as public goods

109

Clark et al. (2008). Also, personal characteristics that highly correlate with life satisfaction are averaged

110

out at higher levels of aggregation. For instance, genetic disposition explain as much as 50 percent of life

111

satisfaction (Diener et al., 1999).

112

We know from the literature that there are diminishing marginal returns from income to life satisfaction,

113

at both, person and country levels (Diener et al., 1993, Sanfey and Teksoz, 2005). Figure 1 shows these relationships. This study finds a similar relationship at province level (figure 2)

12

.

The relationship

Figure 1: Income and life satisfaction. (a) Across income groups in the US, averages from 1981 to 1984 (Diener et al., 1993).

(b) Across countries in the World, averages from 1996 to 2004 (Author’s calculation based on World Values Survey Data).

114 115

between life satisfaction and regional income is quadratic13 and similar to that across people and countries.

116

There are two clusters of outliers: The British (UK) are more satisfied than their income would suggest, 11 All significant at .05 level of significance, personal income correlation is polychroic; correlations with regional income in previous year are almost the same. 12 The happiest country Denmark is not shown because regional income data are missing – for detailed data on life satisfaction and regional income see table 4 in the appendix A. 13 There is a similar relationship between life satisfaction and regional disposable income (see figure 7 in the appendix A.)

5

3.5

AT

AT UK

BE

UK BE

3.25

UK

UK

UKUK

UK UK

UK

UK

AT

ES

PT

ES

ES FR

2.75

ES ES

BE ES

ES IT

PT

PT PT

IT

ES ES FR ES BE DEDE

FR IT IT DE

DE

IT

FR FR

PT

DE

DE

DE DE DE

DE

FR

ES

DE

DE

DE

DE

FR

AT DE DE

DE ES DE IT

DE

IT IT

ES IT

IT

IT

DE

IT

IT

IT DE

ES

FR

IT FR FRDE FR

FR BE DE

ES FR FR

IT

DE UK

DE

BE ES

FR

AT BE DE

UK

DE

ES

UK

BE UK

BE

UK

UK AT AT

UK UK

UK DE

UK

BE

UK

UK

UK UK UK

UK

3

life satisfaction

UK

AT UK

UK

UK

UK

FR

IT

FR DE

FR FR

PT

FR

PT

2.5

IT

FR

10000

15000

20000

25000

regional income

Figure 2: Life satisfaction across European regions, quadratic fit with 95% confidence interval. Provinces with income>25,000 euro are not shown because they are outliers (See figure 6 in the appendix A for full sample). For a list of countries and their income see table ?? in the appendix A.

117

while the French (FR) and Italians (IT) are less satisfied than income predicts. There are big differences in

118

mean life satisfaction across provinces. There are many provinces with mean life satisfaction below 2.75 or

119

above 3.25 on scale from 1 to 414 .

120

The quadratic relationship between income and life satisfaction is conceptualized in figure 3. In poor

121

provinces or countries income is more important for life satisfaction, but in rich provinces or countries

122

lifestyle is more important for life satisfaction. It is a similar idea to Maslow’s needs pyramid (Maslow,

123

1987): people first need to satisfy basic needs such as nutrition or shelter, and then higher level needs such

124

as self-actualization. In Maslow’s terminology this is the difference between coping and expression.

125

There is also a positive relationship between personal income and life satisfaction within countries as

126

shown in figure 4. The relationship is stronger in poor countries as suggested in the literature (Diener and

127

Biswas-Diener, 2002). The richest Luxembourg has the flattest slope and poor Portugal and Spain have

128

stepper slopes. Personal income is more important in poor countries. 14 Table

5 in the appendix A shows means and standard deviations for life satisfaction and income variables.

6

nateFig1a.jpg (JPEG Image, 750x552 pixels)

http://campfire.theoildrum.com/uploads/12/nateFig1a.jpg

Figure 3: Life Satisfaction and income, (Inglehart, 1997).

BE

DE

DK

ES

FI

FR

IT

3.5 3.25

03/03/10 10:01

2.75

3

1 of 1

2.5

life satisfaction

2.5

2.75

3

3.25

3.5

AT

PT

SE

UK

2.5

2.75

3

3.25

3.5

LU

0

5

10

15

0

5

10

15

0

5

10

15

0

5

10

15

personal income

Figure 4: Personal income and life satisfaction across countries. Solid lines are quadratic regression slopes, and dotted lines show 95% confidence intervals.

7

129

Analysis

130

This section examines income-life satisfaction relationship in a regression framework, controlling for basic

131

predictors of life satisfaction: unemployment, marital status, age, education and community size15 . A natural

132

framework for analysis of data at different levels is called multilevel modeling16 . Multilevel models account

133

for nesting of individuals within provinces. Appendix B shows model equations. The coefficient estimates

134

are similar in ordinal logistic and linear models, and hence, I use linear model for ease of interpretation17 .

135

Table 2 shows coefficient estimates. Table 2: Regression Results of Life Satisfaction. Regional and national incomes are in 1,000s of euro. personal income community size unemployment finished education at 15 or earlier married age age2 regional income income∗ income regional disposable income income∗ disposable income national income national disposable income Constant n AIC BIC *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

a1 0.027*** -0.011 -0.331*** -0.163*** 0.097*** -0.022*** 0.000***

a2 0.032*** -0.022*** -0.340*** -0.058*** 0.074*** -0.024*** 0.000*** 0.008**

a3 0.046*** -0.023*** -0.339*** -0.057*** 0.074*** -0.024*** 0.000*** 0.015*** -0.000**

a4 0.056*** -0.022*** -0.338*** -0.057*** 0.074*** -0.025*** 0.000***

a5 0.046*** -0.025*** -0.342*** -0.057*** 0.074*** -0.024*** 0.000*** 0.010** -0.000**

0.041*** -0.000**

a6 0.055*** -0.024*** -0.340*** -0.057*** 0.073*** -0.025*** 0.000*** 0.031*** -0.000**

0.015 3.292*** 39653 83529 83597

3.132*** 30316 61852 61961

3.003*** 30316 61876 61993

2.805*** 29613 60552 60668

2.821*** 30316 61751 61885

0.025 2.651*** 29613 60424 60557

136

Column a1 shows a basic OLS model that does not control for contextual effects. Personal income is

137

positive and significant. Column a2 adds regional income in a multilevel model (all subsequent models are

138

multilevel). If a person increases his income by one category (there are twelve categories) it produces as

139

much life satisfaction as increasing regional income by 4,000 euro. Column a3 adds cross level interaction of

140

personal income and regional income, and the effect is negative, but very small – personal income matters less

141

for life satisfaction in rich provinces. Column a4 repeats the same model but replaces regional income with

142

disposable regional income. As expected, regional disposable income has bigger effect on life satisfaction

143

than regional income. Regional income measures production and would increase, for instance, if traffic

144

congestion increases, and hence, regional disposable income is a better measure of objective quality of life.

145

Finally, columns a5 and a6 repeat columns a3 and a4 adding national income and national disposable income.

146

National incomes turn out insignificant. 15 The choice of variables is dictated by the literature (for a review see Diener and Biswas-Diener (2002), Diener et al. (1993), Clark et al. (2008)). The set of variables used in this study is somewhat limited due to data availability. 16 For some common problems that multilevel analysis overcomes and definitions of the concepts see http://www.paho.org/ English/DD/AIS/be_v24n3-multilevel.htm. Kreft and de Leeuw (1998) is a good introduction to multilevel modeling, and Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal (2005) show applied analysis. 17 Ferrer-i-Carbonell and Frijters (2004) reached similar conclusion.

8

147

The estimated models suggest substantial effect of regional income on well-being. For instance, coefficient

148

of 0.008 on regional income in column a2 means that an increase by 1,000 euro in regional income will

149

increase life satisfaction by 0.008 on 1-4 scale for everybody in a province. This is a big effect. To better

150

understand size of this effect, imagine that there are one million people living in a province and this is

151

equivalent to shifting 8,000 people from one satisfaction category to another, say from “not very satisfied” to

152

“fairly satisfied”18 . These findings support livability theory. People are happier in rich provinces – objective

153

living conditions matter for life satisfaction.

154

Table 3 shows differences in life satisfaction between top income quartile and bottom income quartile by

155

regional income quartiles. The life satisfaction gap between the rich and the poor is smaller in rich provinces.

156

This finding supports livability theory, too. According to competing comparison theory regional income

157

should not matter for personal income comparisons19 . Table 3: Difference in life satisfaction between top income quartile and bottom income quartile by regional income quartiles. regional quartile 1 2 3 4 Total

income

mean happiness difference 0.35 0.36 0.30 0.29 0.33

158

Summarizing results, regional income and especially regional disposable income matter for life satisfaction

159

beyond personal and national incomes20 . In fact, national income turns out insignificant when controlling for

160

regional income. This is expected result. What matters for life satisfaction is “livability” or average income

161

in the locality where a person lives. National income is a poor proxy for local income. There is larger life

162

satisfaction inequality between the rich and the poor in poor provinces. Personal income matters more for

163

life satisfaction in poor provinces than in rich provinces.

18 Of course, this is just a specific example and it does not mean that always almost .8 percent of province population shift from one category to another. It may be 1.6 percent of population shifting by .5 on happiness measure, etc. As a robustness check provinces with fewer than 200 observations were dropped (external validity for provinces with few respondents may be low) and models were reestimated, and results are similar . See table 6 in the appendix A. 19 Also, there is a negative relationship between life satisfaction and life satisfaction inequality (see figure 8 in the appendix A). 20 That is, regional income is a significant predictor of life satisfaction when controlling for personal and national incomes.

9

Table 4: Definitions of variables (for frequencies see figure 5). variable life satisfaction married age personal income

unemployment community size finished education at 15 or earlier

definition “On the whole, are you very satisfied, fairly satisfied, not very satisfied, or not at all satisfied with the life you lead? Would you say you are...?” 1(married; living as married); 0(otherwise) age in years “We also need some information about the income of this household to be able to analyze the survey results for different types of households. Here is a list of income groups. (SHOW INCOME CARD) Please count the total wages and salaries PER MONTH of all members of this household; all pensions and social insurance benefits; child allowances and any other income like rents, etc... Of course, your answer as all other replies in this interview will be treated confidentially and referring back to you or your household will be impossible. Please give me the letter of the income group your household falls into before tax and other deductions.” “What is your current occupation?” 1(Unemployed or temporarily not working); 0(otherwise) “Would you say you live in a ...?” “How old were you when you finished your full-time education?” 1(up to 15 years); 0(otherwise)

10

life satisfaction

married

age 100

very satisfied married

80

fairly satisfied 60 not very satisfied

not married

40

not at all satisfied 20 0

10,000 20,000 Frequency

30,000

0

10,000 20,000 Frequency

30,000

0

5,000 10,000 Frequency

15,000

[categories classified into 5 bins]

personal income

unemployment

10

community size

large town

1

small/mid size town 5

0 rural area/village

0

0

5,000 Frequency

10,000

0

20,000 40,000 Frequency

60,000

0

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 Frequency

[categories classified into 5 bins]

finished education at 15 or earlier

regional income

national income

35000

30000

1 30000

25000 25000 20000

20000

0

15000

15000

10000 10000 0

10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 Frequency

0

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 Frequency

0

[categories classified into 5 bins]

regional disposable income 16000

10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 Frequency [categories classified into 5 bins]

national disposable income 14000

14000 12000 12000 10000 10000 8000

8000 6000 0

5,000 10,000 Frequency

15,000

[categories classified into 5 bins]

6000

0

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 Frequency [categories classified into 5 bins]

Figure 5: Histograms of variables. Figure 1: histograms

1

11

3.5

AT

UK

UK UK UK UK

UK

2.75

ESIT

PT

PT PT

IT FR

FR IT BE DE

PT

LU

BE

UK UK AT DE UK

IT DE

BE DE

AT

AT UK

DE

BE UK DE

ES DE BE

AT UK

UK

DE DE DE DE DE

BE DE DE

DE DE FR DE DE

DE ES ES FR DEIT DE ES ES IT FR FR FR ES

ES ES ES ES FR ES FR ES BE ES ES DE DE IT IT ITDE

UKUK UK AT AT UK UK UK UK UK AT UK

BE ES

UK

PT

UK UK

UK

UK DE DE

BE

ES

BE

UK BE

UK UK UK

3

life satisfaction

3.25

AT UK

DE

IT

DE

IT

IT IT

IT

IT IT

DE

DE

DE FR

FR

DE FRFR FR FR FR FR FR

FR DE

IT

FR PT

PT

2.5

IT

FR

FR

10000

20000

30000

40000

regional income

Figure 6: Life satisfaction across European regions, quadratic fit with 95% confidence interval.

12

3.5

AT

UK BE AT

UK

UK

UK UK UK UK

UK

ES ES

ES

PT ES

2.75

PT

ES

ES ES ES

ES IT IT

ES ES

IT IT

ES FR

FR ES ES FR FR ES

PT PT

UK

AT

AT UK

DE BE

AT DE

AT

DE

DE AT

UKDE

BE DE

UK BE

FR BE

FR BE DE FR FR

UK UK UK

BEUK

DE DE DE

DE IT

DE DE DE DE DE

DE

DE DE

DE IT DE

ES

IT FR FR FR FR DE

FR IT

PT

FR

BE BE FR

ES

BE

UK UK UKUK UK UK AT AT UK UK

UK UK UK UK UK

UK UK

3

life satisfaction

3.25

UK

DE

BE DE IT IT IT

DE DE DE IT

IT IT

IT

DE

DE

DE

DE DE

FR IT

FR FR FR

DE

DE

FR PT

FR

2.5

IT PT

FR

6000

8000

10000

12000

14000

16000

regional disposable income

Figure 7: Life satisfaction across European regions, quadratic fit with 95% confidence interval.

13

DK DK

DK

3.5

DK

AT

SE

3.25

FI IT

UK

DE

BE

3

life satisfaction

BE UK SE AT BE UK UK AT LU UK UK SE UK SE UK FI BE UK UK UK UK UK AT UK UKFI AT AT FI FI UK FI UK UK UK UK FI UK DE UK UK FI UK AT FIAT FI DE FI AT FI UK UK FI FI UK FI FI UK UK DE UK BE UK DE UK DE FI FI DE DE BE UK DE DE DE DE DE DE DE BE DE DE DE DE UK ES ESIT IT BE DE IT BE FR DE DE IT IT IT DE ES ES ES PT ES ES IT ES FR IT DE DE ES IT FRES DE ES ITFR ES FR FR BE DEES ES ES DE FR DE FR IT FR IT IT ES IT IT PT FR DE DE FR FR ITDE DE DE FR FR FR DE FRIT DE FR FR PT PT PT DE FR DE PT FR PT IT SE

SE SE

ES

FR

BE

2.5

2.75

DE

FR

.5

.6

.7

.8

.9

life satisfaction inequality

Figure 8: Life satisfaction and life satisfaction inequality (standard deviation of life satisfaction).

Table 5: Means and standard deviations at province level and within countries. country

Mean

Sd

Mean

Sd

Mean

life satisfaction

life satisfaction

regional income

regional income

regional

Sd dispos-

able income

regional

AT

3.2

0.1

19.8

4.8

12.6

0.9

BE

3.1

0.2

18.6

7.5

11.9

1.2

DE

2.9

0.1

19.5

4.2

13.3

1.3

DK

3.6

0.0 14.1

2.8

8.8

1.4

ES

2.9

0.0

FI

3.1

0.1

FR

2.8

0.1

16.0

2.8

10.5

0.8

IT

2.9

0.1

18.0

4.8

11.8

2.8

LU

3.3

PT

2.7

0.1

11.1

2.3

7.3

0.9

SE

3.3

0.0

UK

3.2

0.1

16.6

2.9

11.5

1.2

Total

3.0

0.2

17.3

4.7

11.4

2.2

34.0

14

dispos-

able income

Table 6: Regression Results of Life Satisfaction. Provinces with sample smaller than 200 dropped (25% of cases). Regional and national incomes are in 1,000s of euro. b1

b2

b3

b4

b5

b6

personal income

0.027***

0.031***

0.049***

0.064***

0.049***

0.063***

community size

-0.006

-0.019**

-0.019**

-0.019**

-0.020**

-0.020**

unemployment

-0.343***

-0.348***

-0.347***

-0.345***

-0.348***

-0.346***

finished education at 15 or earlier

-0.174***

-0.043***

-0.043***

-0.042***

-0.042***

-0.042***

married

0.094***

0.064***

0.065***

0.064***

0.063***

0.063***

age

-0.021***

-0.023***

-0.023***

-0.024***

-0.023***

-0.024***

age2

0.000***

0.000***

0.000***

0.000***

0.000***

0.000***

0.008*

0.018***

regional income income∗ income

0.011**

-0.000**

-0.000**

regional disposable income

0.049***

0.039***

income∗ disposable income

-0.000***

-0.000***

national income

0.016

national disposable income Constant

0.026 3.271***

3.107***

2.923***

2.705***

2.778***

n

29623

22473

AIC

62708

45896

BIC

62775

46000

46030

2.559***

22473

21825

22473

21825

45917

44685

45874

44639

44797

46002

44767

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

164

Appendix B

165

Multilevel Model Without subscripting for individual right-hand variables, the classical regression model is given by: yij = αj + β1j X1ij + Xij β + ij

(1)

166

where yij is life satisfaction score for individual i in province j. Xij is a vector of person level variables and,

167

in addition, X1ij is personal income. In its present form this model assumes a single intercept αj and that

168

β1j = β1 across all j. Both assumptions need to be relaxed. In a multilevel model αj is not constant across provinces: αj = γ0 + γ1 Z1j + Zj γ + ζj

(2)

where Zj is a vector of province level predictor variables (excluding Z1j ). If Z1j is a province level variable, say Per Capita Gross Domestic Product (PCGDP ), that is suspected to have interactive effect with a person level variable, say personal income, insertion of (2) into (1) will produce the random intercept model to be estimated: yij = (γ0 + ζj ) + γ1 Z1j + Zj γ + β1j X1ij + Xij β + ij 15

(3)

169

The province specific intercept is given by (γ0 + ζj ). In addition, slope for X1ij is likely to be different across provinces. For simplicity, assume that β1j varies by province depending only on Z1j . β1j = λ01 + λ11 Z1j + u1j

(4)

Insertion of (4) into (3) gives: yij = (γ0 + ζj ) + γ1 Z1j + Zj γ + λ01 X1ij + λ11 X1ij Z1j + β1j X1ij + Xij β (5)

+ (ij + u1j X1ij ) β1j = β1 170

λ01 is a random slope coefficient. λ11 is a cross level interaction random slope coefficient.

171

Appendix C

172

Data sources

173

All person level indicators from Eurobarometer:

174

Reif, Karlheinz, and Eric Marlier. EUROBAROMETER 44.2BIS MEGA-SURVEY: POLICIES AND

175

PRACTICES IN BUILDING EUROPE AND THE EUROPEAN UNION, JANUARY-MARCH 1996 [Com-

176

puter file]. Conducted by INRA (Europe), Brussels. 2nd ICPSR ed. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Con-

177

sortium for Political and Social Research [producer], 2001. Cologne, Germany: Zentralarchiv fur Empirische

178

Sozialforschung/Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributors],

179

2001. doi:10.3886/ICPSR06748

180

http://www.icpsr.umich.edu/icpsrweb/ICPSR/studies/6748

181

Regional income; Gross Domestic Product (GDP) at current market prices, Purchasing Power Standard,

182

183

euro per inhabitant: http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/show.do?query=BOOKMARK_DS-075725_QID_-69E25FC0_

184

UID_-3F171EB0&layout=TIME,C,X,0;GEO,B,Y,0;UNIT,L,Z,0;INDICATORS,C,Z,1;&zSelection=DS-075725INDICATORS,

185

OBS_FLAG;DS-075725UNIT,PPS_HAB;&rankName1=TIME_1_0_0_0&rankName2=INDICATORS_1_0_-1_2&rankName3=

186

UNIT_1_0_-1_2&rankName4=GEO_1_2_0_1&sortC=ASC_-1_FIRST&rStp=&cStp=&rDCh=&cDCh=&rDM=true&cDM=

187

true&footnes=false&empty=false&wai=false&time_mode=NONE&lang=EN [note: this page loads slowly]

188

189

Regional disposable income; Disposable income based on final consumption, Purchasing Power Standard, euro per inhabitant:

16

190

http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/show.do?query=BOOKMARK_DS-053856_QID_-17C0DCE0_

191

UID_-3F171EB0&layout=TIME,C,X,0;GEO,B,Y,0;INDIC_NA,L,Z,0;UNIT,L,Z,1;INDICATORS,C,Z,2;&zSelection=

192

DS-053856INDICATORS,OBS_FLAG;DS-053856UNIT,PPCS_HAB;DS-053856INDIC_NA,B6N_U;&rankName1=TIME_

193

1_0_0_0&rankName2=INDIC-NA_1_0_-1_2&rankName3=INDICATORS_1_0_-1_2&rankName4=UNIT_1_0_-1_2&rankName5=

194

GEO_1_2_0_1&sortC=ASC_-1_FIRST&rStp=&cStp=&rDCh=&cDCh=&rDM=true&cDM=true&footnes=false&empty=

195

false&wai=false&time_mode=NONE&lang=EN [note: this page loads slowly]

17

196

References

197

Aslam, A. and L. Corrado (2007): “No Man is an Island: the Inter-personal Determinants of Regional

198

199

200

201

202

203

204

205

206

Well-Being in Europe,” Unpublished. Blanchflower, D. and A. Oswald (2004): “Money, sex and happiness: An empirical study,” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 393–415. Bohnke, P. (2008): “Does Society Matter? Life Satisfaction in the Enlarged Europe,” Social Indicators Research, 87, 189–210. Clark, A. E. (2003): “Inequality-Aversion and Income Mobility: A Direct Test,” DELTA Working Paper, 03-11. Clark, A. E., P. Frijters, and M. A. Shields (2008): “Relative Income, Happiness, and Utility: An Explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and Other Puzzles,” Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 95–144.

207

Delhey, J. (2005): Life satisfaction in an enlarged Europe, Eurofound.

208

Diener, E. and R. Biswas-Diener (2002): “Will money increase subjective well-being? A Literature

209

210

211

212

213

214

215

216

217

218

219

Review and Guide to Needed Research,” Social Indicators Research, 57, 119–169. Diener, E., E. Sandvik, L. Seidlitz, and M. Diener (1993): “The relationship between income and subjective well-being:relative or absolute?” Social Indicators Research, 28, 195–223. Diener, E., E. M. Suh, and R. E. Lucas (1999): “Subjective well-being: three decades of progress,” Psychological Bulletin, 125, 276–302. Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. and P. Frijters (2004): “How Important is Methodology for the Estimates of the Determinants of Happiness?” Economic Journal, 114, 641–659. Frey, B. S. and A. Stutzer (2000): “Happiness, Economy and Institutions,” Economic Journal, 110, 918–938. Inglehart, R. (1997): Modernization and postmodernization: Cultural, economic, and political change in 43 societies, Princeton Univ Pr.

220

Kreft, I. and J. de Leeuw (1998): Introducing Multilevel Modelling, London: Sage Publications.

221

Maslow, A. (1987): Motivation and personality, Longman, 3 ed.

18

222

Michalos, A. C. (1985): “Multiple Discrepancies Theory (MDT),” Social Indicators Research, 16, 347–413.

223

Okulicz-Kozaryn, A. (2010): “Geography of European Life Satisfaction,” Forthcoming in Social Indicators

224

225

226

227

228

229

230

231

232

233

234

Research. Pittau, M., R. Zelli, and A. Gelman (2010): “Economic Disparities and Life Satisfaction in European Regions.” Social Indicators Research, 96, 339 – 361. Putnam, R. D., R. Leonardi, and R. Y. Nanetti (1993): Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy., Princeton University Press. Rabe-Hesketh, S. and A. Skrondal (2005): Multilevel and Longitudinal Modelling Using Stata, College Station: Stata Press. Rampichini, C. and S. Schifini D’Andrea (1998): “A hierarchical ordinal probit model for the analysis of life satisfaction in Italy.” Social Indicators Research, 44, 41 – 69. Robinson, W. S. (1950): “Ecological correlations and the behavior of individuals.” American Sociological Review, 15, 351 – 357.

235

Sanfey, P. and U. Teksoz (2005): “Does Transition Make You Happy?” EBRD Working Paper 58.

236

Schyns, P. (2002): “Wealth of nations, individual income and life satisfaction in 42 countries: a multilevel

237

238

239

240

approach,” Social Indicators Research, 60, 5–40. Somarriba, N. and B. Pena (2009): “Synthetic Indicators of Quality of Life in Europe,” Social Indicators Research, 94, 115–133. Stiglitz, J., A. Sen, and J. Fitoussi (2009): “Report by the Commission on the measurement of economic

241

performance and social progress,” Paris, available at www. stiglitz-sen-fitoussi. fr.

242

Veenhoven, R. (1991): “Is happiness relative?” Social Indicators Research, 24, 1–34.

243

Veenhoven, R. and J. Ehrhardt (1995): “The Cross-National Pattern of Happiness: Test of Predictions

244

Implied in Three Theories of Happiness,” Social Indicators Research, 34, 33–68.

19

Income and Well-being across European Provinces

relationship is important for people: Will making more money make me happier? And it is important for. 16 policy makers: Should taxation encourage longer working hours or more leisure? 17. How income relates to life satisfaction? A major theory that explains this relationship across countries is. 18 called livability theory ...

545KB Sizes 0 Downloads 144 Views

Recommend Documents

Provinces and Districts of Thailand.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Provinces and ...

Income inequality and export prices across countries
while differentiated goods confirm the predictions from trade models incorporating non- homothetic preferences, homogeneous goods follow a different pattern.

European Fixed Income Markets
Structured Equity Derivatives: The Definitive Guide to Exotic Options and Structured ... Jossey-Bass, 989 Market Street, San Francisco, CA 94103-1741, USA ... European fixed income markets : money, bond, and interest rate ...... markets available, th

Retirement and Financial Wellbeing - Employee Benefit Research ...
Jan 11, 2018 - 2. Employee Benefit Research Institute: EBRI Policy Forum #82 – Retirement and Financial Wellbeing, January 11, 2018 reactions to such a program were largely positive. After learning additional details about the proposed program, suc

Wellbeing 232.pdf
I want to know what the future holds for breast cancer. patients and what is going to be available in the coming. months and years. These are the people that are ...

European Partitioning Across Africa Cloze & Map.pdf
European Partitioning Across Africa Cloze & Map.pdf. European Partitioning Across Africa Cloze & Map.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu.

of cadiz and huelva provinces (sw spain)
1 Dpto. Biologia Animal, Biologia Vegetal y Ecologia, Area de Zoologta,. Universidad de Jaen. ..... laboratory manual. Cold Spring Harbor ... Gazumyan, A., Zinmmermann, E., Goldberg, N.S., Bittker, N.S., Campbell,. G.L. & Paviaa, C.S., 1992.

Indigenous health and wellbeing - Australian Institute of Aboriginal ...
Apr 3, 2009 - only respond to the building of a real sense of control in individual and .... Aboriginal testimony of the nexus between human health and place', ..... not equate to good health and wellbeing and second, privatisation and ..... informat

EBRI-ERF POLICY FORUM #82 Retirement and Financial Wellbeing ...
4 days ago - Charitable Trusts o http://www.pewtrusts.org/en/about/ · experts/john-scott · • http://www.pewtrusts.org/~/media/assets/2017/10/retire · ment_savings_worker_reactions_v5.pdf. 10:30-10:45 - Financial Shocks Put Retirement Security at Ri

Indigenous health and wellbeing - Australian Institute of Aboriginal ...
Apr 3, 2009 - The study supports the assertion that connection to country, or behaviours .... . 13 Social ...

BOOK LAUNCHING The Wellbeing Society.pdf
BOOK LAUNCHING The Wellbeing Society.pdf. BOOK LAUNCHING The Wellbeing Society.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying BOOK ...

Wellbeing workshops Spring 2017.pdf
Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Wellbeing workshops Spring 2017.pdf. Wellbeing workshops Spring 2017.pdf. Open. Extract.

Wellbeing workshops Spring 2017.pdf
Student Wellbeing Service. A series of personal development courses and one-off workshops. designed to help you get the best out of life at University.

BOOK LAUNCHING The Wellbeing Society.pdf
Page 1 of 6. 1. BOOK LAUNCHING IN BANGKOK. THE WELLBEING SOCIETY. A Radical Middle Path to Global. Transformation. Author: Hans van Willenswaard. Publishers: Garden of Fruition, Bangkok, 2016. The book re-envisions the complex learning journey of a g

sarmizegetusa ulpia traiana capital of the dacian provinces
a very dynamic, cultural, social, economic, religious and military center. With its ... During the 2016 campaign, we will continue the exploration of the Domus ...

sarmizegetusa ulpia traiana capital of the dacian provinces
a very dynamic, cultural, social, economic, religious and military center. With its ... During the 2016 campaign, we will continue the exploration of the Domus ...