It’s Not You, It’s Me: Breakups in U.S.-China Trade Relationships Ryan Monarch Federal Reserve Board [email protected]

August 7, 2014

Any opinions and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System, or the U.S. Census Bureau. All results have been reviewed to ensure that no confidential information is disclosed.

Introduction

1/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Mismatch between producers and suppliers can be a source of inefficiency. If buyers do not know about lower-priced alternatives to their current supplier, or are unable / unwilling to pay the cost of changing, this can lead to high prices. Anecdotal evidence suggests that finding the right supplier is difficult:

Introduction

1/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Mismatch between producers and suppliers can be a source of inefficiency. If buyers do not know about lower-priced alternatives to their current supplier, or are unable / unwilling to pay the cost of changing, this can lead to high prices. Anecdotal evidence suggests that finding the right supplier is difficult:

Introduction

1/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Mismatch between producers and suppliers can be a source of inefficiency. If buyers do not know about lower-priced alternatives to their current supplier, or are unable / unwilling to pay the cost of changing, this can lead to high prices. Anecdotal evidence suggests that finding the right supplier is difficult:

Little empirical work on why one supplier is chosen and not another.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

In this paper, I:

2/ 39

Use two-sided trade data from U.S. Customs and Border Protection to describe how U.S. importers match with Chinese exporters. Model an importer’s choice of exporter as a dynamic discrete choice problem with switching costs: Cost of switching partner Additional cost of switching city.

Estimate these switching frictions across industries. Determine how import prices will change based on switching becoming more common and/or more efficent.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Preview of Empirical Results: Importers are very likely to remain with their partner over time.

3/ 39

45% of U.S. continuing importers from China maintain their partner year-to-year (average of 30 choices in an HS10 product).

A significant share of switching occurs within-city. 1/3 of switching importers remain in the same city (average of 9 cities).

Higher prices strongly affect the probability of switching.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Preview of Quantitative Results:

4/ 39

Structural estimates of switching costs are large and heterogeneous across industries. The impact of switching frictions on prices is sizable: Halving costs leads to a 12.5% lower U.S.-China Import Price Index. Eliminating partner costs while maintaining geographic costs lowers prices by 15.2%.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Related Research Use of importer-exporter relationship data:

5/ 39

Kamal and Krizan (2012), Eaton, Eslava, Jinkins, Krizan, Kugler, and Tybout (2012), Kamal and Sundaram (2013), Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe (2013)

Discrete Choice Modeling: Rust (1987), Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995), Fox (2010), Su and Judd (2012), Dub´e, Fox, and Su (2012)

Relationships, networking and contract formation among suppliers: Joskow (1985), Doney and Cannon (1997), Kranton and Mineheart (2001), Rauch (2001), Rauch and Watson (2004), Ahn, Khandewal and Wei (2011), Tang and Zhang (2012)

Relationship frictions in importer-exporter choice Alessandria (2009), Kleshchelski and Vincent (2009), Drozd and Nosal (2012)

Data

Introduction

7/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

U.S. import data is from the Linked-Longitudinal Foreign Trade Transaction Database (LFTTD), collected by U.S. Customs and Border Protection and maintained by U.S. Census Bureau. Each transaction contains (a) (b) (c) (d)

Value and quantity (and thus “unit value”) HS 10 industry code. Unique exporter identifier (known as Manuf. ID). Exporter location (city) information.

Conclusion

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

U.S. import data is from the Linked-Longitudinal Foreign Trade Transaction Database (LFTTD), collected by U.S. Customs and Border Protection and maintained by U.S. Census Bureau. Each transaction contains (a) (b) (c) (d)

Value and quantity (and thus “unit value”) HS 10 industry code. Unique exporter identifier (known as Manuf. ID). Exporter location (city) information.

Example: MONARCH PAPER PRODUCTS 426 THOMPSON ST, BASEMENT ANN ARBOR, MI 48104 USA

7/ 39

Internal Validity

External Validity

Conclusion

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

U.S. import data is from the Linked-Longitudinal Foreign Trade Transaction Database (LFTTD), collected by U.S. Customs and Border Protection and maintained by U.S. Census Bureau. Each transaction contains (a) (b) (c) (d)

Value and quantity (and thus “unit value”) HS 10 industry code. Unique exporter identifier (known as Manuf. ID). Exporter location (city) information.

Example: MONARCH PAPER PRODUCTS 426 THOMPSON ST, BASEMENT ANN ARBOR, MI 48104 USA

8/ 39

Internal Validity

External Validity

Conclusion

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

U.S. import data is from the Linked-Longitudinal Foreign Trade Transaction Database (LFTTD), collected by U.S. Customs and Border Protection and maintained by U.S. Census Bureau. Each transaction contains (a) (b) (c) (d)

Value and quantity (and thus “unit value”) HS 10 industry code. Unique exporter identifier (known as Manuf. ID). Exporter location (city) information.

Example: MONARCH PAPER PRODUCTS 426 THOMPSON ST, BASEMENT ANN ARBOR, MI 48104 USA

9/ 39

Internal Validity

External Validity

USMONPAP426ANN

Conclusion

771673 Introduction

354052 Data

478006 Model

539859 Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Fact 1: Many Importer-Exporter Relationships Remain Over Time Fact 2: Strong Geographic Component to Switching Behavior Figure: “Staying” Percentages of Continuing Importers from China, 2003-2008 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 Same Partner

Same City

Same Province

Staying means “highest value share from same supplier” (Mean = 83.9%). Does not inlcude “related party” imports.

Internal Validity 10/ 39

External Validity

Robustness

2003 39,098,921,196 Introduction Data 2004 62,308,431,843 2005 83827616010 2006 1.12478E+11 2007 1.25419E+11 2008 140,239,928,638

Model

35182994843 Implementation Results 55926603344 74123737186 92421195287 1.10957E+11 1.22529E+11

19367929172 Counterfactuals Conclusion 29198387690 37454826628 47534086862 58207220996 61416071528

Fact 1: Many Importer-Exporter Relationships Remain Over Time Fact 2: Strong Geographic Component to Switching Behavior Figure: U.S. (Non-Subsidiary) Imports from China, 2003-2008 160 140 120

152,436,100,000

Billions USD

100 80 60 40 20 0 2003

2004 Total Imports

2005

2006

2007

2008

Total Imports, Same Partner

Staying means “highest value share from same supplier” (Mean = 83.9%). Does not inlcude “related party” imports.

Internal Validity 11/ 39

External Validity

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Fact 3: The decision to switch is correlated with price and exporter/importer covariates. Dep. Var.: Stayed with Chinese Exporter Year-to-Year, 2002-2008 (1) (2) (3) (4) ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ Log Price -0.0084 -0.0099 -0.0104 -0.0106∗∗∗ (0.001)

(0.001)

(0.001)

Log Supplier Size

(0.001)

0.0399∗∗∗

0.0643∗∗∗

0.0643∗∗∗

(0.001)

(0.001)

(0.001)

Supplier Age

-0.0024∗∗∗

-0.0031∗∗∗

-0.0029∗∗∗

(0.000)

Importer Size Entry Year FE N R2

No 510,485 0.07

No 510,485 0.09

(0.000)

(0.000)

-0.0322∗∗∗

-0.0306∗∗∗

(0.001)

(0.001)

No 510,485 0.10

Yes 510,485 0.10

HS10 product and year fixed effects included. Standard errors clustered at product level.

12/ 39

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Fact 3: The decision to switch is correlated with price and exporter/importer covariates.

13/ 39

Conclusion

Model

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Dynamic Discrete Exporter Choice Model

15/ 39

Importer m picks the exporter xtm ∈ Xt giving highest profits, knowing  m E px,t : Expected price from each xt βx , βc : Frictions from switching exporter and city. λx,t : Quality for each xt m x,t : Match-specific shock for each xt (i.i.d).

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Dynamic Discrete Exporter Choice Model

15/ 39

Importer m picks the exporter xtm ∈ Xt giving highest profits, knowing  m E px,t : Expected price from each xt βx , βc : Frictions from switching exporter and city. λx,t : Quality for each xt m x,t : Match-specific shock for each xt (i.i.d).

Price transition process- parametrized with LFTTD: xtm = xtm−1 :

m m m px,t = px,t−1 + ηc,t + ux,t

xtm = xem 6= xtm−1 :

pxem,t =

m 2 ux,t ∼ N 0, σx,t



1 N

PN

n=1

pxen,t−1 + ηce,t + uxem,t

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Sketch of the Model: which x maximizes profits?

16/ 39

Possible Choices

X1

Importer

X2 (current)

Choice Affected By E[p1], λ1, ε1, must pay βx

E[p2], λ2, ε2

X3 E[p3], λ3, ε3, must pay βx and βc

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Importers Final good producer m requires J inputs, indexed j = 1, ..., J.  m J . Thus an xj,t for each product j, with whole set Xtm = xj,t j=1

Monopolistically competitive in its final good. Production is Cobb-Douglas in labor and inputs. CES demand for its final good, with elasticity of substitution σ.

17/ 39

Conclusion

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Importers Final good producer m requires J inputs, indexed j = 1, ..., J.

17/ 39

 m J . Thus an xj,t for each product j, with whole set Xtm = xj,t j=1

Monopolistically competitive in its final good. Production is Cobb-Douglas in labor and inputs. CES demand for its final good, with elasticity of substitution σ.

Choice of which exporter xj,t to obtain input j. i h m Form expectations about the price from an exporter E pj,x,t . Frictions from changing exporters, measured as an additional component of the price paid:  m   m m m m m p¯x,j,t = E pj,x,t exp ζx,j 1{xj,t 6= xj,t−1 } + ζc,j 1{cj,t 6= cj.t−1 }

Introduction

18/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

n oJ m : Expected importer profits at t with choice vector Xtm = xj,t j=1

πtm = maxm pm Qm − MC (Xtm ) Qm pm ,Xt

Specific form of MC

Each product j is additively separable in log terms, and thus I focus on the purchase of good j only.

Introduction

19/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

For any importer, the log expected exporter-specific profit term from a match xtm is:  m m m πm t (xt , β) + x,t = βp E ln px,t + ξ λx,t − |{z} βx |{z}

1

{xtm

6=

m xt−1 }

PartnerCost Specifics

Preference Heterogeneity



βc |{z}

CityCost

1

{ctm

6=

Quality m ct−1 } +

m x,t |{z}

Profit Shock

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Value Function Importer m chooses an exporter x in each period to maximize profits. " V (pt−1 , xt−1 , t−1 ) =

max

{xt ,xt+1 ,...}

E

∞ X

# δ τ −t (π τ (xτ , pτ −1 , xτ −1 , β) + x,τ )

τ =t

which can be rewritten as a Bellman Equation:   0 0 0 + δEV x , p, x,  π x , p, x, β +  V (p, x, ) = max x 0 x

for

20/ 39

0

 EV x , p, x,  =

Z Z p0

0

  V p 0 , x 0 , 0 h p 0 , 0 |p, x, x 0 ,  dp 0 d0

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Assumption (1) Conditional Independence h (pt+1 , t+1 ) = g (t+1 ) f (pt+1 |pt , xt , xt+1 ) Assumption (2) Type I Extreme Value (Gumbel) Shocks Pr (t < y ) = G (y ) = exp{− exp{−y − γ}}, γ = 0.577

21/ 39

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Assumption (1) Conditional Independence h (pt+1 , t+1 ) = g (t+1 ) f (pt+1 |pt , xt , xt+1 ) Assumption (2) Type I Extreme Value (Gumbel) Shocks Pr (t < y ) = G (y ) = exp{− exp{−y − γ}}, γ = 0.577 Proposition For s = {p−1 , x−1 }, and any variable a0 as the one-period ahead of a:      exp π x C , s, β + δEV x C , s C P x |s, β = P (1) x , s, β) + δEV (b x , s)] xb∈X exp [π (b

21/ 39

for (

Z EV (x, s) =

log s0

X

)     exp π x 0 , s 0 , β + δEV x 0 , s 0 f s 0 |s, x

x 0 ∈X

(2)

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Maximum Likelihood The parameters β can then be solved for via maximum likelihood m , pm estimation. For observed {xt−1 x,t−1 }, the likelihood of observing the set of outcomes at time t is

22/ 39

L (β) =

M Y m=1

  m m m m m P xtm |xt−1 , px,t−1 , β · f px,t |px,t−1 , xt−1 , xtm

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Maximum Likelihood The parameters β can then be solved for via maximum likelihood m , pm estimation. For observed {xt−1 x,t−1 }, the likelihood of observing the set of outcomes at time t is

22/ 39

L (β) =

M Y

  m m m m m P xtm |xt−1 , px,t−1 , β · f px,t |px,t−1 , xt−1 , xtm

m=1

The log-liklihood maximization problem can be written: max ln L (β) = max β

β

M X

P m=1

m m m m exp [π m t (xt , st , β) + δEV (xt , st )] + ... m m xt , st , β) + δEV (b xtm , stm )] xbtm ∈X exp [π (b

(3)

s.t Z EV (xt , st ) =

log st+1

  X 

xt+1 ∈X

  exp [π t+1 (xt+1 , st+1 , β) + δEV (xt+1 , st+1 )] 

× f (st+1 |st , xt )

(4)

Implementation

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Bringing the Model to the Data In order to compute EV (xt , st ) in (4), I approximate the integral using the equation: EV (xt , sbt ) = N X b st+1 =1

24/ 39

log

  X 

xt+1 ∈X

st+1 , xt+1 )] exp [π t+1 (xt+1 , sbt+1 , β) + δEV (b

 

· Pr (b st+1 |b s t , xt )



Many importers have more than one exporting partner: I make the observed choice “who do I get the majority of my imports from”. The average share of imports from a U.S. importer’s main Chinese exporte is 83.9%, standard deviation of 22%.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

I use the MPEC methodology of Su and Judd (2012) and Dub´e, Fox and Su (2012) to solve the MLE problem The only values of β and EV that are used as test candidates are those that satisfy the fixed point equation above.

Data from U.S.-China trade between 2005-2006. Use TOMLAB / KNITRO to compute the Jacobian and the gradient numerically, and then solve the above MLE problem. Fixed parameters: δ=0.975, N=5 Quality λ is approximated similar to the control function approach of Kim and Petrin (2008) and Khandewal (2011). Quality Monte Carlo Results

25/ 39

Results

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Summary of Results

27/ 39

Model estimates of switching costs are large βx βc

Partner Cost City Cost

Mean 2.99 1.61

For 2 identical partners, switching requires an unobservable shock ≈ 2.3 standard deviations above the mean.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Summary of Results

27/ 39

Model estimates of switching costs are large βx βc

Partner Cost City Cost

Mean 2.99 1.61

For 2 identical partners, switching requires an unobservable shock ≈ 2.3 standard deviations above the mean.

Estimates are heterogeneous across industries.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Low out-city switching implies high out-city switching costs...

28/ 39

βx βc

HS6 841320

Table: Parameter Estimates HS6 841320 820310 Partner Cost 1.67 2.74 Out-City Cost 3.95 2.95

HS6 820310

Conclusion

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Low out-city switching implies high out-city switching costs...

28/ 39

βx βc

HS6 841320

Table: Parameter Estimates HS6 841320 820310 Partner Cost 1.67 2.74 Out-City Cost 3.95 2.95

HS6 820310

Very few switching importers (≈ 20%) switch outside of their city.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

and high out-city switching implies low out-city switching costs.

29/ 39

βx βc

Table: Parameter Estimates HS6 841320 820310 847130 Partner Cost 1.67 2.74 3.00 Out-City Cost 3.95 2.95 0.43

HS6 847130

HS6 871120

871120 3.91 0.19

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

and high out-city switching implies low out-city switching costs.

29/ 39

βx βc

Table: Parameter Estimates HS6 841320 820310 847130 Partner Cost 1.67 2.74 3.00 Out-City Cost 3.95 2.95 0.43

HS6 847130

HS6 871120

871120 3.91 0.19

Most switching importers (≈ 80%) switch outside of their city.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

High sensitivity to price changes implies a strong effect on switching...

30/ 39

βp

Table: Parameter Estimates HS10 6116106500 Price Elasticity of Switching -0.06

HS10 6116106500

HS10 6403406000

6403406000 -0.05

Import price elasticity is large (9-14)

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

and low sensitivity to price changes implies a non-effect on switching.

31/ 39

βp

Table: Parameter Estimates HS10 611610 640340 6116930800 Elas. of Switching -0.06 -0.05 0.25

HS10 6116930800

HS10 6107110010

6107110010 0.51

Import price elasticity is small (1-2)

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Model Fit

32/ 39

I estimate parameters for 50 randomly chosen industries. Compute BLS Import Price Index: Weight by firm size to make Industry Price Index, then weight by industry size.

Price Index Weighted Average Median

Data

Median over 1000 runs

%

84.6239 66.1725

76.4979 61.7019

90.4 93.2

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Model Fit

32/ 39

I estimate parameters for 50 randomly chosen industries. Compute BLS Import Price Index: Weight by firm size to make Industry Price Index, then weight by industry size.

Price Index Weighted Average Median

Data

Median over 1000 runs

%

84.6239 66.1725

76.4979 61.7019

90.4 93.2

Total Switching Partner Total Switching City

Data 714 416

Industry Median 711 469

% 99.6 112.7

Counterfactuals

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Counterfactual Experiments

34/ 39

I estimate parameters for 50 randomly chosen industries.

Counterfactual I: Adjust the switching cost parameters, reassign importers to exporters, and calculate the BLS Import Price Index for each set of outcomes. Partner Cost βx ↓ 50%, City Cost βc ↓ 50% =⇒ Prices decrease by 12.5% % of Staying Importers ↓ from 57% to 18%

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Counterfactual I: Adjust the switching cost parameters, and reassign importers to different exporters: Figure: Kernel Density Plots, Original β vs. Reduced By Half

Individual Industries

35/ 39

Introduction

36/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Figure: Kernel Density Plots, Selected Industries

Conclusion

Overall Price Index

HS 401120, Rubber Tires

HS 610432, W/G Cotton Jackets

HS 847130, Laptop Computers

HS 640340, Metal Toe-Cap Ftwr

HS 852520, Cell Phones

HS 850940, Mixers/Blenders

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Counterfactual I: Adjust the switching cost parameters, and reassign importers to different exporters: βx = 0, βc unchanged =⇒ Prices decrease by 15.20% % of Staying Importers ↓ from 57% to 8%

βx unchanged, βc = 0 =⇒ Prices decrease by 7.37% % of Switching Importers ↓ from 57% to 31%

βx triples, βc triples =⇒ Prices increase by 7.62% % of Staying Importers ↑ from 57% to 90% Summary

37/ 39

Introduction

38/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Counterfactual II: Allow for an additional supplier, that can be switched to with no city-switching friction: Table: Counterfactual Results (II) Reduction from average Offered Price Trade Share U.S. Exporter Price Median 3.86% 56.27% 75th Pct. 3.18% 34.04%

Conclusion

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Conclusion

39/ 39

Demonstrated new empirical regularities for exporter switching. Solved a Dynamic Discrete Choice model to solve for geographically diverse switching costs. Estimated cost measures that connect well to our conceptions of substitutability and geographic switching behavior. Performed counterfactual experiments to demonstrate the importance of the switching channel for import prices.

Thank You!

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Figure: Robustness Checks, % of Importers Staying

Conclusion

Go Back

Importer_counts Importer_counts

Original Partner Found in Later Year Original Partner Found in Later Year 1

1

0.9

0.9

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7 0.6

0.6

0.5

0.5

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1 0

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

Same Partner

1.00 Same 0.44 0.29 Sheet1 0.19 0.13 0.10

Same City

1.00 0.61 0.50 0.42 0.37 0.34

Sheet1 2002 1.00 2003 0.68 2004 0.60 2005 0.53 2006 0.49 2007 0.47

1.00 0.61 0.61 0.61 0.61 0.61

1.00 0.68 0.68 0.68 0.68 0.68

Province

Importer as Firm-HS6 Code 1.0

1.0

0.9

1.00 0.9 0.44 0.8 0.44 0.7 0.44 0.44 0.6 0.44 0.5

0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4

0.1

0.0

0.0 Same Partner

Same City

0.9 0.8 0.7

Same Partner

0.00 0.80 2006

2007

Same Province

0.53 0.49 0.47

Same City

0.00

Same Province

Same City

1.0

Same Province

Page 4

0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

0.0

1.00

1.00 0.90

Same Partner

Same City

2002

Same Par

2002

Same Pa

1.00 Same Pa 0.68 0.68 0.68 0.68 0.68

Same Partner

2008

0.00

2002

1.00 0.61 0.61 0.61 0.61 0.61

Importer as Firm

0.5

0.40 0.20

0.0

Same Partner

0.60

Manufacturing Firms Only 0.20

0.1

Same Province

0.6

0.0

Sheet1 0.00 0.80 2005 1.00 2002 0.60 0.68 Same City Same Par 0.60 0.40

2004

0.2

Page 2

1.0

1.00 0.61 0.50 0.42 0.37 0.34

0.3

0.2

0.1

1.00 0.44 0.8 0.44 0.7 0.44 0.44 0.6 0.44 0.5 0.9

2003

0.4

0.3

0.2

41/ 39

1.0

0.4

0.3

0

1.00 0.44 0.29 0.19 0.13 0.10

0.90 Same Province

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Are these identified exporters some other firm, not the manufacturer?

42/ 39

Possibility 1: This is actually the shipping / forwarding firm, not the manufacturer. Possibility 2: This is a trading house or intermediary.

Possibility 1: This is actually the shipping / forwarding firm.

Possibility 2: This is a trading house or intermediary.

Is the exporter code is uniquely capturing one exporting firm?

Is the exporter code is uniquely capturing one exporting firm?

Panel A: Uniqueness of the “MID”, 2005 Industry (CIC) # of Exporters # of “MID”s CIC 3663 39 38 CIC 3689 27 26 CIC 3353 37 37 CIC 3331 35 35 CIC 4154 74 73 Panel B: Uniqueness of the City Code Industry (CIC) # of Cities # of City Codes,2005 CIC 3663 22 21 CIC 3689 15 14 CIC 3353 28 24 CIC 3331 15 13 CIC 4154 19 18

% 97.4 97.3 100 100 98.6

% 95.5 93.3 85.7 86.7 94.7

Panel C: Changes in the “MID” over Time, 2005-2006 Industry (CIC) # of Exporters # of with Identical “MID” CIC 3663 33 33 CIC 3689 26 26 CIC 3353 31 28 CIC 3331 20 17 CIC 4154 63 62

Go back

% 100 100 90.3 85.0 98.4

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Fact 1: Prevalent Breakups in Import-Export Relationships Fact 2: Strong Geographic Component to Switching Behavior

Table 1: Firm‐HS10 Code Year Total Importers Same Partner 2003 99,116 55,272 2004 84,367 35,193 2005 74,506 22,594 2006 64,323 15,683 2007 50,105 9,840

Sheet1 Same City Same Province 65,905 69,310 50,478 54,967 40,755 45,865 34,033 39,317 25,697 30,290

Table: Later Year “Staying” Counts of U.S. Firms Importing from China in 2002

Go Back

49/ 39

China 80,963 67,908 60,143 53,514 42,201

Introduction

50/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Production is Cobb-Douglas. Unit cost bundle:  cm (Xtm ) = w α 

J Y 

1−α m p¯x,j,t

γj



j=1

Importer productivity depends on both individual firm productivity and the product quality/ specific match from the exporter it uses: φm (Xtm ) = ψm

J Y

λνx,j

j=1

Marginal cost function is: MC (Xtm ) = cm (Xtm ) Go back

1 φm (Xtm )

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Assuming CES demand with e.o.s. σ, profits are: πtm

1 = max B m Xt σ



σ σ−1

1−σ

[φm ((Xtm )]σ−1 cm (Xtm )1−σ

After taking logs, and focusing on the choice of input j, the supplier choice profit maximization problem is: X m m ln πtm = A + ln πj,t + ln πk,t k6=j

where m ln πj,t = max ν (σ − 1) ln λx,j,t m xj,t

  m   m  m  m m + (1 − α) (1 − σ) γj E ln px,j,t + ζx,j 1 xj,t 6= xj,t−1 + ζc,j 1 cj,t 6= cj,t−1 Go back

51/ 39

Introduction

52/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

If importer m stays with its current partner x in city c, using (1) and taking logs, we can write the price process as: pm,x,t = pm,x,t−1 + ηc,t + um,x,t

(5)

A high price increase from one exporter could be due to city reasons or idiosyncratic reasons. Key importer decision: far city, lower average price vs. same city, high probability for high average price.

If importer m decides to use a different partner x 0 in the same city c, then the price process is: pm,x 0 ,t =

N 1 X pn,x 0 ,t−1 + ηc,t + vm,x,t N n=1

n = 1, ..., N are the importers from x 0 in time t − 1.

(6)

Introduction

53/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

If the importer decides to go to an exporter x 00 in another city c 0 , then the price process is: 0

pm,x 00 ,t

N 1 X = 0 pn0 ,x 00 ,t−1 + ηc 0 ,t + wm,x 00 ,c 0 ,t N 0 n =1

(7)

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

If the importer decides to go to an exporter x 00 in another city c 0 , then the price process is: 0

pm,x 00 ,t

N 1 X = 0 pn0 ,x 00 ,t−1 + ηc 0 ,t + wm,x 00 ,c 0 ,t N 0

(7)

n =1

I use these to characterize a distribution of expected prices to avoid a Heckman-type selection problem. Go back

53/ 39

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

To estimate unobserved exporter heterogeneity, I assume a simple price process for exporters: m px,t =µ

1 β (λx,t ) zx

Then take logs and regressing export price on a number of exporter-specific covariates: Number of HS 10 products exported Age Size of exports to the U.S. Total number of transactions Total number of import partners. Location fixed effects.

Following the control function estimation technique of Kim and Petrin (2008), use the residual unobserved heterogeneity as a component of the profit function. Go back

54/ 39

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Table: Monte Carlo Replication Results, based on 250 Replications Conv. βp βx βc Rate Pre-Set Values −0.5 −1 −3 Sample A: M = 6, X = 3, C = 2 .456 Mean −0.378 −35.45 −3.633 Median −0.341 −2.293 −3.429 Sample B: M = 30, X = 33, C = 3 1 Mean −0.543 −0.843 −8.209 Median −0.540 −0.837 −5.017 Sample C: M = 30, X = 33, C = 9 1 Mean −0.538 −0.985 −3.427 Median −0.512 −1.055 −3.081 Go Back

55/ 39

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Value Function Importer m chooses an exporter x in each period to maximize profits. " V (pt−1 , xt−1 , t−1 ) =

max

{xt ,xt+1 ,...}

E

∞ X

# δ τ −t (e π (pτ −1 , xτ −1 , xτ , β) + x,τ )

τ =t

which can be rewritten as a Bellman Equation:   0 0 0 + δEV p, x, x ,  V (p, x, ) = max π e p, x, x , β +  x 0 x

for EV p, x, x

0



Z Z = p0

Go Back

56/ 39

0

  V p 0 , x 0 , 0 h p 0 , 0 |p, x, x 0 ,  dp 0 d0

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

Bringing the Model to the Data Many importers have more than one exporting partner: I make the observed choice “who do I get the majority of my imports from”. The average share of imports from a U.S. importer’s main Chinese exporte is 83.9%, standard deviation of 22%.

Data from U.S.-China trade between 2005-2006. Quality λ is approximated similar to the control function approach of Kim and Petrin (2008). Quality Monte Carlo Results

57/ 39

Introduction

58/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

I use the MPEC methodology of Su and Judd (2012) and Dube, Fox and Su (2012) to solve the MLE problem The only values of β and EV that are used as test candidates are those that satisfy the fixed point equation (2) above.

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

I use the MPEC methodology of Su and Judd (2012) and Dube, Fox and Su (2012) to solve the MLE problem The only values of β and EV that are used as test candidates are those that satisfy the fixed point equation (2) above.

Use TOMLAB / KNITRO to compute the Jacobian and the gradient numerically, and then solve the above MLE problem. Price space discretized into N = 5 intervals. Rate of time preference δ = 0.975. Go Back

58/ 39

Introduction

59/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

The above equation does not account for serial correlation in : If the importer has some characterstic that makes them prefer exporter x in both periods, this will show up as high switching cost.

Reduced form check: The correlation of lagged quality λx,t−1 on exporter choice xt . Not related to current profits, but if correlated with future choice, then can augment the error term for serial correlation.

Introduction

59/ 39

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Conclusion

The above equation does not account for serial correlation in : If the importer has some characterstic that makes them prefer exporter x in both periods, this will show up as high switching cost.

Reduced form check: The correlation of lagged quality λx,t−1 on exporter choice xt . Not related to current profits, but if correlated with future choice, then can augment the error term for serial correlation.  m m m πm t (xt , β) + x,t = βp E ln px,t + ξλx,t m m m −βx 1{xtm 6= xt−1 } − βc 1{ctm 6= ct−1 } + αxm + νx,t

Estimating α with an average of 35 partners means a large increase in the state variables. Can estimate a ‘limited memory” version where α is not observed until the match is made (α is importer-exporter-time specific). Go Back

Introduction

Data

Model

Implementation

Results

Counterfactuals

Table: Counterfactual Results (I) βx = Original βx ↓ 50% βx ↓ 100% Sample βc ↓ 50% βc = βc ↓ 100% Price Index Staying City Stay Go Back

60/ 39

Conclusion

βx ↑ 200% βc ↑ 200%

-

-12.50%

-15.20%

-7.37%

+7.62%

57% 75%

18% 43%

8% 47%

31% 46%

90% 93%

It's Not You, It's Me: Breakups in US-China Trade ...

Aug 7, 2014 - year-to-year (average of 30 choices in an HS10 product). .... HS10 product and year fixed effects included. ..... HS 847130, Laptop Computers.

3MB Sizes 0 Downloads 110 Views

Recommend Documents

“It's Not You, It's Me”: Breakups in US-China Trade ...
Apr 19, 2016 - 4% of total imports from China would flow back to a theoretical U.S. supplier that charged ...... present discounted stream of expected profits.

Its not a box activity (Isabel).pdf
Illustrations © 2007 by Antoinette Portis Permission to reproduce and distribute this page has been granted by the copyright holder, HarperCollins Publishers. All rights reserved. www.harpercollinschildrens.com. You're invited to a B.Y.O.B.* event i

pdf-76\its-me-edward-wayne-edwards-the-serial-killer-you-never ...
Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. pdf-76\its-me-edward-wayne-edwards-the-serial-killer-you-never-heard-of-by-john-a-cameron.pdf.

teach-me-how-its-done-1.pdf
Page 2 of 6. long brown hair. “Mr. Jones! I'm fine, really,” she said. Eddie didn't believe it. “Please, call me Eddie. Get in the car, I'll give you a ride home.”.

Life in its Pure Essence.pdf
Life in its Pure Essence.pdf. Life in its Pure Essence.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Life in its Pure Essence.pdf. Page 1 of 3.

Japan: Finding Its Way
In spite of more than a century of prayer and the efforts of dedicated missionaries and national Christians, the soil for the. Gospel in Japan remains difficult.

Japan: Finding Its Way
Page 1 ... church even if we waited for 10 years. The. Network encouraged us to step fan/vard and succeed. " ... victims who create jewelry from broken pottery.

ITS/2009/11/1225
Nov 30, 2009 - Note : The design, schematic and physical layout is similar to the above except the difference of plug sockets 18 more than the classroom ...

PDF Download The City in History: Its Origins, Its ...
... Mumford Lewis The city s development from ancient times to the modern age ... Its Prospects ,ebook design The City in History: Its Origins, Its Transformations, ... Its Origins, Its Transformations, and Its Prospects ,ebook reader software The ..

pdf-1444\mercury-poisoning-its-not-in-our-heads-anymore ...
... apps below to open or edit this item. pdf-1444\mercury-poisoning-its-not-in-our-heads-anym ... rue-stories-symptoms-and-treatments-by-jean-shaw.pdf.

Neural Network Toolbox - Share ITS
are used, in this supervised learning, to train a network. Batch training of a network proceeds by making weight and bias changes based on an entire set (batch) of input vectors. Incremental training changes the weights and biases of a network as nee