Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 45, No. 9, 1513–1525, October 2009

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes in Emerging Markets Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

ALBERTO CHONG* & GIANMARCO LEON** *Inter-American Development Bank, Washington DC, USA, **University of California, USA

Final version received October 2008

ABSTRACT A recent large firm-level dataset is analysed to compare labour indicators of privatised, private, and public firms around the world, in particular differences relating to wages, benefits, labour composition, education and training, unionisation, and quality of management. We find that labour productivity and the ratio of permanent to temporary workers increase after privatisation.

I. Introduction Empirical evidence suggests that labour productivity tends to rise following privatisation, but the reasons for this are unclear. Critics of privatisation argue that employment reductions are the crucial means of driving up productivity, and thus, profitability. While the scant available evidence indicates that labour cost reductions are a source of the gains after privatisation, these savings explain less than half of the higher observed profitability (La Porta and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, 1999). Increasing labour productivity may not necessarily involve job cuts exclusively, and even when it does there may be other productivity enhancing measures to be taken also, as labour cost reductions may also come from lower wages and benefits.1 Whereas most of the literature on the impact of privatisation focuses on firm performance (Megginson and Netter, 2001; Chong and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, 2005; Cook and Uchida, 2008) there is practically no research on the link between privatisation and labour outcomes, in particular, from a cross-country perspective. In fact, while most of the very few existing studies on labour outcomes after privatisation focus on wages and the quality of the managers there are several critical issues that remain unanswered. For example, the rise in the average wage depends on the composition of the dismissed workers. If the dismissed workers were those with Correspondence Address: Alberto Chong, Research Department, Inter-American Development Bank, 1300 New York Ave., NW, Washington, DC 20577, USA. Email: [email protected] An Online Appendix is available for this article which can be accessed via the online version of the journal available at www.informaworld.com/fjds ISSN 0022-0388 Print/1743-9140 Online/09/091513-13 ª 2009 Taylor & Francis DOI: 10.1080/00220380902935899

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

1514 A. Chong & G. Leon fewer qualifications, and lower wages, the average wage will go up. However, if skilled workers are more likely to be dismissed average wages (for this reason) should fall. Blue-collar workers actually appear to fare better than their white-collar counterparts; some recent evidence indicates that it cannot be concluded that unskilled workers fared worse than skilled labour as a result of privatisation (Chong and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, 2006). Thus, this paper offers a more detailed analysis on labour effects of privatisation not only in terms of composition, but also in regards to education and training, and unionisation. The implications of labour effects for profits are not clear-cut. The fraction of profitability changes that may be attributed to labour cost savings encompasses the lower costs stemming from layoffs and the higher costs from wage increases for the remaining workers. There is evidence that pay differentials tend to increase, partly in response to labour market conditions and especially to attract and provide incentives in the recruitment and retention of both experienced and skilled professionals and managers (World Bank, 2005). At the same time, it is said that privatisation tends to produce ‘flatter’ organisations, removing layers of middle management as labour contracts tend to be simplified, and often allowing managers to deploy workers in more flexible ways. Workers and unions are generally concerned that a focus on profit and financial performance by the private operator, following privatisation, will lead to deterioration of working conditions because of unwarranted intensification of work following privatisation, which may be expected in the context of increasing productivity. Thus, the impact on working hours may involve increasing them (World Bank, 2005). Additionally, there may be an erosion of national level collective bargaining, with a shift to enterprise level bargaining or individual pay determination, a trend intensified by the increased use of sub-contractors. Finally, pay systems may change after privatisation, as new managers will seek to relate earnings more directly to productivity performance. Privatisation may have compositional effects on the labour force and hurt unskilled workers disproportionately (World Bank, 2005). In this paper we focus on a broad set of labour outcomes in privatised firms for a very large cross-section of firms mostly from emerging markets around the world, and analyse the differences between private, public and privatised firms. In particular, we study whether differences, if any, are structural and whether convergence occurs (that is, do privatised firms converge to the outcomes observed in private firms). The specific focus is on wages, benefits, labour composition, education and training, unionisation, and quality of management.2 While there is some theoretical work on the link between privatisation and labour outcomes (Haskel and Szymansky, 1992) to our knowledge this is the first crosssection paper at the firm level that deals with this issue that provides empirical evidence in a systematic manner.3 Furthermore, the country-specific empirical evidence available is limited and focuses almost exclusively on the impact on employment and wages of specific sectors. For instance, Monteiro (2003) argues that wages of the workers in the Portuguese banking sector follow a non-monotonic pattern after privatisation: at first wages decrease, but later they recover and converge to the private sector level. Similarly, Chong et al. (2008) find that in Peru initially there is a negative effect of privatisation on wages, but later they recover to

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes 1515 private sector levels. They also find that various measures of quality of the work environment converge toward the standards of the private sector.4 Djankov and Murrell (2002) argue that the literature on the effects of changes in managers suffers from endogeneity with respect to privatisation as new owners pick new managers, and the effect of management change is confounded with ownership change, especially when the new owners themselves are the new managers. For example, the retail shops studied in Barberis et al. (1996) are in many cases manager-owned. Even for midsize and larger enterprises, managers may be also owners (Kuznetsov et al., 2002) and hence lose their jobs when there is ownership change. According to Classens and Djankov (1999) the privatisation process in the Czech Republic prevented incumbent managers from obtaining ownership. Thus, management changes were separated from ownership change. Labour productivity growth increases by 4.2 per cent with the appointment of a new manager in privatised enterprises. The appointment of new managers in state-owned enterprises yields a 3.5 per cent increase in labour productivity growth. Similarly, Frydman et al. (1999) use a sample of state-owned and newly privatised enterprises in the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland to study management turnover and its effect on the annual rate of revenue growth during the period 1991 to 1993. They show that the turnover rate was high as almost two thirds of managers left. In state-owned enterprises, management turnover is statistically insignificant but in privatised enterprises the effect is large at about 18 per cent. For the case of Ukraine, Warzynski (2001) finds that management turnover does not affect the change in productivity in state-owned enterprises, but has a small positive effect in privatised enterprises. Djankov and Murrell (2002) find that manager incentives and turnover, considered together, are an important determinant of restructuring. Separately, manager turnover and manager incentives also have significant effects on restructuring. There is also relevant literature at the country level for transition economies on the role of managers on productivity changes during privatisation. Groves et al. (1995) use a sample of Chinese state-owned enterprises (SOEs) to investigate the link between manager turnover and productivity growth, and find that the economic benefit of replacing bad managers is high as new managers bring about a 16 per cent increase in labour productivity.5 Although these were public sector firms, the Communist Party exercised control over pay and promotion so incentives for managers were imposed (by the Party rather than the market), even if Party members were more likely to get jobs and received a pay premium. Although China has not implemented privatisation as conventionally defined, since the time of the study there has been considerable reform: the private sector has increased and SOEs are more market-oriented, so that managers have greater autonomy for example. Nevertheless, the wage premium from Communist Party membership has increased, especially for less skilled workers, in line with a general increase in pay differentials (Appleton et al., 2009). The tendency for pay differentials to increase can weaken any link between privatisation and labour productivity. The paper is organised as follows. The next section describes the data employed, namely recently released firm data from the World Bank for a large number of countries. The third section provides our empirical analysis. The fourth section studies convergence patterns between privatised and private firms. The fifth section

1516 A. Chong & G. Leon focuses on the role of institutions. Finally, the sixth section summarises and concludes.

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

II. Data Our main data source is the Productivity and Investment Climate survey from World Bank (2006). This comprehensive firm-level survey covers several thousand business establishments in about 75 countries around the world; the main objective of this survey was to provide governments and private sector agents with quantitative data to allow an adequate assessment of the business environment and firm performance in an internationally comparable data set. The main focus of the survey is on the microeconomic and structural dimensions of the business environment in a country. Thus, the surveys provide considerable detail on factors related to the effective functioning of product markets, financial and non-financial factor markets, and infrastructure services, including weaknesses in the legal, regulatory, and institutional frameworks. The data also include questions on the characteristics of the business and the investment climate in which it operates including: general information about the firm, such as ownership, activities, location, sales and supplies, investment climate constraints; infrastructure and services. With respect to labour relations the survey includes wages, compensations, the skills of workers, the status and training; availability of skills; unionisation, business–government relations and several others. Our most complete sample includes 35,262 firms for 75 countries, with many African, Latin American and Eastern European countries (see Table 1), which comprise the regions where privatisation was pursued more actively.6 Some five per cent of the interviewed firms were involved in a privatisation process (about the same percentage are state owned firms). While some countries have privatised much more

Table 1. Distribution of firms in sample by ownership status, industrial sector, and region Private

Industrial sector Manufacturing Services Agro industry Construction Other Total Region Africa East Asia Pacific Europe and Central Asia Latin America and the Caribbean Middle East and North Africa South Asia Total

Privatised

Government

Total

%

No.

%

No.

%

No.

%

No.

91.2 83.5 86.3 81.7 69.1 89.0

23292 6237 466 1292 96 31383

4.4 5.8 5.0 9.4 19.4 5.0

1124 432 27 148 27 1758

4.4 10.7 8.7 8.9 11.5 6.0

1120 797 47 141 16 2121

72.4 21.2 1.5 4.5 0.4 100.0

25536 7466 540 1581 139 35262

89.4 84.8 82.0 99.0

2450 6291 9796 4933

5.5 2.2 10.8 0.6

152 165 1291 31

5.0 12.9 7.2 0.4

138 960 857 19

7.8 21.0 33.9 14.1

2740 7416 11944 4983

96.8 96.7 89.0

3039 4874 31383

0.8 1.9 5.0

25 94 1758

2.4 1.4 6.0

76 71 2121

8.9 14.3 100.0

3140 5039 35262

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes 1517 than others, the overall numbers are consistent with the percentages of privatised firms around the world when using other sources (World Bank, 2006). The Online Appendix provides further detail, including a full definition of variables, mean values and correlation measures among the variables employed. III. Empirical Approach

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

In order to study the possible effect of privatisation on a relatively wide variety of labour outcomes our empirical analysis is based on a parsimonious but reasonably comprehensive approach. We estimate an empirical specification of the form: yijkt ¼ aijkt þ b1 privijkt þ b2 privatijkt þ b2 salesijkt þ uj þ nk þ eijkt

ð1Þ

where yijkt is an outcome variable of firm i, belonging to industry k, in country j, interviewed in year t. In this context, privijkt (private) and privatijkt (privatised) are our variables of interest. The former is defined as a dummy variable which takes the value of one when the firm’s largest shareholder is an individual, family, domestic company, foreign company, bank, investment fund, the managers, or the employees of the firm. On the other hand, a privatised firm is defined as one that used to be owned by the government at some point but that at the time of the survey the largest shareholder was a private firm, where such a firm is defined as above. Governmentowned enterprises are used as the base category. The variable salesijkt is the natural logarithm of the total sales during the last fiscal year in real thousand dollars, to control for the effects of the size of the firm on labour outcomes.7 We also include country, industry, and year fixed effects, which are represented by the terms uj, vk and mt, respectively, and eijkt is an error term. Unlike other firm-level surveys, the Investment Climate dataset includes an industry categorisation based on the threedigit ISIC codes.8 As mentioned above, this allows us to control for effects due to particular industry structures or productivity differences across industries. The case of the natural monopolies in public services provides a good example of the need to control for particular industry effects. As is well known, when private firms take care of public utilities, regulatory issues are crucial as the lack of competitors and the regulatory burden may have an impact on prices and the make up on the contractual arrangements of the factors of production, in particular, human capital. Furthermore, the performance of privatised utilities tends to differ from privatised firms in other sectors (Cook and Uchida, 2008). It may be argued that endogeneity poses a problem in the empirical approach of this paper. For example, the existence of any labour streamlining activity may signal that the firm is in bad shape. The privatisation decision of a firm that is being streamlined may be linked not to the streamlining activities themselves, but because such reform is pursued precisely when firms are inefficient and unprofitable in the first place. If this effect is not controlled for, an incorrect inference that labourrestructuring ‘causes’ (or ‘precedes’) privatisation could be drawn. A particular example is when governments try to restructure the labour force of state-owned enterprises before sale in order to raise the privatisation price. The resulting sign on privatisation may be a reflection that firms in bad shape are downsizing labour. For instance, if the unobservable characteristics of a firm are positively correlated with

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

1518 A. Chong & G. Leon the presence of strong unions and frequent strikes, the government may be particularly interested in reducing union power. Such endogeneity does not appear to be of great concern in this paper for several reasons. In most cases in our sample, privatisation occurred more than 10 years before the firm was surveyed (the average number of years after privatisation that the survey was taken is 9.7 years, see Online Appendix Table A2). Furthermore, privatisation processes are typically embedded in the context of a much larger reform process; the decision to privatise may not depend on particular characteristics of a firm, but rather on a country-level political decision. In this context, it is reasonable to believe that labour outcomes, or workers’ characteristics, will not affect the decision to pursue privatisation. This is particularly true in emerging markets where most of the privatisation processes pursued by governments have been at a broad national level and, essentially in all cases, the decision to privatise has come from an overriding political decision in the context of structural reforms (Chong and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, 2005). Given the fact that our sample size consists of mostly emerging markets we believe the argument above is reasonably solid.9 Even under the assumption that the endogeneity concern raised above is relevant, most of the labour variables employed as dependent variables are very unlikely to be affected. IV. Findings Table 2 shows results when using our benchmark specification (1) for a broad set of labour outcomes. In the first column we show the set of labour outcomes used as dependent variables, while the remaining columns report the estimated coefficients of the independent variables. Our variables of interest are the dummies for both private and privatised firms, with government-owned enterprises as the base (omitted) category. In line with the recent literature surveys (Megginson and Netter, 2001; Djankov and Murrell, 2002; Chong and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, 2005), we find evidence of improved performance in both private and privatised firms in terms of productivity, which is significantly higher than that of state-owned firms. Interestingly, when testing the differences in labour productivity, as measured by the ratio of total wages and compensations to total gross sales, we find a statistically significant difference between firms. Interestingly, labour productivity of permanent workers differs by type of firm, whereas the productivity of temporary workers is similar across firms. That is, for a given level of wages and compensations to permanent workers, total sales and benefits are higher in both private and privatised firms, when compared to the state-owned enterprises. Notice that the productivity of permanent workers appears to be higher in private firms than in privatised ones, which confirms previous findings in the literature. However, this result does not hold in the case of temporary workers. The liberalisation of labour markets and the simplification of contracts in developing countries provided incentives for firms to attract the most experienced and skilled workers, while the low skilled tasks were – in most cases – performed by temporary workers. The difference in the incentive schemes in private and privatised firms for temporary and permanent workers may explain our findings.

(0.102) (0.049) (0.091) (0.113)

70.992 (1.231)

0.412 (0.770) 0.498 (71.312)

1.139 (1.933) 71.971 (1.970)

0.081 (0.028)***

0.043 0.043 0.098 0.132

70.078 (0.018)*** 70.008 (0.016)

Private

(0.120) (0.102) (0.105)*** (0.155)

2.111 (1.161)*

5.588 (0.930)*** 75.481 (1.210)***

71.204 (1.556) 73.329 (1.485)**

0.064 (0.024)**

0.034 70.063 0.308 0.082

70.032 (0.014)** 0.001 (0.015)

Privatised

(0.017)*** (0.018)*** (0.017)*** (0.018)***

0.345 (0.073)***

70.801 (0.189)*** 0.968 (0.204)***

2.732 (0.471)*** 1.783 (0.314)***

70.004 (0.002)**

0.061 0.107 0.159 0.068

70.034 (0.005)*** 70.010 (0.002)***

Log(Sales)

17839

34751 24779

15518 11233

24196

2619 9873 6955 3939

15595 4021

Obs.

0.02

0.33 0.13

0.03 0.02

0.08

0.32 0.58 0.42 0.79

0.27 0.09

R2

Note: The dependent variables are shown in the first column, as the control and interest variables are shown in the next columns. All results come from country fixed effects regressions using industry and year dummies. We also control for the log of total sales in the previous fiscal year. Heteroskedasticy robust standard errors are corrected for clusters at the industry and country levels in all cases (shown in parentheses). *significant at 10 per cent; **significant at 5 per cent; ***significant at 1 per cent.

Productivity Total wages and comp. (perm. workers)/Total sales Total wages and comp. (temp. workers)/Total sales Average wages Log(Average wages and compensations temp. workers) Log(Average wages perm. workers) Log(Average wages perm. workers (managers)) Log(Average wages perm. workers (prod. workers)) Composition of the workforce Temp. workers/Perm. workers Training % perm. skilled emp. received training % perm. unskilled emp. who received training Education of the workforce % of workforce with fewer than 12 yrs. educ. % of workforce with more than 12 yrs. educ. Quality of the top manager Years of exp. of the top manager in the field

Dependent variables

Independent variables

Table 2. Does privatisation make a difference in labour outcomes?

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes 1519

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

1520 A. Chong & G. Leon Somewhat surprisingly, the observed difference in labour productivity between permanent workers is not reflected in average wages. In fact, when focusing our analysis on the wage structure, it is clear that, on average, privatised firms tend to pay higher wages to their managerial staff than government owned and private firms, whereas there are no significant differences in the average wages to unskilled or production workers. It is believed that pay differentials tend to increase when privatisation processes take place, partly in response to labour market conditions and especially because privatised firms try to attract and provide incentives in the recruitment and retention of both experienced and skilled professionals and managers (Kikeri, 1999; World Bank, 2005). First, the pay-scale constraints imposed by public sector employment laws are relaxed; and second, privatised firms tend to invest more widely in the managerial sector, in order to restructure the firm and catch up with organisational structures of the private sector.10 It is argued by critics that privatisation brings a significant reduction in the number of workers, as well as job security (Feffer, 2005). The main argument is that the new jobs in privatised firms are offered mostly through temporary contracts, and this would be particularly true in the case of unskilled workers. This type of contract tends to be more flexible in terms of firing and hiring, but also implies a significantly lower burden for the firm in terms of social protection and effective compensations to workers. We further analyse this issue by using the ratio of temporary to total workers as a dependent variable. The results in Table 2 show that both private and privatised firms take more advantage of labour liberalisation than the public sector, hiring significantly more temporary workers as a proportion of total employment. However, privatised firms are constrained in their hiring processes to the extent that they inherit labour contracts from the public companies (changing these would be difficult and/or slow). This restriction is illustrated by the magnitude of the coefficients found, which show that private firms have, on average, a higher proportion of temporary workers. There are also some slight differences in the proportion of permanent skilled and unskilled workers who receive job training. While we don’t find any differences in the proportion of skilled workers who receive job training, privatised and private firms train a smaller proportion of their unskilled workers when compared with stateowned enterprises. It has been claimed that private companies groom skilled workers for managerial positions, while lower skilled tasks tend to be left to temporary workers (Chong and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, 2005), for whom training is assumed by the workers themselves or non existent. As expected, government-owned firms have much higher unionisation rates than private and privatised firms (in the case of privatised firms the coefficients are statistically insignificant). This may be explained by the fact that in most cases privatised firms still have to honour some contracts and labour structures from the time they were state-owned. Even though unionisation rates differ among types of firms, there are no noticeable effects for the number of days of production lost due to strikes or civil unrest. These results are explained mostly by the political trends in developing countries, where labour liberalisation drove down unionisation rates and labour protests were addressed through official channels, rather than in the streets.11 When it comes to the educational level of the labour force, we find some substantial differences among type of firm. Although the workforce composition

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes 1521 within privatised firms is skewed towards workers with a lower educational level we also find that the top managers in privatised firms have significantly more work experience. This reinforces the conventional wisdom that privatised firms attract the most capable managerial staff in order to enhance the production processes and be able to compete with the private sector. The results presented in this section are robust to the inclusion of some labour law proxies that may affect the particular environment of certain firms. Even though we control for country and industry fixed effects, certain labour laws may have firmspecific effects (such as more frequent visits of inspectors). Online Appendix Tables C1 and C2 include two additional variables to allow for this; the degree to which firms perceive that labour law represents a constraint to business, and whether the labour inspector or social security inspector has required illegal payments. The results in Table 2 hold even after the inclusion of these variables; moreover, they are almost never statistically significant, suggesting that most of the variation in labour laws is captured by the country and industry level fixed effects. V. Convergence Between Private and Privatised Firms Why are there any differences between privatised and private firms if they both produce under the same set of rules and incentives? A plausible explanation is that time matters. Privatised firms cannot be transformed from one day to the next. There may be an adjustment period after which full convergence occurs (Chong et al., 2008). To test for this in our benchmark specification in (1), we replace the dummy for privatised firms by another explanatory variable that captures the number of years since the state-owned enterprise became private.12 Results are shown in Table 3. The interpretation of the coefficients is straightforward. If we obtain the same sign for both the coefficient on the private firm dummy and the number of years since privatisation occurred a convergence pattern is present. If both are positive, private firms have a higher value than SOEs and the value for privatised firms increases with years since privatisation (presumably to eventually converge with private firms). A similar argument applies if both are negative. We do not find evidence of convergence for labour productivity of permanent or temporary workers. For wage composition, we find no statistically significant differences between private, privatised or state-owned firms in terms of wages and compensations to permanent and temporary workers. A similar finding holds for managerial pay, so there is no evidence of convergence. In the case of the ratio of the number of temporary to permanent workers, we find convergence; the coefficients on private firms and years since privatisation are positive and significant. This is consistent with the argument stated above that most of the differences in labour outcomes are observed because privatised firms still may have to comply with labour contracts inherited from the time when the firm was state owned. As time goes by and these workers leave the firm, the workforce composition of privatised firms will tend to converge towards the one observed in the private sector. We also find that privatised firms offer less training to their unskilled workers, compared to both state-owned and private sector firms. Interestingly, this gap tends to increase with years since privatisation. This result may give credence to the commonly held view that, at least in this aspect, privatisation tends to be less

1522 A. Chong & G. Leon Table 3. Do privatised firms converge with the firms in the private sector? Independent variables

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

Dependent variables Productivity Total wages and comp. (perm. workers)/Total sales Total wages and comp. (temp. workers)/Total sales Average wages Log(Average wages and compensations temp. workers) Log(Average wages perm. workers) Log(Average wages perm. workers (managers)) Log(Average wages perm. workers (prod. workers)) Composition of the workforce Temp. workers/Perm. workers Training % perm. skilled emp. received training % perm. unskilled emp. who received training Education of the workforce % of workforce with fewer than 12 yrs. educ. % of workforce with more than 12 yrs. educ. Quality of the top manager Years of exp. of the top manager in the field

Private

Time since privatisation

Obs.

R2

70.062 (0.014)*** 70.001 (0.001)

12427 0.26

70.007 (0.013)

0.000 (0.001)

4008

0.09

0.023 (0.074)

0.005 (0.006)

2611

0.32

0.054 (0.047) 70.018 (0.114)

70.004 (0.008) 0.005 (0.009)

9861 6950

0.58 0.42

0.085 (0.101)

0.003 (0.009)

3933

0.79

0.005 (0.002)**

24160 0.08

0.07 (0.028)** 1.258 (1.980) 71.496 (1.966)

70.806 (0.850) 2.031 (1.180)*

71.723 (1.129)

70.113 (0.160)

15494 0.03

70.289 (0.169)*

11211 0.02

0.361 (0.086)*** 34685 0.33 70.361 (0.095)*** 24746 0.13

0.034 (0.072)

17810 0.02

Notes: The dependent variables are shown in the first column, as the control and interest variables are shown in the next columns. All results come from country fixed effects regressions using industry and year dummies, we also control for the log of total sales in the previous fiscal year. Heteroskedasticy robust standard errors are corrected for clusters at the industry and country levels in all cases (shown in parentheses). *significant at 10 per cent; **significant at 5 per cent; ***significant at 1 per cent.

beneficial to the more vulnerable workers, as typically they are unskilled. However, it is unclear if this is actually the case, as we do not have information on workers that move from a temporary to permanent status. Finally, in terms of the educational levels of the workforce employed, we find divergence rather than convergence. Privatised firms tend to have more uneducated workers and fewer employees with more than 12 years of formal education, while private firms seem to concentrate on relatively highly educated workers. The divergence may occur because of technological differences between types of firms. Human capital requirements may be different for newly privatised firms as machinery and equipment for such firms are typically less capital

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes 1523 intensive, due to the low levels of investment in technology in the public sector, thus the changes in the demand for skilled workers may still be gradual. This is consistent with some previous findings for Latin America (Chong and Lo´pez-deSilanes, 2005). Presumably, privatised and private firms competing in the same market will have similar production technologies, and face a similar demand. Hence, according to standard economic theory, they should behave in a similar way, or in any case converge to the same production behaviour in the long run. Nevertheless, we still observe that there are some areas where private and privatised firms still seem to differ systematically, or even diverge in time. These divergences can only be explained by factors that limit or restrict the behaviour of privatised firms relative to private firms, such as differences in the regulatory or institutional environment in the country. Appendix D (online) reports estimates including a measure of ‘Rule of law’ to capture the institutional environment; there is some evidence that labour markets are more flexible, and convergence more likely, in countries that score higher for the quality of the institutional environment. VI. Summary and Conclusions In this paper we study the link between privatisation and a broad set of labour outcomes in a cross-section of firms for several emerging markets around the world. While some studies have focused on the impact of privatisation on employment, and to a much lesser extent wages, these tend to focus on one specific country and in several cases yield somewhat contradictory results that stress the need for further empirical work on a largely unexplored question. We focus on observed labour differences between private, public and privatised firms for a very large number of firms in many countries, and consider whether privatised firms converge towards the levels in private firms (with tentative results on how the institutional environment may affect convergence). The particular focus is on wages, benefits, labour composition, education and training, unionisation and quality of management. We find that while labour productivity increases after privatisation, the ratio of permanent workers to temporary workers decreases, and that convergence toward the average labour outcome depends in some degree on the quality of the institutions, namely, the Rule of law. This is particularly true in the case of the ratio of temporary workers to permanent workers, the education of the workforce, and the average wages and compensations of temporary workers. Overall our results show that privatisation does not necessarily benefit particular groups in the society, as critics argue. Yet, the patterns followed by privatised firms do show that the incentive schemes provided to the private sector, along with labour deregulation, mostly hurt unskilled workers, who receive less compensation and training, as they end up being hired as temporary workers. This suggests that the gains in productivity due to privatisation should be redistributed, especially trying to provide technical training to the workforce. Finally, improvements in the institutional framework, especially in areas related to securing property rights, may enhance the convergence between private and privatised firms. Clearly, more research is needed on this.

1524 A. Chong & G. Leon Acknowledgement Cesar Calderon, Hugo N˜opo, Anna Serrichio, Ma´ximo Torero, and Luisa Zanforlin, provided valuable comments and suggestions. The findings and interpretations in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Inter-American Development Bank or its corresponding executive directors. The standard disclaimer applies.

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

Notes 1. Chong and Lo´pez-de-Silanes (2006) provide evidence that for some Latin American countries real and industry-adjusted wages of workers in privatised firms increased after privatisation. Both real and industry-adjusted wages for the median firm increased by about 100 per cent in Mexico and Peru; Bolivia enjoyed real wage increases of almost 110 per cent, while in Argentina the industry-adjusted increase was about 70 per cent. Colombia shows the smallest increase, but even in this case workers in privatised firms increased their wages more than others in the private sector. 2. We are not able to make a rigorous impact evaluation of workers after privatisation, as we do not have pre- and post-privatisation data but only information on workers who stayed in firms after privatisation. 3. Haskel and Szymansky (1992) develop a theoretical model in which the objective function of the privatised firm focuses on profit maximisation and the minimisation of the union’s bargaining power. Their model predicts convergence between the wages in the privatised firms and other private firms. 4. Other relevant studies on wages and employment are Tansel (1998) who uses retrospective data for Turkey; Galiani and Sturzenegger (2008) who focus on one single firm in Argentina; Haskel and Syzmansky (1993) on the United Kingdom, and Brown et al. (2006) on Ukraine. 5. Poorly performing firms are more likely to have a new manager selected by ‘auction’ and such managers are required to post a higher security deposit and are subject to more frequent performance reviews. The incidence of turnover during the sample period of 1980 to 1989 is very high as only 11 per cent of managers in place in 1980 remained managers by the end of the period, and almost half of managers were appointed after 1985. 6. The complete list of countries, and the number of firms interviewed in each country are detailed in the Online Appendix. 7. In alternative specifications we normalised this variable using number of workers. The results are very similar and are available from the authors upon request. 8. Overall, our sample includes observations for the following industries (the number of firms in the industry in parentheses): Textiles (2886), Leather (843), Garments (4342), Agro industry (499), Food (3474), Beverages (837), Metals and machinery (3497), Electronics (1414), Chemicals and pharmaceutics (2043), Construction (1523), Wood and furniture (2169), Non-metallic and plastic materials (1679), Paper (590), Sport goods (44), IT services (670), Other manufacturing (490), Telecommunications (164), Accounting and finance (230), Advertising and marketing (690), Other services (933), Retail and wholesale trade (2654), Hotels and restaurants (761), Transport (720), Real estate and rental services (433), Mining and quarrying (114), Auto and auto components (945), Other transport equipment (76), Other unclassified (31). 9. When excluding the four countries that are not emerging market economies (Spain, Portugal, Korea, and Ireland) and replicating all the exercises performed in this paper, the results do not change. 10. This finding is partly consistent with the conventional wisdom that the less qualified workers tend to be losers in privatisation processes. For a number of reasons (for example, political) state-owned enterprises tend to pay wages and benefits in excess of marginal productivity. In fact, this is particularly true for unskilled workers (Kikeri, 1999). Privatisation may be simply adjusting payment with marginal productivity. 11. These results are not shown in the tables for space reasons, but are available upon request to the authors. 12. In our sample we do not have privatised firms that become state-owned firms again.

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes 1525

Downloaded by [University of California, Berkeley] at 08:49 14 June 2012

References Appleton, S., Knight, J., Song, L. and Xia, Q. (2009) The economics of Communist Party membership: the curious case of rising numbers and wage premium during China’s transition. Journal of Development Studies, 45(2), pp. 256–275. Barberis, Nicholas, Boycko, Maxim, Shleifer, Andrei and Tsukanova, Natalia (1996) How does privatization work? Evidence from the Russian shops. Journal of Political Economy, 104(4), pp. 764–790. Brown, David, Earle, John and Vakhitov, Vladimir (2006) Wages, layoffs, and privatization: evidence from Ukraine. Journal of Comparative Economics, 34(2), pp. 272–294. Chong, Alberto and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, Florencio (eds.) (2005). Privatization in Latin America: Myths and Reality (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press). Chong, Alberto and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, Florencio (2006) Privatization, labor policies, and rehiring around the world. Manuscript, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington DC. Chong, Alberto, Lo´pez-de-Silanes, Florencio and Torero, Maximo (2008) Back to reality: what happens to workers after privatization? Manuscript, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington DC. Classens, Stijn and Djankov, Simeon (1999) Enterprise performance and management turnover in the Czech Republic. European Economic Review, 43, pp. 1115–1124. Cook, P. and Uchida, Y. (2008) The performance of privatised enterprises in developing countries. Journal of Development Studies, 44(9), pp. 1342–1353. Djankov, Simeon and Murrell, Peter (2002) Enterprise restructuring in transition: a quantitative survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(3), pp. 739–792. Fallick, Bruce (1995) A review of the recent empirical literature on displaced workers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 50(1), pp. 5–16. Feffer, John (2005) Living in Hope: People Challenging Globalization (Philadelphia, PA: American Friends Service Committee). Frydman, Roman, Gray, Cheryl, Hessel, Marek and Rapaczynski, Andrej (1999) When does privatization work? The impact of private ownership on corporate performance in the transition economies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4), pp. 1153–1191. Galiani, Sebastian and Sturzenegger, Federico (2008) The impact of privatization on the earnings of restructured workers evidence from the oil industry. Journal of Labor Research, 29, pp. 162–176. Groves, Theodore, Hong, Yongmiao, McMillan, John and Naughton, Barry (1995) Autonomy and incentives in Chinese state enterprises. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(1), pp. 183–209. Haskel, Jonathan and Szymansky, Stefan (1992) A bargaining theory of privatization. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 63(2), pp. 207–227. Haskel, Jonathan and Szymansky, Stefan (1993) Privatization, liberalization, wages and employment: theory and evidence for the UK. Economica, 3, pp. 161–182. Kikeri, Sunita (1999) Labor redundancies and privatization: what should governments do? Public Policy for the Private Sector. Note No. 174. The World Bank Group; Finance, Private Sector, and Infrastructure Network, Washington DC. Kuznetsov, Boris, Mangiarotti, Giovanni and Schaffer, Mark (2002) Insider ownership and economic performance of Russian firms. Center for Economic Research Transition, Harriot-Watt University, Edinburgh. La Porta, Rafael and Lo´pez-de-Silanes, Florencio (1999) The benefits of privatization: evidence from Mexico. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4), pp. 1193–1242. Megginson, William and Netter, Jeffry (2001) From state to market: a survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(2), pp. 321–389. Monteiro, Natalia (2003) The impact of privatization on wages: evidence from the Portuguese banking industry, NIPE WP 11/04. Tansel, Aysit (1998) Workers displaced due to privatization in Turkey: before versus after displacement. METU Studies in Development, 25(4), pp. 625–647. Warzynski, Frederic (2001) The complementarity of reforms: evidence from a survey of Ukrainian firms. LICOS Centre for Transition Economics, Catholic University Leuven. World Bank (2005) PPIF Labor Toolkit (Washington, DC: The World Bank). World Bank (2006) World Development Report 2006 (New York: Oxford University Press).

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes in Emerging ...

For example, the rise in the average wage depends on .... (1999) use a sample of state-owned and newly privatised enterprises ..... Acknowledgement.

131KB Sizes 1 Downloads 148 Views

Recommend Documents

Privatised Firms and Labour Outcomes in Emerging ...
For example, the rise in the average wage depends on ... Email: [email protected] .... (1999) use a sample of state-owned and newly privatised enterprises ..... Telecommunications (164), Accounting and finance (230), Advertising and ...

Self-Selection and Screening in Law Firms
Dec 3, 2007 - Workers with high effort costs do not find the investment worthwhile, ...... significant lower profit level when firms switch from one track to two ...

TRENDS IN COHABITATION OUTCOMES: COMPOSITIONAL ...
Jan 10, 2012 - 39.2. Some college. 15.7. 15.8. 19.0. 21.9. 24.9. 27.3. 21.2. College or more. 13.2. 13.6. 15.9. 18.2. 19.1. 20.1. 17.1. Mother had teen birth. 16.6.

TNPSC Labour Officer in the Tamil Nadu Labour Service Question and ...
TNPSC Labour Officer in the Tamil Nadu Labour Service Question and Answer 10.11.2012.pdf. TNPSC Labour Officer in the Tamil Nadu Labour Service ...

TRENDS IN COHABITATION OUTCOMES: COMPOSITIONAL ...
Jan 10, 2012 - The data are cross-sectional but contain a detailed retrospective ... To analyze change over time, I created six cohabitation cohorts: 1980-1984, ..... Qualitative evidence also shows that the exact start and end dates of.

Emerging and Re-emerging Infectious Disease and Soil Transmitted ...
... a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Emerging and Re-emerging Infectious Disease and Soil Transmitted Helminths Program.pdf. Emerging and Re-emerging I

Diploma in Labour Laws and Welfare.pdf
a) Notional extension of employer's premises. b) Types of ... d) Retrenchment and Lay-off. ... Displaying Diploma in Labour Laws and Welfare.pdf. Page 1 of 4.

Synchronising Deregulation in Product and Labour ...
integration and labour market regulation that determines the degree of employment protection. Keywords: Deregulation ... al. (2003) reach similar conclusions for the telecom sectors. 1 ... is then the better solution for two reasons. First, product .

Labour Law in Tanzania Book.pdf
... was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Labour Law in Tanzania Book.pdf. Labour Law in Tan

Adjustment costs in labour markets and the ...
Aug 8, 2005 - We compare simulation results from each and show how different treatments can sig- ... labour is treated as fully mobile across all sectors in the economy. .... geneity to deal with cross hauling in trade data and specialization, ...

Review Essay: Land, Labour and Agrarian Transition in ...
van de Walle misconstrue landlessness, misinterpret the associated data and ... 'from a highly controlled collective-farming system to the type of free-market ..... which, as an agrarian political economist, I define as differentiation in access to.

Swipe right: Preferences and outcomes in online mate search
Nov 9, 2016 - dataset from a mobile dating app, I observe search behavior, ..... registered users are examined by the app's developers in order to avoid and ...

Swipe right: Preferences and outcomes in online mate search
Nov 9, 2016 - Unlike traditional online dating websites (see e.g. Hitsch et al., 2010), users in ..... On a more social dimension, no. of friends is the number of ...

Variations in parenting and adolescent outcomes ...
P. Leaf, P. I.) and the JHU Center for Adolescent Health (U48 DP4000040, F. Sonenstein, P. I.), both of which are .... younger, F(1, 1021) = 12.7, p < .001, and less likely to live in San Antonio, ...... Cultural diversity: A wake-up call for parents

Complementary inputs and the existence of stable outcomes in large ...
Jun 22, 2017 - However, Azevedo and Hatfield's (2013) conditions do not define a maximal domain for the existence of stable outcomes in large two-sided ...

Swipe right: Preferences and outcomes in online ... - Semantic Scholar
Nov 9, 2016 - a telephone message is exchanged (which happens in 2 percent of initial matches), correspond- ing to a match as ... The ranks assigned in the first stage are in line with the phone numbers exchanged later, with lower ranks ...... The or

Synchronising Deregulation in Product and Labour ...
... regulatory reform; Li et al. (2003) reach similar conclusions for the telecom sectors. 1 ..... more fierce opposition of a deregulation. The existence of these rents ...

Synchronising Deregulation in Product and Labour ...
labour market regulation that determines the degree of employment protection. Keywords: ...... Conflicts,. Princeton University-IR Section Working Paper 444.

Synchronising Deregulation in Product and Labour ... - Acrobat Planet
main reason why frictions remain in European labour markets, says Saint-Paul (2000), is that ..... optimal intervention into the market place, but a function of the legal culture and history of the country. EPL may ..... one possible equilibrium path