Economics Letters 104 (2009) 23–26

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economics Letters j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w. e l s ev i e r. c o m / l o c a t e / e c o l e t

Simultaneous vs. sequential price competition with incomplete information☆ Leandro Arozamena a,⁎, Federico Weinschelbaum b,1 a b

Universidad Torcuato Di Tella and CONICET, Argentina Universidad de San Andrés, Vito Dumas 284, B1644BID Victoria, Buenos Aires, Argentina

a r t i c l e

i n f o

Article history: Received 27 May 2008 Received in revised form 16 March 2009 Accepted 18 March 2009 Available online 27 March 2009

a b s t r a c t We compare equilibria with sequential and simultaneous moves under homogeneous-good Bertrand competition when unit costs are private information. Under an alternative interpretation, we examine the consequences of awarding a right of first refusal in a first-price procurement auction with endogenous quantity. © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Oligopoly Auctions with endogenous quantity Right of first refusal Second-mover advantage JEL classification: C72 D43 D44

1. Introduction The consequences of different orderings of moves in strategic interaction have been extensively analyzed in the literature, particularly for oligopoly games. In the case of sequential moves, the main issue has been whether first or second movers hold an advantage.2 In addition, once the equilibria that follow from simultaneous and sequential moves are known, the timing of the game can be made endogenous by adding a prior stage where players choose when to move.3 Most of these analyses have been carried out under complete information. Here we pose a similar question in the specific case of price competition with incomplete information. Two firms compete à la Bertrand in a homogeneous-good market. Firms' (constant) unit costs are private information. Firms may quote their prices simultaneously. Alternatively, it may be the case that one of the firms sets its price first, its rival observes that choice and then quotes its own price. We compare the equilibria that result from simultaneous and sequential ☆ We are grateful to Walter Cont and Germán Coloma for their comments on a previous version of this note. We acknowledge financial support from FONCyT, PICT 2255. ⁎ Corresponding author. Saenz Valiente 1010, C1428BIJ Buenos Aires, Argentina. Tel.: +54 11 5169 7300; fax: +54 11 5169 7348. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (L. Arozamena), [email protected] (F. Weinschelbaum). 1 Tel.: +54 11 4725 7041; fax: +54 11 4725 7010. 2 There is a large literature on sequential competition. See, for instance, Gal-Or (1985), and, more recently, Dastidar (2004) and Amir and Stepanova (2006). 3 Endogenous timing is examined, among others, by Hamilton and Slutsky (1990), Amir and Grilo (1999), Hurkens and van Damme (1999) and Amir and Stepanova (2006). 0165-1765/$ – see front matter © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2009.03.017

choices. Our analysis can be viewed, then, as a contribution to any attempt to endogenize the timing of moves in Bertrand competition with incomplete information. This form of price competition under incomplete information may be also understood as a procurement auction with variable quantities. That is, the buyer announces a demand schedule. Firms then compete in an auction where the exact procured quantity depends on the final price according to that schedule. Simultaneous competition corresponds to the case of a first-price auction. Sequential competition will occur whenever one of the bidders has a right of first refusal, i.e. the right to observe her rival's bid and match it to win if she desires to do so. Since rights of first refusal are quite common, for instance, in transactions among firms, examining their consequences is an interesting issue. Our analysis attempts to establish the changes in bidding behavior and buyer's and bidders' profits induced by the introduction of such rights. In what follows, we characterize the equilibria of the sequential and the simultaneous game4 and then compare the equilibria under both timings. First, we show that the fact that the rival will move second can make a firm behave more or less aggressively than under simultaneous competition. We provide sufficient conditions on cost distributions and demand for the first mover to be more aggressive in the sequential case. Next, we show that there is a second-mover advantage in the sequential game, and we prove that the first mover is 4 Spulber (1995) examines the case of static Bertrand competition, i.e. our simultaneous game. Hansen (1988) compares first- and second-price variable– quantity auctions with simultaneous bidding.

24

L. Arozamena, F. Weinschelbaum / Economics Letters 104 (2009) 23–26

worse off when price-quoting is sequential. Finally, we establish that, under certain conditions, buyer and total surplus are larger in the simultaneous game.

Given firm 2's behavior, firm 1 has to quote a price lower than c2 to win. Hence, given c1, firm 1's problem is maxðb − c1 ÞQ ðbÞ½1 − F ðbÞ b

2. The model Two risk-neutral firms compete à la Bertrand in a homogeneousproduct market. Market demand is Q(p), with Q′(p) b 0.5 The firm that quotes the lowest price sells the quantity that the demand function specifies at that price, while its rival makes no profit. Let ci be firm i's constant unit cost (i = 1,2). ci is firm i's private information. Unit costs are i.i.d. according to the cumulative distribution function F, with _ support [c̲,c ]. We assume that F has a density that is positive and _ _ bounded for all c ∈ [c̲,c ]. Finally, we also assume that Q(c ) N 0. Suppose first that both firms quote prices simultaneously.6 This is the case of simultaneous price competition under incomplete information studied in Spulber (1995), or the first-price variablequantity auction examined in Hansen (1988). Let b0i (ci) be firm i's bidding function in this game. Under our assumptions (see Maskin and Riley, 1984, Theorem 2), there is a unique symmetric equilibrium in strictly increasing strategies. Suppose then that firm j (j ≠ i) quotes its price according to the bidding function b0j (cj), and let ϕ0j (b) be its inverse. Then, firm i's problem when its cost is ci is h  i 0 maxðbi − ci ÞQ ðbi Þ 1 − F /j ðbi Þ

The corresponding first-order condition is h  i 0 Q ðbi Þ 1 − F /j ðbi Þ   h  i bi − ci = Q ðbi Þf /0j ðbi Þ /0j Vðbi Þ − Q Vðbi Þ 1 − F /0j ðbi Þ

In the symmetric equilibrium we have b0i (c) = b0j (c) = b0(c), and = ϕ0j (c) = ϕ0(c). Then, the equilibrium inverse bidding function, ϕ0(c), solves the differential equation

ϕ0i (c)

h  i Q ðbÞ 1 − F /0 ðbÞ      b − / ðbÞ = Q ðbÞf /0 ðbÞ /0 VðbÞ − Q VðbÞ 1 − F /0 ðbÞ

b − c1 =

ð1Þ

Unfortunately, in general there is no explicit solution to Eq. (1), so we will have to work with the differential equation defining ϕ0(b) implicitly. Consider now the case of sequential competition. One firm (say, firm 1) quotes its price b1. Its rival, firm 2, observes b1 and then chooses its own price b2. To avoid technical complications, we will assume that firm 2 wins the competition if there is a tie.7 The equilibrium behavior of firm 2 in the sequential game is easy to establish. Given b1, firm 2 has to match that bid to win. It will want to do so whenever b1 ≥ c2, and will thus set b2 = min{b1, pM(c2)}, where pM(c2) is the monopoly price for unit cost c2. If b1 b c2, firm 2 will not match but rather set some price b2 N b1 so as to lose. Any strategy that generates this behavior will strictly dominate any strategy that does not.8

We define H ðbÞu

Q ðbÞ½1 − F ðbÞ = Q ðbÞf ðbÞ − Q VðbÞ½1 − F ðbÞ

1 f ðbÞ 1 − F ðbÞ

ð Þ − QQ Vb ðbÞ

In what follows, we will assume that H is strictly decreasing.9 Then, the unique equilibrium bidding function for firm 1, which we denote by b1(c1), is strictly increasing. Let ϕ1(b) be its inverse, which is defined by 1

b − / ðbÞ =

Q ðbÞ½1 − F ðbÞ Q ðbÞf ðbÞ − Q VðbÞ½1 − F ðbÞ

ð2Þ

Suppose we move from simultaneous to sequential bidding. How does equilibrium bidding behavior change? In the case of firm 2, the answer is straightforward. From firm 1's perspective, in the sequential case firm 2 behaves as if it was bidding its own cost. Since in the simultaneous case firm 2 bids above its cost, firm 1 faces a more aggressive rival in sequential competition. The comparison is more interesting in the case of firm 1. When moving from simultaneous to sequential competition, is it possible that firm 1 become uniformly more aggressive (i.e. b0(c) N b1(c) for all _ _ c b c ) or uniformly less aggressive (i.e. b0(c) b b1(c) for all c b c )? Proposition 1 provides sufficient conditions for firm 1 to be uniformly more aggressive in the sequential case. Let γðbÞ = − ð1 Q−ðbFÞ ð=bÞQÞ V=ðbfÞðbÞ. Proposition 1. If H(b) is convex and γ(b) is decreasing (one of them _ strictly),10 then b0(c) N b1(c) for all c b c . Proof. See Appendix A. Remark I. We could analogously prove that if H(b) is concave and γ(b) is increasing – one of them strictly – (respectively, if H(b) is linear and _ γ(b) is constant) then b0(c) b b1(c) for all c b c (respectively, b0(c) = b1 _ _ (c) for all c). However, γ(b) N 0 for all b b c and γ(c ) = 0.11 Then, γ(b) has _ to be decreasing in a subinterval of [c̲,c ] Example 1 provides a case where the conditions mentioned in Proposition 1 are satisfied. 2

Example 1. If F ðcÞ = 12 c + c2 with support [0,1] and Q(p) = 10 − p, H (b) is strictly convex and γ(b) is strictly decreasing. However, firm 1 may also be uniformly less aggressive under sequential bidding. 9

5

Q ðbÞ½1 − F ðbÞ Q ðbÞf ðbÞ − Q VðbÞ½1 − F ðbÞ

3. Bidding aggressiveness

bi

0

The resulting first-order condition is

As usual, we assume that Q(p) is not “too convex,” so that the second-order conditions of the monopoly profit-maximization problem are satisfied. 6 Ties (which will happen with zero probability at the equilibrium) are solved randomly in this case. 7 This is exactly what happens in a procurement auction when firm 2 is awarded a right of first refusal. 8 Since when b1 b c2 any b2 N b1 is optimal, there isn’t a strictly dominant strategy.

Where convenient, we will assume as well that it is differentiable. 2 None of these conditions implies the other. If F ðcÞ = 12 + c2 (with support [0,1]) and Q(p) = 10 – p2, H(b) is convex and γ(b) is increasing in a subinterval of [0,1]. If 2 F ðcÞ = 32 − c2 on the same support and Q(p) = 10 – p, then H(b) is strictly concave and γ(b) is decreasing. With a fixed quantity, these conditions become those in Arozamena and Weinschelbaum (forthcoming), Proposition 1. 11 – Q(b)/Q′(b) has to be bounded below for the monopoly price to be well defined, so γ(c̅) = 0. 10

L. Arozamena, F. Weinschelbaum / Economics Letters 104 (2009) 23–26

Fig. 1.

Example 2. Let ϕF(b) be the equilibrium inverse bidding function in the first-price auction with a _fixed quantity. Hansen (1988) proved  −1 that ϕF(b) b ϕ0(b) for all b b c . Take F ðcÞ = 1 − 1 −e e − 1 e1 − c − 1 with support [0,1] and Q(p) = 20 – p. Fig. 1 depicts ϕF(b) – ϕ1(b). Since _ _ ϕ1(b) b ϕF(b) for all b b c , it follows that ϕ1(b) b ϕ0(b) for all b b c . 4. Welfare and efficiency Is there a second-mover advantage in the sequential game? We provide now a positive answer. Proposition 2. Let U1i (c) be firm i's interim expected profit in the _ sequential game, i = 1,2. Then, U12(c) N U11(c) for all c b c . _ U12(c) = ∫ϕc1(c) [min{b1(s),pM(c)} − c]Q(min{b1(s), _ 1

Proof. For any c, pM(c)})f(s)ds. Then, since ϕ (c) b c for any c b c , 1

U2 ðcÞN

Z

ch

c

h

n o i  n o 1 M 1 M min b ðsÞ; p ðcÞ − c Q min b ðsÞ; p ðcÞ f ðsÞds N

25

Comparing buyer welfare and efficiency between the two games presents similar complications. Both equilibria lead to market inefficiency: for all cost pairs (c1,c2), the final price is higher than min{c1,c2}. Just as above, if b1(c) ≥ b0(c) for all c the price is higher in the sequential game. Then, expected buyer surplus is lower when competition is sequential. Simultaneous competition is more efficient, since (i) the price is always lower, and (ii) in our setting, the firm with the lowest cost is always the winner, while in the sequential case firm 1 0 2 may _ win even though c2 N c1. But we may have b (c) b b (c) for all c b c , so that, for some cost pairs, the corresponding price is lower in the sequential game. Hence, we cannot make a general assertion. Proposition 3 shows, however, that under some assumptions we can. _ Proposition 3. If F is logconcave,12 pM(c̲) ≥ c and H(b) is convex, then expected buyer surplus and expected total surplus are higher in the simultaneous than in the sequential game. Proof. From Hansen (1988), under our assumptions, both expected buyer and total surplus are lower in a second-price than in a first-price auction. Then, it suffices to show that both surpluses are lower in our sequential game than in a second-price auction. Let GSPA(b) (G1(b)) be the c.d.f. of the equilibrium price in a simultaneous second-price SPA 1 auction (in _ our sequential game). We will show that G (b) N G (b) for all b b c , and the result will follow. Since in a second-price auction each firm bids its own cost, GSPA(b) = (F(b))2. In addition, G1(b) = F(ϕ1(b)). For all b ∈ (c̲,b1(0)), we have G_SPA (b) N G1(b) = 0. Clearly, then, if both distributions _cross at _some b̂ b c , it SPA 1 ̂ ̂ But, GSPA(c ) =G1(c ) = 1, so, for ′(b). has to be the case _ that G ′(b) b G SPA 1 SPA ̃ 1 ̃ ̃ ̃ ̂ some b ∈ (b,c ), we   must have G ′(b) =G ′(b) and G (b) b G (b). Hence,

G1 V ˜b

GSPA′ ˜b

G1 ˜b

GSPA ˜b

 b

  or

       f V /1 b˜ /1 V b˜ 2f b˜    b   F /1 b˜ F b˜

i   1 1 b ðcÞ − c Q b ðcÞ ½1 − F ðcÞ

where the last inequality holds since b1(c) is strictly increasing and, if b1(c) b pM(c), (b − c)Q(b) is strictly increasing in b. As U11(c) = [b1(c) − □ c]Q(b1(c))[1 − F(b1(c))], the result follows. Let us now compare the equilibria of the simultaneous and the sequential game in terms of bidder welfare. Let Ui0(c) be firm i's interim expected utility when its cost is c in the case of simultaneous competition. It is straightforward that U11(c)bU10(c) for all c bc .̅ Indeed, the situation firm 1 faces in the sequential case is the same it would face in the simultaneous case if firm 2 bid its own cost, as mentioned above. Since in the simultaneous game firm 2 bids above its cost, firm 1 must be better off. The comparison, however, is not as clear in the case of the second mover. If b1(c) ≥ b0(c) for all c, then U12(c) N U20(c) follows: not only does firm 2 hold the advantage of moving second, but it also faces a (weakly) less aggressive rival. For every cost realization (c1,c2), (i) if firm 2 wins in the simultaneous game, it wins as well in the sequential game, and it does so at a higher price; and (ii) it is possible that firm 2 loses in the simultaneous game and wins in the sequential game. Still, as we have shown, there is a whole class of cases where b1(c) b b0(c) for all c b c ̅. There is another unfavorable effect on U12(c). Given c2 and given that firm 2 wins, in the simultaneous case there is no uncertainty associated to the price firm 2 will be paid. In the sequential case that price is firm 1's bid, a random variable for firm 2 from an ex-ante standpoint. Given that firm 2's profit function is concave in price, this is detrimental to expected profits. It seems possible then that the second mover could be worse off in the sequential than in the simultaneous case, but we do not have an example where this happens.

As F(c) is logconcave, f(b)/F(b) is decreasing. Then, the last inequality 1 can only hold if ϕ1′(b)̃ b 2. However, from Eq. (2), _ ϕ ′(b)= 1−H′(b). It can be checked that, under our assumptions, H′(c ) =−1. Given that H(b) □ is convex, ϕ1′(b)̃ ≥2, a contradiction. Remark 2. Note that the equilibrium in the second-price auction is unaffected by the timing of the game. Then in the cases where Proposition 3 applies, the proof shows that, under sequential bidding, the first-price auction generates a lower expected buyer and total surplus than the second-price auction. This ranking is the opposite of the one obtained by Hansen (1988) for the simultaneous case. 5. Concluding remarks By comparing the equilibria in simultaneous and sequential pricequoting, we conclude that moving first may lead a firm to bid more or less aggressively that it would in a simultaneous game. The second mover holds an advantage. Moreover, shifting from simultaneous to sequential competition is certainly detrimental to the first mover. Under some conditions, that shift has negative consequences for buyer surplus and efficiency. If we take the oligopoly interpretation of our games, and along the lines of the literature on endogenous timing in symmetric-information cases, it would be interesting to add a first stage where firms strategically determine the order of moves. This, however, remains to be done.

12 Log concavity holds for most well-known c.d.f.'s. See Bagnoli and Bergstrom ^ (2005).

26

L. Arozamena, F. Weinschelbaum / Economics Letters 104 (2009) 23–26

Appendix A. Proof of Proposition 1

_ _ _ 0 1 ). Since ϕ0(c )= _Suppose then that ϕ (b)N ϕ (b) for some b ∈ (c_ −δ,c 1 0 ϕ (c )=c, it has to be true that, for some b⁎ close to c , ϕ ′(b⁎)N ϕ ′(b⁎) and ϕ0(b⁎)N ϕ1(b⁎). Then, from Eq. (2), and the fact that H(b) is convex, 1

In terms of inverse bidding functions, we have to show that ϕ0(b) b _ ϕ1(b) for all b b c . Step 1 below shows that if ϕ0(b̂) = ϕ1(b̂) for some _ _ b̂ b c , then ϕ0′(b̂) N ϕ1′(b̂). Step 2 proves that, for b close enough to c , ϕ0(b) b ϕ1(b). Then, the result follows. Step 1. Notice that HðbÞ =   1 H / ðbÞ H ðbÞ

1 − F ð/1 ðbÞÞ " f ð/1 ðbÞÞ

=

1 − F ðbÞ f ðbÞ

ð1 − F ðbÞÞ = f ðbÞ . 1 + γ ðbÞ

1 + γðbÞ   1 + γ /1 ðbÞ

Hence, for any b,

# ð3Þ

But substituting from Eq. (1) in the last expression, we obtain

    If, for some b̂ b c, we have /1 b̂ = /0 b̂ = ĉ , then, from Eqs. (1) and (2)   b̂ =

1 − F ðc ̂ Þ f ðc ̂ Þ

         H b4 − H /0 b4 b4 − /1 b4 4 4     = 1− / b = 1 − HV b V 1 − b4 − /0 b4 b4 − /0 b4       0 4 0 4 H / b H / b   b   + b4 − /0 b4 b4 − /0 b4 1V



1V

/

4 b



  1 − F /0 b4  = f /0 b4  /0 V b4 − Q ðb4Þ = Q Vðb4Þ    b 1 + γ /0 b4

ð4Þ

the same reasoning that lead to Since ϕ0(b⁎) N ϕ1(b⁎), following   1 − F /0 b4  = f /0 b4  0V 4 . A contradiction Eq. (4) in step 1, / b N ð1 − F ðb4 ÞÞ = f ðb4 Þ obtains, since, as γ(b) is decreasing,

Differentiating both sides of Eq. (2) and subtracting from Eq. (4) we have

  1 − F b4  = f b4          /0 V b4  /0 V b4 −  1 + γ b4  Q b4 = Q V b4 1V 4 0V 4       V /0 V b4 =/ b / b b 0 4 0 4 1+γ / b 1+γ / b

0V

/

 

1 − F b̂ f b̂

/

    1V b̂ − / b̂ =

0V

2 3      H ðc ̂ Þ 1 + γ ðc ̂ Þ 5   − 1 + H V b̂   − 1 − H V b̂ =  4 1 − F b̂ ̂ ̂ H b 1+γ b   1 − F ðc ̂ Þ f ðc ̂ Þ f b̂

where the last equality follows from Eq. (3). Since γ(b) is decreasing and c ̂ b b̂,       H ðc ̂ Þ   Hðc ̂ Þ − H b̂ 1 V   / b̂ − / b̂ z   − 1 + H V b̂ = H b̂ H b̂       Hðc ̂ Þ − H b̂ + H V b̂ + H V b̂ = ̂ b − ĉ 0V

where the inequality is strict if γ(b) is strictly decreasing and the last equality follows from Eq. (2). The first term in the last expression is positive, while the is negative. If H(b) is convex (strictly  second   H ðc ̂Þ − H b̂ + H V b̂ zðNÞ0. convex), ̂ b − ĉ

_ _ Step 2. Take δ small enough. If ϕ0(b̃) = ϕ1(b̃) for some b̃ ∈ (c − δ,c ), 0 1 ̃ we know from step 1 that, for b slightly above b, ϕ (b) N ϕ (b). Then, we focus on showing that this last inequality leads to a contradiction.



References Amir, R., Grilo, I., 1999. Stackelberg versus Cournot equilibrium. Games and Economic Behavior 26, 1–21. Amir, R., Stepanova, A., 2006. Second-mover advantage and price leadership in Bertrand duopoly. Games and Economic Behavior 55, 1–20. Arozamena, L. and Weinschelbaum, F., forthcoming. The effect of corruption on bidding behavior in first-price auctions, European Economic Review. Bagnoli, M., Bergstrom, T., 2005. Log-concave probability and its applications. Economic Theory 26, 445–469. Dastidar, K.G., 2004. On Stackelberg games in a homogeneous product market. European Economic Review 48, 549–562. Gal-Or, E., 1985. First mover and second mover advantages. International Economic Review 26, 649–653. Hamilton, J., Slutsky, S., 1990. Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or Cournot equilibria. Games and Economic Behavior 2, 29–46. Hansen, R., 1988. Auctions with endogenous quantity. RAND Journal of Economics 19, 44–58. Hurkens, S., van Damme, E., 1999. Endogenous Stackelberg leadership. Games and Economic Behavior 28, 105–129. Maskin, E., Riley, J., 1984. Optimal auctions with risk averse buyers. Econometrica 52, 1473–1518. Spulber, D., 1995. Bertrand competition when rivals' costs are unknown. Journal of Industrial Economics 43, 1–11.

Simultaneous vs. sequential price competition with ...

Aug 22, 2011 - assume that firm 2 wins the competition if there is a tie.7 The equilibrium behavior of firm 2 in the sequential game is easy to establish. Given b1, firm 2 has to match that bid to win. It will want to do so whenever b1 ≥ c2, and will thus set b2 = min{b1, pM(c2)}, where. pM(c2) is the monopoly price for unit cost ...

176KB Sizes 0 Downloads 208 Views

Recommend Documents

Sequential Descending-Price auctions with asymmetric ...
Nov 23, 2000 - The paper reports an analysis of price behaviour at a fish market which is or- .... they symmetrised? buyers by assuming that one large buyer (who bought ... The work of Ginsburgh (1998) on wine auction data stands as an ...

Price Competition with Decreasing Returns#to#Scale ...
Dec 10, 2014 - Key words: Price competition, Demand rationing, Convex costs, .... Let si (pi) denote the quantity that solves this optimization problem.9 The ...

Matching and Price Competition with an Outside Market
May 15, 2014 - Bulow and Levin (2006) develop a model of matching with salaries in which equilibrium salaries, relative to their competitive levels, are compressed and, on average, lower. This paper expands their model by allowing for a competitive o

Consumer Search and Price Competition
Nov 6, 2016 - Keywords : Consumer search; price advertisements; online shopping; Bertrand competition; product differentiation. 1 Introduction. We consider ...

Matching and Price Competition: Comment
where each firm can hire only one worker and ... sizes on that Web site (the data were collected on October .... Our analysis relied crucially on the assumption.

Relaxing Price Competition Through Product ...
have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a .... income ti, is indifferent between good fc at price pk and good Ic —- I at price p, ... being a measure of the relative qualities of goods 1 and 2, and the residual good

Consumer Search and Price Competition
37Integrate equation (2) by parts and differentiate with respect to w, then h(w) = ∫. ¯v w−z∗ g(w − vi)dF(vi)+. (1 − G(z∗))f(w − z∗). The second term vanishes as z∗ → ¯z. 38If ¯z = ∞, then ∫. ¯v+z∗ w f(w − z∗)dH(w)nâ

Calvo vs. Rotemberg Price Setting
Long-run Phillips Curve and Disinflation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Price Setting. Guido Ascari (°) Lorenza Rossi (*). (°)Universitа degli Studi di Pavia e IfW.

Modelling Simultaneous Games with Concurrent ...
1Acknowledges a Rubicon grant of the NWO (680-50-0504) for her visit to University of Amsterdam in the ... as well as support from the INIGMA project, NWO.

Sequential Negotiations with Costly Information ...
Aug 1, 2013 - Sonat “stated that other parties had expressed interest in a business combination ...... No sale to a noninspecting bidder occurs before the final period, since the option to .... The item is a startup with a novel tanning technology.

Facilitation vs. apparent competition: insect ... - Wiley Online Library
Apparent competition from nurse plants can strongly reduce recruitment facilitation in stressful environments .... often exceed 30 °C. The site was representative of the transition between dry coniferous woodlands and the semiarid Patagonian steppe

With Sequential Service Taken Seriously
random times) in a discrete model." However, they did not appeal to these hints when they asserted consistency between the sequential service constraint and the policy that they identify with deposit insurance and that overcomes the difficulties asso

Competition vs. property rights: American antitrust law, the Freiburg ...
Sep 30, 2011 - (“European Union” and “EU”), as the former were the official ones in the period under scrutiny. .... competition as a wasteful process, as well as from the support for Taylorist criteria of industrial organization ... Act in 18

VS Curl & Hair Dryer Competition - Instagram FINAL.pdf ...
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. VS Curl & Hair Dryer Competition - Instagram FINAL.pdf. VS Curl & Hair Dryer Competition - Instagram FINAL.p

Competition vs. property rights: American antitrust law, the Freiburg ...
Sep 30, 2011 - contribution to the historical evolution of US antitrust law has been smaller than usually believed. Second ..... giants which had until then eluded antitrust law. Among ...... A Policy at War with Itself, New York: The Free Press.

Facilitation vs. apparent competition: insect herbivory ...
modelling approach (PROC GENMOD, SAS Institute 1996). Proportional data were ..... and Quercus lobata in California. Ecology, 73, 2118–2128. .... Technical support issues arising from supporting information (other than missing files) should ...

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
Jul 21, 2017 - Email: [email protected]. ... since, in our model, consumers purchase in volume and they may choose to purchase more than ... 1The approaches proposed in the marketing literature (e.g. Dikson and .... between product varieties is hi

Does Competition Reduce Price Dispersion? New ...
including advance-purchase requirements, nonrefundable tickets, and. Saturday night .... Section III includes our own fixed-effects panel analysis. Section IV .... The data also show a large amount of variation in competition over time within the ...

Spatial Competition with Heterogeneous Firms
I know of no analytic solutions with heterogeneous firms and convex costs of .... A producer must design its product and a retailer must build a store. ...... 20 The proofs of proposition 2 and of all subsequent propositions are relegated to App. A.

Sequential Auctions with Supply Uncertainty
Page 1 ... earlier draft. Remaining errors are my own. 1 ..... requirement for the seller will in turn make him unable to take full advantage of his own. 7One could ...

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
(2017) who consider a competitive facility location problem on a network in which consumers located on vertices wish to connect to the nearest facility and each competitor locates a facility on a vertex trying to maximize her market share. This liter

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
Email: [email protected]. ... At the same time, the marketing ... 1The approaches proposed in the marketing literature (e.g. Dikson and ...... This is exactly the result for the benchmark monopolistic competition model without network (see.

Price Competition in Product Variety Networks
Mar 19, 2018 - settings, where prices are typically strategic complements (Vives, 1999). Furthermore, we ... we provide examples obtained via simulations. 4 ...