Sorting and the output loss due to search frictions Pieter A. Gautieryand Coen N. Teulings

z

First version 2010, this version October 2014

Abstract We analyze a general search model with on-the-job search (OJS) and sorting of heterogeneous workers into heterogeneous jobs. For given values of non-market time, the relative e¢ ciency of OJS, and the amount of search frictions, we derive a simple relationship between the unemployment rate, mismatch and wage dispersion. We estimate the latter two from standard micro data. Our methodology accounts for measurement error, which is crucial to distinguish true from spurious mismatch and wage dispersion. We …nd that without frictions, output would be about 9.5% higher if …rms can commit to pay wages as a function of match quality and 15.5% higher if they cannot. Non-commitment leads to a business-stealing externality which causes a 5.5% drop in output. JEL codes: E24, J62, J63, J64

We thank seminar participants at MIT, the 2009 Sandjberg conference on search models of the labor market, the Sciences Po conference on sorting, University of Munich, SED (2011), the 2011 Tinbergen conference in Amsterdam, Essex, UPenn and the SAM meeting in Rouen for useful comments and discussions. Finally, we thank Bart Hobijn for sharing his labor-market ‡ow data with us, and Xiaoming Cai for excellent research assistance. y VU University Amsterdam, Tinbergen Institute, CEPR, Ces-Ifo, IZA, email: [email protected] z University of Cambridge, University of Amsterdam, Tinbergen Institute, CEPR, CeS-Ifo, IZA, email: [email protected]

1

Introduction

Labor productivity depends crucially on the proper sorting of worker types into job types, a process that is hindered by search frictions. If all unemployed workers and jobs were alike, it would be hard to imagine why it takes workers months to …nd a suitable job. But also if workers and jobs were heterogeneous but search frictions were absent, the loss in output due to mismatch would be irrelevant because all workers would be matched to their optimal job types. This paper explicitly models this interaction between search frictions and heterogeneity and estimates the output loss due to search frictions. This loss is then decomposed in its three components: (i) unemployment, (ii) resources spent on recruitment activities and (iii) mismatch. We also estimate the output loss that can be attributed to the inability of employers to commit to future wage payments. Only this loss can potentially be reduced by policy intervention. The starting point of this paper is the framework of Gautier, Teulings and Van Vuuren (2010) who analyze a class of search models with on-the-job (OJS) search and worker and job heterogeneity where the productivity of a match depends on the degree of mismatch. Their production function can be interpreted as a second-order Taylor approximation of a more general speci…cation of the production technology. Within this framework, various wage mechanisms can be analyzed such as wage posting with full commitment, as in Burdett and Mortensen (1998) and Bontemps, van den Berg, and Robin (2000), and wage mechanisms without commitment, as in Coles (2001) and Shimer (2006). The key di¤erence between wage setting with and without commitment is that in the former case, …rms pay both hiring and no-quit premiums, whereas in the latter case, …rms pay only no-quit premiums. Our model is related to hedonic pricing/assignment/sorting models in which worker types are imperfect substitutes –in the spirit of Rosen (1974), Sattinger (1975) and Teulings (1995, 2005). Intuitively, the less substitutable worker types are, the larger will be the productivity loss due to mismatch. We use a relation between Katz and Murphy’s (1992) elasticity of complementarity between high- and low-skilled workers and the curvature of the production function. This curvature determines how sensitive output is to the degree of mismatch. In a Walrasian equilibrium, the above

1

models generate a perfect sorting of high-skilled workers at complex jobs. With search frictions, this perfect correlation breaks down. Within the class of sorting models with search frictions, a distinction can be made between hierarchical models, like Shimer and Smith (2000), and circle models, like Marimon and Zillibotti (1999). Since circle models are more easy to handle analytically than hierarchical models, we apply a circle model in our theoretical analysis.1 We show that the equilibrium depends on just four parameters: (i) the value of nonmarket time, (ii) the relative e¢ ciency of on- versus o¤-the-job search, (iii) the curvature of the production function (i.e. how fast output falls with the degree of mismatch), and (iv) a composite parameter that measures the amount of search frictions. The relevance of our model depends on how well it can match the empirical values for these parameters. The main hurdle is to obtain estimates for wage dispersion and the output loss due to mismatch. We follow Gautier and Teulings (2006) by using data on wages and on worker and job characteristics to construct an empirical measure for mismatch. We also o¤er a new simple statistic for wage dispersion due to search frictions, namely the intercept of a simple quadratic wage regression with appropriately normalized measures for worker and job characteristics (this measures the di¤erence between the expected maximum and the average wage). The simplicity of this measure makes it easily applicable. Since observed mismatch can be either real or due to measurement error, it is important to correct for this. We show how to do that. Given wage dispersion and mismatch, our model implies a value for the unemployment rate. We …nd values that are close to the empirical values of about 5%: Hence, our model can jointly explain the observed wage dispersion for workers with equal skill and unemployment. We use the model to calculate the total output loss due to search frictions, which we estimate to be between 9 and 16% of the total value added of labour, depending on whether …rms can or cannot commit to paying hiring premiums. Unemployment accounts 1

We can still match moments generated by a hierarchical process because analytical conclusions from a circle model translate into a hierarchical setting because the former can be viewed of as a second order Taylor approximation of the latter, see Gautier, Teulings, and Van Vuuren (2005). The intuition is that in hierarchical models, the output and wage loss due to mismatch also depends on the expected distance to one’s optimal job type.

2

for less than 30% of this loss. If …rms cannot commit to wages, their quasi-rents are higher than in the social optimum, due to a business-stealing externality. As a result of free entry, these quasi-rents are all spent on (excess) vacancy creation. The estimated output loss due to this business-stealing externality is 5:5% of the total value added of labour. This externality can potentially be reduced by policies that shift rents from the …rms to the workers.2 Most of the literature on sorting with frictions considers global absolute advantages of high-skilled workers. Atakan (2006) and Eeckhout and Kircher (2009) consider a simpli…ed version of Shimer and Smith (2000). Similar to our model, wages are highest at the optimal assignment and they are lower at both less and more complex jobs. Their model is however less suitable to bring to the data. Hagedorn, Law and Manovskii (2012) show how both the Shimer and Smith (2000) model and our model are non-parametrically identi…ed from individual wage data from …rm-worker data sets. The idea is that wages are informative about the ranks of worker types within each …rm. Bagger and Lentz (2012) consider a sorting model where workers search most intensively for the jobs where they earn the highest wages. Lise and Robin (2013) consider a sorting model with on-thejob search that focuses on the macro dynamics in the presence of aggregate shocks. Lise, Meghir and Robin (2012), Lopes de Melo (2008) and Bartolucci and Devicienti (2012) also look at sorting in models with OJS. Their focus is on interpreting the correlations between worker and …rm …xed e¤ects. Under comparative advantage, this issue is not very meaningful. For example, in Teulings and Gautier (2004), complex jobs do not have an absolute advantage over simple jobs. They only have a comparative advantage when occupied by better-skilled workers. Since skilled workers have an absolute advantage, workers employed in more-complex jobs earn higher wages but the higher wages are not due to the job, but to the type of workers that occupy these jobs. In this context, one can just reverse the ordering of job types to change from negative to positive assortative matching. Without loss of generality, we focus on the latter. An important di¤erence 2

In Gautier et al. (2014) we show that if a union sets pay scales ex ante to reduce the business externality, it will set the lowest wage on the pay scale too high which increases unemployment and may actually reduce welfare.

3

between the empirical sorting models described above and ours is that all jobs in a …rm have the same …xed e¤ect. We do not make that assumption. Cornfeld (2014) considers a di¤erent type of sorting model where skill is de…ned as the set of tasks that a worker can perform. Finally, Jovanovic (2013) looks at the e¤ect of misallocation in the labor market on growth in a model where agents must learn about their abilities and Concerning wage dispersion, Hornstein et al. (2010) also derive a simple relationship between the unemployment rate and wage dispersion, the mean-min ratio. We show that this measure is sensitive to measurement error. They argue that search models without OJS cannot explain the coexistence of a low unemployment rate and substantial wage dispersion because the former suggests low frictions, while the latter suggests high frictions. Gautier and Teulings (2006) made a similar point. This issue can be resolved by allowing for OJS, since this lowers the reservation wage (consequently wage dispersion rises and the unemployment rate falls). Allowing for OJS is also quantitatively important, since Fallick and Fleischman (2004) and Nagypal (2005) show that job-to-job ‡ows are substantial. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a summary of the model of Gautier, Teulings and Van Vuuren (2010) as a point of reference for the rest of the paper. Section 3 discusses how we can identify and measure mismatch and wage dispersion in the presence of measurement error. Section 4 presents the calibration results, the estimation of the output loss due to search frictions and the decomposition of this loss. Finally, Section 5 concludes.

2 2.1

The Model Assumptions

Production There is a continuum of worker types, s; and job types, c; s and c are locations on a circle. Workers can only produce output when matched to a job. The productivity of a match of worker type s to job type c depends on the shortest distance jxj between s and c along the circumference of the circle. Y (x) has an interior maximum at x = 0 and is symmetric 4

around this maximum Y (0) (normalized to unity). Finally, Y (x) is twice di¤erentiable and strictly concave. We consider the simplest functional form that meets these criteria: Y (x) = 1

1 2 x: 2

We call x the mismatch indicator. The parameter

(1) determines the substitutability of

worker types: the lower , the more easily worker types can be substituted. Y (x) can be interpreted as a second-order Taylor approximation around the optimal assignment of a more general production technology. Since the …rst derivative of a continuous production function equals zero in the optimal assignment, Y 0 (0) = 0, the …rst-order term drops out. We are interested in equilibria where unemployed job seekers do not accept all job o¤ers, which imposes a minimum constraint on .3 Labor supply and the value of non-market time Labor supply per s-type is uniformly distributed over the circumference of the circle. Total labor supply in period t equals L(t). We normalize the labor force at t = 0 to one. Unemployed workers receive the value of non-market time B. Employed workers supply a …xed amount of labor (normalized to one), and their payo¤ is equal to the wage they receive. Workers live forever. They maximize the discounted value of their expected lifetime payo¤s. Golden-growth path We study the economy while it is on a golden-growth path, where the discount rate > 0 is equal to the growth rate of the labor force. Hence, the size of the labor force is L(t) = exp( t). The assumption of a golden-growth path buys us a lot in terms of transparency and tractability. The golden-growth assumption is a generalisation of the assumption of zero discounting (zero discounting is the special case of the golden-growth being equal to zero), an assumption that is often applied in the wage posting literature, see for example Burdett and Mortensen (1998). New workers enter the labor force as unemployed. Since labor supply at t = 0 and the productivity in the optimal assignment Y (0) are normalized to one, the output of this economy would be equal to one in the 3

A su¢ cient condition for this is that Y (x) < 0 for at least some x.

5

absence of search frictions. Job o¤er arrival rates and job destruction Unemployed job seekers receive job o¤ers at a rate . Workers receive job o¤ers at a rate . The parameter search;

;0

1; measures the e¢ ciency of on- relative to o¤-the-job

= 0 is the case without OJS;

= 1 is the case where on- and o¤-the-job search

are equally e¢ cient. Matches between workers and jobs are destroyed at an exogenous rate

> 0.

As is well known in the job search literature, see e.g. Burdett and Mortensen (1998), the number of parameters can be reduced by introducing a composite parameter4 , 2 : + Hence, we can ignore the separate parameters ; ; and , and focus on the composite parameter

instead.

Vacancy creation and contact technology For our empirical analysis, we can ignore the process of vacancy creation and the job o¤er arrival technology that underlies the value of . However, when analyzing the output loss due to search frictions and the constrained e¢ ciency of the equilibrium, we have to be explicit about vacancy creation and the contact technology. We assume that there is free entry of vacancies for all c-types. The cost of maintaining a vacancy is equal to K per period. After a vacancy is …lled, the …rm’s only cost is the worker’s wage. The supply of vacancies is determined by a zero pro…t condition. Vacancies are uniformly distributed over the circumference of the circle. When a worker leaves a job, this job disappears. Let u be the unemployment rate. Due to the normalization of labor supply to one, u is equal to the number of unemployed. Then, the e¤ective number of job seekers is equal to the number of unemployed plus the number of employed weighted by the relative e¢ ciency of on-the-job search, u +

(1

u). The job-o¤er-arrival rate

4

is a function of

It is convenient to add a factor 2 to the de…nition of to account for the fact that this model is symmetric around the optimal allocation x = 0. Hence, job o¤ers with positive and negative values of x are equivalent.

6

the e¤ective supply of job seekers and the number of vacancies, v: = where 0 = 0 and

( ; )

(1

u)]

(2)

v ;

1. This speci…cation embodies two important special cases: (i) for

= ;0 <

< 1,

=

to-scale matching function; (ii) for that for

[u +

0

= 1, the value of

0

: the classical Pissarides constant-returns-

(u=v)

= 1;

= 0: the quadratic contact technology. Note

is irrelevant. Hence, the case

= 1;

= 1 is equivalent to

the quadratic contact technology in this setting. Finally, note that for our purposes, we do not need to know K because any decrease in K can be captured by a corresponding increase in .5

6

Wage setting Wages, denoted by W (x), are set unilaterally by the …rm, conditional on the mismatch indicator x in the current job. We analyze wage setting under two di¤erent assumptions. Under the …rst assumption, …rms can commit to a future wage payment contingent on x. Then, …rms pay both no-quit and hiring premiums. That is, they account for the positive e¤ect of a higher wage o¤er on reduced quitting and increased hiring as in Burdett and Mortensen (1988). Under the second assumption, …rms are unable to commit to future wage payments. In this case, hiring premiums are non-credible because immediately after the worker has accepted the job, the …rm has no incentive to continue paying a hiring premium, since the worker cannot return to her previous job. Workers anticipate this, and will therefore not respond to this premium in the …rst place, which means that …rms will not o¤er it. No-quit premiums are credible even without commitment because it is in the …rm’s interest to pay them as soon as the worker has accepted the job, for if the …rm does not pay them the worker will quit as soon as a better outside o¤er arrives. 5

Shifting K to 2K so that v shifts to v=2 together with shifting 0 to 2 0 does not e¤ect the equilibrium. 6 2 The number of free parameters can be reduced even further. If we replace by , can be normalized to one. When we simultaneously increase to 2 and to 4 , this is equivalent to increasing simultaneously the job search e¢ ciency and the cost of a bad match. As a result, the upper bound x would shrink to 12 x, but for the rest, everything would remain the same. The composite parameter can be interpreted as a summary statistic for search frictions. Details of this transformation are in Web Appendix C.4 In our empirical application, we need a particular normalization for x and, so we do not apply the …nal normalization here.

7

Since the equilibrium of this economy and its comparative statics are analyzed extensively in Gautier, Teulings, and Van Vuuren (2010), we will only provide a short summary of the main results that are needed for the empirical implementation, below.

2.2

Characterization of the equilibrium

The equilibrium of this economy is characterized by a wage function W (x) and an upper bound x for the absolute value of the mismatch indicator jxj. Job o¤ers with a higher value of x will not be accepted. Since the model is symmetric around x = 0, W (jxj) = W (x). For sake of notational convenience, we focus on the case x

0. Wages are decreasing

in the mismatch indicator x: the lower the mismatch, the higher the wage rate paid by …rms.7 The upper bound x implies a value for u (for a derivation see Web Appendix C.1) u=

1 : 1+ x

Note that the model is very similar to the stochastic job search model of Pissarides (2000) extended with on-the-job search and the constraint that the derivative of Y (x) is zero in the optimal assignment, x = 0.8 A worker accepts any job o¤er with a wage above his current wage and consequently with a mismatch indicator smaller than in his current job. Unemployed workers accept only job o¤ers with x < x. Bellman equations under the Golden Growth assumption Due to the golden-growth assumption, asset values for job seekers and employed workers take a simple form that can be easily interpreted. Let V U and V E be the asset values of an unemployed and an employed worker at her marginal job type (with mismatch indicator x) respectively and let Ex Y and Ex W denote the expected output and wage respectively (the expectation being taken over the mismatch indicator x among employed workers). 7

See Gautier et al. (2010) for a proof. The logic is the same as why bid functions in auction theory are increasing in valuations. 8 The only di¤erence is that under free entry the composition of vacancies adjusts to the composition of the unemployment.

8

Then V U = uB + (1 u) Ex W; uW (x) + (1 u) Ex W VE = ; u + (1 u) vK = (1 u) (Ex Y Ex W ) :

(3)

The derivation of these Bellman equations can be found in Web Appendix C.2. The values of unemployment and employment are a weighted average of the expected payo¤s in the states of employment and unemployment. For the value of unemployment, the expected payo¤s are weighted by their share in the total population. The total expected cost of vacancy creation are equal to expected pro…ts, which in turn are equal to expected productivity minus expected wages times employment. The Bellman equations take this simple form due to the Golden Growth assumption that the growth rate of the workforce is equal to the discount rate. The output loss due to search frictions The output loss due to search frictions can be de…ned as, X

(1

u) (1

Ex Y ) + u (1

B) + vK:

(4)

The output loss is made up of the three components, each of them re‡ected by a term in equation (4). The loss due to: (i) mismatch, (ii) unemployment, and (iii) the cost of vacancy creation and recruitment. The loss due to mismatch is equal to the employment rate 1

u times the di¤erence between productivity in the optimal assignment, Y (0) = 1,

and the expected productivity in the actual assignment, Ex Y . The loss due to unemployment is equal to the unemployment rate u times the di¤erence between the productivity in the optimal assignment and the value of non-market time 1

B. The cost of vacancies

is equal to the vacancy rate v times the cost of a vacancy K. Two components of this output loss are hard to measure, namely the cost of vacancies vK and the productivity loss due to mismatch Ex Y . However, under free entry, all pro…ts are spent on vacancy creation so we can substitute equation (4) in. After some rearrangement, we obtain X = u (1

B) + (1

u) (1 9

Ex W ) = 1

V U:

(5)

The simple relation X = 1

V U can be understood easily. Without search frictions,

workers would be costlessly assigned to their optimal assignment where they earn a wage equal to one and there would be no vacancy cost. Equations (4) and (5) allow us to estimate the output loss due to search frictions and decompose this loss into its three components. Wage formation The de…nition of x as the upper bound of the mismatch indicator implies that for this level of x; wages are equal to output 1 2 x: 2

c (x) = Yb (x) = 1 W

(6)

At the marginal job type, all the surplus should go to the worker. If not, the …rms would expand their matching set. On the worker side, the de…nition of x being the upper bound of x implies that an unemployed worker is indi¤erent between accepting this job or staying unemployed. Hence, V E = V U . Substituting equation (3) in this condition yields c (x) = [u + W

c (x) Since Ex W > B, W When

(1

u)] B + (1

[u +

(1

u)]) Ex W:

(7)

B: the lowest wage is greater or equal to the value of leisure.

< 1, a job seeker reduces his chances of …nding an even better job by accepting

a job. The excess of the marginal wage o¤er relative to the value of leisure compensates for this loss in the option value of …nding a better job. Only when on- and o¤-the-job c (x) = B. search are equally e¢ cient, = 1, equation (7) simpli…es to W Next, consider the wage for better matches, 0

x < x We have two cases, one

where …rms can commit on paying hiring premiums and one where …rms cannot; for a full derivation, we refer to Gautier et al. (2010) and web Appendix C.4. When …rms can commit on future wage payments, the optimal wage policy of the …rm maximizes the expected value of a vacancy. Even though …rms have all the bargaining power, they pay positive wages in order to (i) stimulate new workers to come and (ii) prevent existing workers from quitting. When …rms cannot commit on future wage payments, hiring premiums are non-credible since …rms would stop paying them as soon as the worker has accepted the job. Hence, …rms only pay no quit premia. 10

1 output no OJS: bargaining commitment noncommitment

0.95 0.9 0.85 0.8 0.75 0.7 0.65

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

mismatch: x

c (z) in di¤erent regimes, B = 0:4; Figure 1: Productivity Yb (z) and the shape of W = 1:8, is chosen such that u = 5%

= 0:54,

c (x) for both cases with and without commitment. We Figure 1 depicts Yb (x) and W

use the benchmark values for B; ; and which will be motivated in Section 3.4 below. c (x) is non-di¤erentiable at x = 0. This is due to the hiring and noContrary to Yb (x), W

quit premiums that …rms pay. Since the density of employment is highest for low values of jxj, the elasticity of labor supply is high for these types of jobs. A slight variation in wages has large e¤ects both on the probability that workers accept an outside job o¤er and on the number of workers who are prepared to accept the wage o¤er (the latter being relevant in the case with commitment only). Hence, …rms will bid up wages aggressively for those types of jobs. Figure 1 shows that the wage in the optimal assignment is higher when …rms can commit than when they cannot, since the ability to commit increases competition between …rms for workers. Figure 1 also reveals that for x = 0 the slope of the wage function is smaller (in absolute value) for the case with commitment than without commitment. The dashed line is the wage function that would apply under Nash bargaining without OJS which underlies the analysis in Gautier and Teulings (2006). This wage function does not feature the non-di¤erentiability at x = 0. It is just a simple parabola. In this paper we extend the methodology applied in Gautier and Teulings (2006) for estimating search frictions to the more complex shape of the wage function for the case with OJS. Note

11

that without OJS, we have to assume Nash bargaining, since wage setting by the …rm, as is assumed here, would lead to the Diamond paradox of all wage o¤ers being equal to the value of leisure and the full surplus going to the …rm. With OJS, competition for workers between …rms provides workers with market power (especially for x close to 0) even when they have no bargaining power at all. The distribution of x among employed workers b (x), is given by, The distribution of x among employed workers, G b (x) = 1 G

x (1 +

x : x) x

(8)

See web Appendix C.1 for a derivation. Figure 2 depicts this distribution function and the density function that goes with it. The vertical line gives the upper support, x. The main message from Figure 2 is that the distribution of x has a large probability mass close to zero (the optimal assignment) and a long right tail of bad matches. The median value of x is equal to (1 x = (1

u)=(1 + u) < 1, which is far smaller than the upper support

u)=u for reasonable values of u. In fact, 80% of the workers has x < 5. The

reason for this pattern is that workers who are matched badly quit their jobs fast so their density is low. The reverse holds for good matches, so their density is high. The skewness of the distribution of the mismatch parameter has profound consequences for the di¤erence in wage dispersion between the commitment and no commitment cases. Equilibrium The equilibrium can be summarized by three relations as a function of the model’s four parameters B; ;

and c (0) W

Yb (0)

f (B; ; ; ) ; Ex W = W

(9)

1 Var [x] ; Ex Y = Ye (B; ; ; ) = 2 u = u (B; ; ; ) :

For all three relations there are two versions, one for the case with commitment and one for the case without. The analytical expressions for these functions are presented c (0) Ex W , the max-mean wage di¤erential, in Web appendices, C.5, C.1 and C.4. W 12

1 G(x) g(x)

0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0

0

5

10

15

20

mismatch: x

Figure 2: The distribution (solid) and density function (dashed) of x conditional on employment, parameters same as in Figure 1 can be interpreted as a measure of wage dispersion or the wage loss due to mismatch. f (B; ; ; ), Ye (B; ; ; ) and For the relevant range of , the partial derivatives of W u (B; ; ; ) with respect to

frictions (a lower value of

are negative. Other things equal, an increase in search

) leads to more wage dispersion, more output loss due to

mismatch, and more unemployment. These relations lay the foundations for our empirical inference. The max-min wage di¤erential is larger in the case with commitment because the maximum is higher, see Figure 1, other statistics of wage dispersion (based on the lowest wage) may lead to the opposite conclusion, since most of the probability mass of employment is close to the optimal assignment. In that region, the wage function W (x) is steeper in the case without commitment, leading to larger wage di¤erentials.9 Constrained e¢ ciency Gautier, Teulings, and Van Vuuren (2010) show that for the special case, and o¤-the-job search equally e¢ cient) and a quadratic job search technology, 9

= 1 (on= 1, com-

This is also the reason that the min-mean wage di¤erential used in Hornstein et.al. (2010) is more sensitive to small variations in the models parameters and to measurement error in the minimum. Since our approach uses the max-mean wage di¤erential, it is less sensitive to this problem.

13

mitment yields constrained e¢ ciency. By the zero pro…t condition, …rms create vacancies till the point that the net present value of expected quasi rents (1

u) (Ex Y

Ex W ) is

equal to the cost of a vacancy. Since non-commitment generates higher quasi rents for …rms than commitment, non-commitment leads to excess vacancy creation. Cai et.al. (2014) show numerically that the e¢ ciency result for the case of commitment extends to lower values of ; 0:25 <

3 3.1

< 1.10

Estimation Measuring mismatch

Our basic strategy for empirical inference is the same as in Gautier and Teulings (2006). They estimate the output loss due to search frictions for a model without OJS. This subsection …rst summarizes their results and then we extend them to the case with OJS. Gautier, Teulings and Van Vuuren (2005) show that the Taylor approximations of the search equilibrium in a hierarchical model without OJS correspond one-to-one to the equilibrium in a circle model. We apply the same analogy here. In this analogy, it makes sense to talk about a worker’s type s as an index of her skill and about the job’s type c as an index of its complexity. The idea is to establish empirical counterparts for these skill and complexity indices and then calculate the implied mismatch indicator as the di¤erence between both indicators: x

s

c. Skilled workers are assumed to have an absolute

advantage in any job type and have a comparative advantage in complex jobs. Hence, in a Walrasian equilibrium, better-skilled workers earn higher wages. Comparative advantage as de…ned here requires log supermodularity in the production function: better skilled workers are relatively more productive in more complex jobs. Therefore, skilled workers sort into complex jobs and hence wages are an increasing function of job complexity. Those features do not necessarily carry over to a world with search frictions (see Shimer and Smith, 2000), but under a log supermodular production function they do in expectation.11 10

For < 1, the standard congestion externalities apply and in that case the commitment case does not generate the socially e¢ cient outcome. 11 See Gautier and Teulings (2006) footnote 7 for a more detailed analysis of this issue. See also Eeckhout and Kircher (2011).

14

We use these positive correlations between the worker skill and job-complexity indices on the one hand, and wages, on the other hand to construct indices of worker’s skill and job’s complexity. For this purpose, we run two regressions: one of demeaned log wages on worker characteristics, like gender, race, years of education and experience, and one on job characteristics, like occupation and industry dummies. Details are in Web appendix C.7. The estimated parameter vector can then be used to construct indices for the observed worker and job characteristics sb and b c. Both indices sb and b c have zero mean (since wages are demeaned) and are uncorrelated to their unobserved components

"s and "c ; respectively. Thus, the skill measure is the predicted log wage conditional on standard worker characteristics and the job complexity level is the predicted log wage conditional on job characteristics. Having estimated both indices, the proxy for x is constructed as x b

sb

b c. This way of constructing the skill index sb implies that the

choice of dimension of s is such that the Mincerian rate of return on the skill index is equal to one: dEx [ln W ] =ds = dEx [ln W ] =db s = 1. Moreover, this speci…cation implies that ln W is linear in sb and b c. A similar implication holds for the complexity index b c.

These characteristics are just convenient normalizations of the units of measurements that imply no loss of generality.

Gautier and Teulings (2006) run wage regressions for six countries where they enter both sb and b c simultaneously, joint with their second order terms

c + ! ss sb2 + ! sc sbb c + ! ccb c2 + ": ln W = ! 0 + ! s sb + ! cb

Since neither E[b s2 ], nor E[b sb c], nor E[b c2 ] are equal to zero, an intercept is added to the regression. This intercept will play a crucial role. For all six countries and

cc

< 0, and roughly

sc

=

2

ss

=

2

cc .

ss

< 0;

sc

> 0;

This …nding is consistent with the idea

that the …nal three terms measure the e¤ect of the mismatch indicator x b2 = (b s

b c)2 on

wages. Below we reiterate their result for the United States, which are taken from the

15

March supplements of the CPS 1989-1992 (t-values in brackets). ln W = 0:013 + 0:61b s + 0:66b c

0:17b s2

ln W = 0:024 + 0:61b s + 0:66b c

2

(8:9)

(14:7)

(182:4)

(182:2)

(207:7)

(207:5)

Var [b x] = 0:120:

(21:2)

0:20 x b;

(35:1)

sb c; 0:17b c2 + 0:43b (21:6)

(36:6)

(10) (11)

The coe¢ cients on sb and b c are between zero and one and highly signi…cant. Since at

the optimal assignment there is a one-to-one correspondence between s and c, we cannot

conclude much from the …rst order terms. The one could be a proxy for the measurement

error in the other and the other way around. The second-order terms enter also highly signi…cantly, with the expected signs. In the second regression we impose the restriction sc

=

2

ss

=

2

cc .

Although a formal F-test rejects them due to the large number of

observations, these restrictions hold almost perfectly. This applies to all six countries. Gautier and Teulings (2006) provide two arguments why the second order terms are likely to capture the e¤ect of search frictions, which we reiterate here shortly. First, when observed and unobserved worker and job characteristics are distributed jointly normal, it is impossible for second-order terms to be a proxy for the unobserved component of a …rst-order term, because the correlation of a second-order term in sb and/or b c with the unobserved skill index is a third moment and third moments of a normal distribution are equal to zero. Second, the interpretation of these coe¢ cients as capturing the concavity of

the wage function implies sign restrictions, which are met for all three coe¢ cients for all six countries. We add one new argument here.12 If the signi…cance of the second-order terms is indeed driven by the concavity of the wage function in the mismatch indicator, then their sign would depend on sb and b c capturing worker and job characteristics respectively. To the contrary, if both vectors were composed out of mixtures of job and worker characteristics (e.g. experience and occupation dummies in sb and education and industry dummies in b c)

then the concavity result should not come out. Equation (12) demonstrates this by putting education and occupation in sb, while equation (13) demonstrates it by putting education and industry in sb (and the remaining variables in b c). In both cases, the concavity result 12

We thank Jean Marc Robin for the idea of this test.

16

disappears sb c 0:04b c2 + 0:09b

ln W = 0:00 + 0:52b s + 0:65b c

0:01b s2

ln W = 0:00 + 0:32b s + 0:81b c

0:01b s2 + 0:01b c2 + 0:05b sb c

(0:0)

(0:0)

(132:6)

(79:9)

(175:2)

(233:2)

(0:9)

(4:4)

(4:1)

(1:1)

(12)

(6:2)

(13)

(3:5)

Also note that the constant moves towards zero in that case. Hence, the concavity result in (10) is not a statistical artifact. The quadratic terms in equation (10) correspond nicely to the model without OJS, where the wage function W (x) follows a smooth parabola, see Figure 1. Then, the only remaining question is to what extent the coe¢ cient on x b2 is a¤ected by measurement

error. Here, we want to apply this methodology to a model with OJS. But then we have to …nd a method for …tting a wage function that is not a simple parabola, but a more complicated function that is non-di¤erentiable at x = 0. This question will be addressed below.

3.2

Capturing the shape of W (x)

The …rst step in …nding a tractable approach to estimating the function ln W (x) is to consider a simple Taylor expansion around the optimal assignment, x = 0. In section 4 when we calibrate the model, we will use the exact expressions and test how well the approximations below perform. Start from the circle model. Then ! 2 jxj + O x2 ;

ln W (x) = ! 0

(14)

where we demean the data on ln W , such that Ex ln W = 0. The wage curves in Figure 1 imply that ! 2 > 0. If there were no search frictions, then x = 0 at all job types and therefore ! 0 = 0. By construction, ! 0 is approximately equal to our measure of wage dispersion, the max-mean wage di¤erential. ! 0 = ! 2 E [jxj] = ln W (0)

Ex ln W & ln W (0)

ln Ex W & W (0)

Ex W:

(15)

The …rst equality follows from taking expectations at the left- and right-hand sides of (14) and using Ex ln W = 0 (by demeaning). The second equality follows from evaluating (14) at x = 0: The next approximate equality is due to Jensen’s inequality, lnEx W &Ex ln W . 17

For the third step, note that for small search frictions –and accordingly, small wage di¤erentials–Ex W . W (0) . 1, the approximation ln W . W W (0) ' 1, W (0) Ex W ' [W (0)

1 applies. Finally, since

Ex W ] =W (0). Hence, ! 0 is a convenient statistic for

the relative wage loss due to search frictions. In practice we observe x with a fair amount of measurement error. What are the implications of this? Let "x

"c

"s be the measurement error in the observed signal x b; x b = x + "x ;

with Cov[x; "x ] = 0.13 Hence, Var[b x] =Var[x] +

(16)

2 ",

where

2 "

Var["x ]. Measurement

error is particularly relevant when estimating the e¤ect of mismatch, since the observed mismatch x b can either be due to true mismatch or to measurement error. In a perfect

Walrasian world, there is no mismatch, since s = c for each job. Hence, x = 0. A careless

researcher would ’observe’mismatch since the observed skill and complexity indexes are not equal, sb 6= b c; due to unobserved heterogeneity in s and c. Hence, the ’observed’ mismatch x b is equal to the measurement error: x b = sb

b c = "x since x = 0 for each

job. Failing to correct for the impact of measurement error will therefore overestimate the importance of mismatch.

De…ne the signal-to-noise ratio R

Var[x] =Var[b x]. If the approximation of ln W (x)

in equation (14) would be exact, estimating this equation with OLS (replacing jxj by jb xj) would yield a downwardly-biased estimate of ! 2 for two reasons. First, attenuation bias due to measurement error biases the coe¢ cient on the explanatory variables towards zero; and second, there is the strong convexity at zero. Due to this convexity, E [jxj jb x]

jb xj :

The closer x b is to zero, the stronger this inequality. This is documented in Figure 3, where we present three functions, jb xj, E[jxj jb x], and the least-squares estimation of E[jxj jb x] = 13

By construction, Cov["s ; sb] = Cov["c ; b c] = 0. Hence, "s and "c measure unobserved heterogeneity in s and c. This does not apply to the mismatch indicator x b, where Cov["x ; x b] > 0. This can be seen most easily by considering the limiting case of zero search frictions (the Walrasian equilibrium), where Var[x] = 0 and Var[b x] =Var["x ] 0, since s = c and hence "x = x b. For small search frictions, Var[x] Var["x ], Cov["x ; x] = 0. Hence, "x can be interpreted as pure classical measurement error in the observed mismatch indicator x b. The signal-to-noise ratio that we …nd empirically supports this interpretation, see Section 4.

18

3.5

3

2.5

2

1.5

1

0.5

0 -3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

Figure 3: Smoothing of an absolute value function by random mixing for jxj (black thin), E[jxj j^ x] (blue dotted), least- squares estimate (red solid) 0

+

b2 + 2x

2 x

=

2 "

= 1:

", for the case that both the true value x and measurement error "x are

normally distributed –both with variance equal to unity. The least-squares approximation of E[jxj jb x] turns out to be extremely precise for the relevant range between plus- and minus

two standard deviations of x b 2 [ 2; 2]. This justi…es the idea of approximating equation (14) by a regression model of w with a quadratic term x b2 : ln W = ! 0

!2x b2 + ";

(17)

where " is a zero mean error term. This is a surprising result: while the wage function W (x) with OJS is entirely di¤erent from the wage function without OJS, a second order polynomial is again an accurate approximation of the relation between log wages and the observed proxy for mismatch, x b in the presence of measurement error.

The following proposition relates the least-squares estimate ! 0 to the underlying co-

e¢ cient ! 0 .

Proposition 1 Suppose (i) that the true model is given by ln W = ! 0

19

! 2 jxj ;

where both ln W and x are normalized to have a zero mean, (ii) that we observe only x b = x + "x where both x and "x are distributed normally with Var[x] =Var[b x]

R; (iii)

that we estimate equation (17) by OLS. Then,

1 1 plim! 0 = R! 0 = R! 2 Ejxj: 2 2

Proof: See Appendix A.3. Hence, when there is no measurement error in the observed signal x b (R = 1), the

estimated intercept ! 0 is equal to half the true intercept ! 0 . This underestimation by a factor two is due to the imperfect approximation of the absolute value function by a parabola. When on top of this imperfection in the functional form, there is also measurement error in the signal x b, the underestimation becomes more severe. However, as Figure

3 shows, a parabola provides a very good description for E[jxj] when x is convoluted with measurement error, in particular when R < 1=2. Hence, using a parabola is an e¢ cient

way of estimating ! 0 . Given the measurement error in the data, one cannot do much better by using alternative estimation methods. The estimate of ! 0 is proportional to the signal-to-noise ratio R: Under the assumption of joint normality of x b and "x , Proposition 2 and equation (15) imply that the intercept ! 0 underestimates the true magnitude of wage dispersion by a factor 2=R:

2 W (0) Ex W = !0: W (0) R

(18)

Equation (18) provides a very convenient relation. Twice the intercept of a simple OLS regression, 2! 0 , provides a robust estimate for the magnitude of the wage loss due to search frictions. The estimation results in equation (10) imply ! 0 = 0:024. Hence, the relative wage loss due to mismatch [W (0)

Ex W ] =W (0) is at least 4.8%. This is the limiting

case of R = 1, when there is no measurement error. In the presence of measurement error, the wage loss due to mismatch is larger. Since Var[x] = RVar[b x], the productivity loss due to mismatch follows from Y (0)

Ex Y =

1 1 E[x2 ] = RVar [b x] : 2 2

Conditional on , the variance of the observed mismatch indicator Var[b x] overestimates the productivity loss due to mismatch by a factor R, exactly the reverse of the underestimation 20

of the expected wage dispersion. The latter is due to the fact that part of the variance of a noisy mismatch indicator does not re‡ect true mismatch, but just noise. The elimination of R from these two expressions yields [W (0)

Ex W ] [Y (0)

f (B; ; ; ) Ye (B; ; ; ) = ! 0 Var [b Ex Y ] = W x] :

(19)

Equation (19) is a key equation. It establishes a relation between the four parameters of the model, B; ;

and

on the left hand side and the parameter

and the estimated

statistics ! 0 and Var[b x] on the right hand side. For given , the product of wage and productivity dispersion is not a¤ected by measurement error. More measurement error in x, increases Var[b x] by the same factor as it decreases ! 0 :

3.3

Measuring

and its role in identi…cation

Teulings (2005) shows that there exists a one-to-one correspondence between the Katz and Murphy (1992) elasticity of complementarity between low and high skilled workers, low-high ,

and the parameter .14 Katz and Murphy estimate this elasticity to be 1.4 for

the period 1963-87: a 1% increase in the ratio between high- and low-skilled workers yields a 1.4% fall in the relative wages of high-skilled workers. Suppose that the data are generated by a continuous type model like ours, but that the researcher arbitrarily divides the workforce into two groups, high and low skilled, where all workers below a certain threshold value for s are assigned to the low skilled group and all workers above that threshold are assigned to the high skilled group. When this researcher then tries to estimate

low-high ,

he will obtain the following result: =

1 Var [ln W ]

= low-high

Katz and Murphy (1992)’s benchmark value for value for Var[ln W ] of 0.40) period 1975-87, choosing low-high of

4 yields

1 0:40 low-high

: low-high

of 1:4 yields (using the empirical

= 1:8. Their discussion on pages 71-72 suggests that for the

low-high

= 4, performs better than 1:4. The alternative value for

= 0:6. Better substitutability of worker types reduces the output loss

due to mismatch. 14

In the web appendix C.6, we show that the units of s (dE[ln W ] =ds = 1) are the same as in Teulings (2005) so we can transfer his …ndings to this paper.

21

Figure 4 illustrates the situation for both the commitment and non-commitment cases, using the benchmark values for B;

; and

from the next section. The upward-sloped f (B; ; ; ) and productivity loss curve (red) consists of combinations of wage loss W Ye (B; ; ; ) from equation (9). Each point on the curve corresponds to di¤erent values of . When there are more search frictions (low ), there is both more wage dispersion

and more mismatch. The downward-sloped curve (blue) re‡ects equation (19), using the values of ! 0 ; and Var[b x] discussed above. This yields a hyperbolic relation between f (B; ; ; ) and Ye (B; ; ; ). Each point on this curve corresponds to a di¤erent value W f (B; ; ; ) = 2! 0 = 4:8%. of the signal-to-noise ratio R. In the North-West, R = 1 and W

Note that R is not a completely free parameter because the model restricts the curves to intersect at values for R 1. The lower R, the more Var[b x] overestimates Var[x] and f (B; ; ; ) is underestimated. The intersection of hence Ye (B; ; ; ), but the more W

both curves determines

and R.

Wage di¤erentials are generally larger than productivity di¤erentials, which is due to the fact that the derivative of the production function is zero in the optimum, Y 0 (0) = 0, while the wage function is non-di¤erentiable at that point. Since x = 0 is the point with the highest density, this point matters a lot for the relative size of productivity and wage di¤erentials.15 The ultimate test of the model is to see whether the implied f (B; ; ; ) and value of unemployment is realistic. Figure 5 plots the relation between W u (B; ; ; ). The two points on the curves in Figures 4 and 5 denote the exact solutions, which will be discussed in Section 4. A higher value of

shifts the locus of equation (19)

to the North-East in Figure 4. For a given amount of wage dispersion, a higher

implies

x]). At the intersection with the upward sloped more output loss due to mismatch ( 12 Var[b f (B; ; ; ) and Ye (B; ; ; ) are higher. Figure 5 shows locus of equation (9), both W f (B; ; ; ) that corresponds to = 1:8, implies a value of the that the higher value of W unemployment rate around 10% (the exact solutions imply a lower u). 15

Note that for the model without OJS in Gautier and Teulings (2006), productivity di¤erentials are always larger than wage di¤erentials.

22

0.12 theoretical relation: non-commitment theoretical relation: commitment match data: γ = 0.6

mismatch (Y(0)-E(Y))

0.1

match data: γ = 1.8

0.08

0.06

0.04

0.02

0 0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

wage dispersion (W (0)-E(W))

Figure 4: Identi…cation, the role of

(B = 0:4,

= 0:54)

0.35

non-commitment commitment

unemployment

0.3

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.05

0 0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

wage dispersion (W (0)-E(W))

Figure 5: Unemployment (B = 0:4,

23

= 0:54)

3.4

The values of B and

Hall and Milgrom derive a value for B based on UI bene…ts of 0.25 and an estimated Frisch elasticity of labor supply of 1. This implies a value of B = 0:71.16 In our setting, where we are interested in the mean or median worker, such a high value would have the unpleasant implication that if nobody would work in the US, per capita output would only be 27% lower than in case everybody would be at her optimal job. Therefore, we think it is more reasonable to set B = 0:4 following Shimer (2005). As a robustness check, we also calibrate our model for B = 0:6. The value of

is identi…ed from the relation between the ratio of the (average)

employment-to-employment hazard rate, fee ; and the employment-to-unemployment hazard rate, feu , see Appendix A.2 1+q fee = ln (1 + q) 1; feu q 1 u (B; ; ; ) q : u (B; ; ; ) Since q is an increasing function of fee

=feu . Hence,

=

u(B; ; ; ) 1 u(B; ; ; )

(20)

fee

=feu , its inverse exists. Denote this inverse by

fee

=feu . Identi…cation of the model proceeds along

the same lines as in Figure 4, but now taking B and

fee

=feu as given instead of B and .

Monthly transition rates from 1967-2010 similar to Shimer (2007) imply that feu = 2:13% per month for the mean worker. The value of fee is 2.7% according to Fallick and Fleischman (2004), 2.9% according to Nagypal, and 3.3% according to Moscarini and Vella (2008), applying a correction for missing records in the CPS.17 Hence, for the mean worker,

2:7 (= 2:13

1:27)

fee =feu

3:3 (= 2:13

1:55):18

16

Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008) and Hall (2009) seek to explain the cyclical behavior of unemployment, so they use larger values for B. For these studies, the value of non-market time of the marginal worker is relevant whereas here we are interested in the value of non-market time for the average worker, which justi…es a lower value of B. 17 Nagypal’s values come from the SIPP and the CPS. She argues that those estimates are downwardly biased because when workers change jobs it is not uncommon for them to experience a short unemployment spell. In the data, this yields an employment-unemployment transition followed by an unemployment-employment transition. This bias might be larger than the time aggregation bias in the unemployment out‡ow rate. 18 We thank Bart Hobijn for sharing his data.

24

If we consider the median worker, a lower value for feu applies. This can be seen as follows. According to the BLS statistics, median tenure is 4.6 years.19 In the absence of duration dependence and ignoring the ‡ow out of the labor force, the total hazard out of the current job, fee + feu , is 1.3%.20 The transition rate feu (the equivalent of ) is assumed to be constant in our model, while the unconditional transition rate, fee ; exhibits negative duration dependence due to heterogeneity in the match quality x: high quality matches survive. Negative duration dependence implies that the hazard rate for low-tenure workers is above 1.3% and the rate for high-tenure workers is below 1.3%. Since feu is constant, it must be smaller than 1.3%, much lower than the value reported by Shimer. This implies that the assumption of the absence of duration dependence of feu is rejected by the data. Apparently, a small group of weakly attached workers frequently transits between unemployment and employment. In order to capture this feature of reality, other mechanisms must be introduced (such as learning, see Moscarini (2005); or random growth, see Buhai and Teulings (2014)). This falls outside the scope of this paper. Hence, our model is unable to explain this feature of reality. We set fee =feu = 1:75 in our preferred calibration, but we check the robustness of our results for higher values of fee =feu in Appendix B.

4

Calibration

The methodology applied in the previous section requires two approximations. First, we approximate ln W (x) by a …rst order Taylor expansion in Section 3.2, using the absolute value transformation:

! 2 jxj. Second, we approximate the distribution of x by the

normal distribution, see Proposition 2, while its actual distribution is far from normal, see Figure 2. In this section, we use the exact expressions to calibrate our model. The calibration proceeds as follows, 1. We set B = 0:4 and

= 1:8 (our preferred values, see the discussion in the previous

section). 19

www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/tenure.pdf Ignoring ‡ows out of the labor force, the total hazard out of employment can be solved from 1 exp [ 55 (fee + feu )] = 0:5: 20

25

2. Take starting values for

and .

3. Var[x] can be calculated directly, see (31) in Web Appendix C.5. The variance of 2 ";

the measurement error distribution, 2 "

can be calculated from

= Var[^ x]

Var [x] ;

using the empirical value Var[^ x] = 0:12. Note that consistency requires Var[^ x] Var[x], which is an additional test for the model (i.e. the intersection of the blue and red curve in Figure 4 occurs before the end point of the blue curve that corresponds to R = 1 in the north west). This condition turns out to hold in our calibration. 4. The fee =feu ratio in the model follows from (20) while the simulated ! 0 is obtained b as follows. First draw values from G(x), see (8). Next, add measurement error using the value of

2 "

from step 3 and run regression (17). Compare the simulated

values for fee =feu and ! 0 to the empirical values, fee =feu = 1:75 and ! 0 = 0:0241. As long as they do not match, adjust

and

and return to step 2 till convergence

is reached. This procedure converges fast (also for the alternative calibration in Web Appendix B). Table 1 presents the implied values for our key variables. u(%)

W (0)

E xW

Ex W=W (x) Y (0)

commitment

yes

4:72

no

yes

4:48 0:58

no

yes

0:54 6:04

no

Ex Y

R(%)

x100

x100

yes

8:01 1:51

no

yes

1:44 2:32

Table 1: Calibration results for B = 0:4; f ee=f eu = 1:75;

no

yes

no

2:39 21:5

22:2

= 1:8

The implied unemployment rate in Table 1 is in the reasonable range for both the commitment (4:72%) and non-commitment case (4:48%). Hence, the data do not allow us to discriminate between commitment and non-commitment. On-the-job search is about half as e¢ cient as o¤-the-job search. The mean-min ratio predicted by the model is similar to the one reported by Hornstein et al. (2010) if they use the 10th percentile as the lowest 26

wage. The signal-noise ratio R may appear low at …rst sight. However, remember that R would be 0 in the Walrasian case, see the discussion regarding equation (16). Hence, there is no natural lower bound for R. Our results also show that the approximations in Section 3.2 overestimated unemployment and wage dispersion. For the no commitment case, the approximations suggested that, W (0) Ex W = 11% and u = 10% while for the commitment case, the approximations would give W (0) Ex W = 11% and u = 11%: In the simulations where we use the exact values we get less wage dispersion (W (0) Ex W equals for commitment and no commitment respectively 6% and 8%) and a lower unemployment rate of 4:5%: The high values in the approximations were mainly due to the fact that there we assumed that x b followed a normal distribution rather than the actual distribution G(x) that we use here

(which is far from normal). The linear approximation of the wage function applied in (14) had little e¤ect. In Tables 3 and 4 in Appendix B we present the calibration results for 8 other combinations of the parameters B; fee =feu ; and . The calibration with B = 0:6,

= 1:8 and

fee =feue = 1:3 gives an implausibly large frictional unemployment rate of 11%. In general, for B = 0:6, the unemployment rate is a bit higher and for for our baseline analysis. and

= 0:6, it is a bit lower than

can increase to almost 1 if we use B = 0:6, fee =feu = 1:75

= 1:8: For the no commitment case, unemployment varies between 2:8 and 12:7 for

the eight di¤erent con…gurations. Figure 4 illustrates what happens if we use di¤erent parameters in the calibration. For example, if we calibrate the model with a higher value of B, this makes the theoretical relationship between wage dispersion and mismatch steeper (the yellow curve). With a higher B, it is harder to generate wage dispersion. A given level of wage dispersion is then associated with more frictions and consequently more mismatch. However, at the new intersection, the corresponding unemployment rate and with the empirical value of fee =feu . Therefore,

are no longer consistent

must increase to shift the yellow curve

back and this is depicted by the green dotted curve. Figure 6 gives the corresponding values of unemployment.

27

0.35 B = 0.4, ψ=0.26 B = 0.6, ψ=0.26 B = 0.6, ψ=0.54

unemployment

0.3

0.25

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.05

0 0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

wage dispersion (W (0)-E(W))

Figure 6: The e¤ect of B on the estimated value of u

0.12 B = 0.4, ψ=0.26 match data: γ = 1.8 B = 0.6, ψ=0.26 B = 0.6, ψ=0.54

mismatch (Y(0)-E(Y))

0.1

0.08

0.06

0.04

0.02

0 0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

wage dispersion (W(0)-E(W))

The e¤ect of B on the estimted value of

4.1

Composition of the output loss and the business-stealing externality

Table 2 shows for our baseline parameters that if …rms can commit to wages, the output loss, X, due to search frictions is 10:0% while if …rms cannot commit, it is 15:5%. A large share of the output loss in the non-commitment case is due to vacancy creation. This is due to the fact that we assume free entry, or equivalently, an in…nite elasticity of vacancy creation with respect to pro…ts per worker. In reality, there will be imperfect competition 28

and part of the pro…ts will be captured by the owners of the …rm. Commitment

yes

no

u(1 B) (1 u) [Ex Y Ex W ] (1 u) [Y (0) Ex Y ] X (%)

2:84 4:43 2:21 9:48

2:69 10:48 2:28 15:45

Table 2: Decomposition of output loss due to frictions forB = 0:4, f ee=f eu = 1:75 The large value of (1

u) (Ex Y

= 1:8 and

Ex W ) for the non-commitment case is socially ine¢ -

cient because of a business-stealing externality (see Gautier et al. 2010). The idea is that without commitment, when opening a vacancy, individual …rms do not internalize the future output loss of the …rm from which they poach a worker. Although the transitions of workers to better matches are always e¢ cient, the expected productivity gains are too small to justify, from a social point of view, the entry cost of the marginal …rm. Tables 5 and 6 in Appendix B present the estimated output loss for the eight di¤erent calibrations and …nd that X varies between 6:42% (commitment, B = 0:4, and 18:78% (non-commitment, B = 0:6,

= 0:6; fee =feu = 1:75)

= 1:8; fee =feu = 1:3).

Estimating the business-stealing externality Table 2 is not suitable to estimate the business-stealing e¤ect because it keeps constant the outcome variable fee =feu , and not the parameter . In order to estimate the businessstealing e¤ect, we use for the commitment case the same parameter values, B = 0:4, = 1:8; and

= 0:54 as in the no-commitment case. Under commitment, there is no

excessive vacancy creation (vK reduces to 4:67) and this makes the unemployment rate slightly higher (5:05%). The output loss due to mismatch under commitment is almost the same (2:33) as for the original calibration. The total output loss due to search frictions is now 15:45% for no commitment and 10:03% for commitment. The di¤erence of almost 5:5% points is the welfare loss due to the existence of a business-stealing externality that arises if …rms cannot commit to wages contingent on x: Note that this estimate is based on the assumption that all excessive rents of the ine¢ cient wage mechanism are spent on 29

vacancy creation. If the rents end up at the …rm owners, the losses will be smaller, since they will derive utility from this income.

5

Conclusion

Due to frictions, only a subset of the contacts between vacancies and workers results in a match, and this creates (i) unemployment, (ii) wage dispersion amongst identical workers and (iii) mismatch. This paper contributes to the literature by measuring these manifestations of search frictions and presenting a model that can jointly explain them (allowing for measurement error). Our methodology yields a very simple and tractable method for estimating wage dispersion due to search frictions using a simple OLS regression on worker and job characteristics. We use the analogy to hedonic pricing models to derive the curvature of the production function from Katz and Murphy’s estimate of the elasticity of complementarity between high and low skilled workers. The output loss due to search frictions only depends on four parameters: the value of non-market time B, the relative e¢ ciency of on-the job search,

and a composite parameter that captures everything

that a¤ects frictions (the e¢ ciency of matching, the discount rate, the job destruction rate, vacancy creation cost and a parameter measuring the cost of mismatch). Search frictions generate output losses directly due to the suboptimal allocation of resources, and indirectly, because decentralized wage mechanisms potentially come with distortions. Allowing for two-sided heterogeneity is extremely important because it is the interaction between the search frictions, the type distributions and the production technology that determines how important these frictions are. If workers and …rms are identical, then all contacts result in a match. Under two-sided heterogeneity, the production technology matters because it determines how much output is lost due to mismatch. The more di¢ cult it is to substitute between worker types, the greater this output loss. By combining information on wage dispersion and the substitutability of worker types we can learn about the actual amount of frictions and the importance of a precise match. We then use our model to quantify and decompose this total output loss. Traditionally, most of the macro labor literature has focussed on unemployment, but our results imply

30

that mismatch and job creation cost are also important. We …nd that this total loss is between 9% and 16%, depending on whether …rms can or cannot commit to wages, on the value of non-market time and on the e¢ ciency of on–relative to o¤-the-job search. Gautier and Teulings (2006) did not allow for on-the-job search, and therefore substantially overestimated the output loss due to frictions.

References [1] Abowd, J.M., F. Kramarz and D.N. Margolis (1998), High wage workers and high wage …rms, Econometrica, 67, 251-333. [2] Atakan, A. (2006), Assortative matching with explicit search costs, Econometrica 74, 667–680. [3] Bagger J. and R. Lentz, An Empirical Model of Wage Dispersion with Sorting, Mimeo University of Wisconsin-Madison. [4] Bartolucci C. and F. Devicienti (2012), Better workers move to better …rms: A simple test to identify sorting, mimeo Collegio Carlo Alberto. [5] Becker, G. S. (1973), A theory of marriage: Part I, Journal of Political Economy 81(4), 813-46. [6] Bontemps, C. J.M. Robin and G.J. Van den Berg (2000), Equilibrium search with continuous productivity dispersion: Theory and nonparametric estimation, International Economic Review, 41, 305-58. [7] Buhai, I.S., and C.N. Teulings (2014), Tenure pro…les and e¢ cient separation in a stochastic productivity model, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, forthcoming. [8] Bound, J. and A. Krueger (1991), The extent of measurement error in longitudinal earnings data: Do two wrongs make a right?, Journal of Labor Economics, 9, 1-24. [9] Burdett K. and D. Mortensen (1998), Equilibrium wage di¤erentials and employer size, International Economic Review, 39, 257-274.

31

[10] Coles M. (2001), Equilibrium wage dispersion, …rm size, and growth, Review of Economic Dynamics, 4-1,159-187. [11] Cornfeld, O. (2012), The price of talent, mimeo Tel Aviv University. [12] Dickens, W. and L.F. Katz (1987), Inter-industry wage di¤erences and theories of wage determination, NBER working paper No. 2271. [13] Eeckhout, J. and P. Kircher (2011), Identifying sorting, in theory, Review of Economic Studies 78-3, 872-906. [14] Eeckhout, J. and P. Kircher (2010). Sorting and decentralized price competition, Econometrica 78-2, 539-574. [15] Elliott, M. (2010), Ine¢ ciencies in networked markets, mimeo Stanford. [16] Elsby, M., B. Hobijn and A. Sahin (2008), Unemployment Dynamics in the OECD, NBER Working Paper 14617. [17] Fallick, B. and C. Fleischman (2004), The importance of employer-to-employer ‡ows in the U.S. labor market, working paper, Federal Reserve Bank Board of Governors, Washington DC. [18] Gautier, P.A. and C.N. Teulings (2006), How large are search frictions? Journal of the European Economic Association, 4-6, 1193-1225. [19] Gautier, P.A, C.N. Teulings and A.P. Van Vuuren (2005), Labor market search with two-sided heterogeneity: hierarchical versus circular models, in: H. Bunzel, B.J. Christensen, G.R. Neumann, and J.M. Robin, eds., Structural Models of Wage and Employment Dynamics, conference volume in honor of Dale Mortensen, Elsevier, Amsterdam. [20] Gautier, P.A, C.N. Teulings and A.P. Van Vuuren (2010), On-the-Job search mismatch and e¢ ciency, Review of Economic Studies, 77-1, 245-272. [21] P.A. Gautier, C.N. Teulings and M. Watanabe (2014) Collective versus decentralized wage bargaining and the e¢ cient allocation of resources (2013), Labour Economics, 26, 34-42. [22] Hall, R.E. (2009), Reconciling cyclical movements in the marginal value of time and the marginal product of labor, Journal of Political Economy, 117, 281-322. 32

[23] Hall, R.E. and P.R. Milgrom (2008), The limited in‡uence of unemployment on the wage bargain, American Economic Review, 98(4), 1653-1674. [24] Hagedorn J. and I. Manovskii (2008), The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies Revisited, American Economic Review, 98, 1692-1706. [25] Hagedorn J. T.H. Law and I. Manovskii (2012), Identifying sorting, mimeo UPenn. [26] Hornstein, A., P. Krusell and G.L. Violante (2010), Frictional wage dispersion in search models: A quantitative assessment, American Economic Review, 101(7), 2873-98. [27] Jovanovic B. (2014), Misallocation and growth, American Economic Review, 104, 1149-71. [28] Katz, L.F. and K.M. Murphy (1992), Changes in relative wages, 1963-1987: Supply and demand factors, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 35-78. [29] Lise, J., C. Meghir, and J.M. Robin (2012), Matching, sorting and wages, UCL mimeo. [30] Lise, J., and J.M. Robin (2013), The Macro-dynamics of Sorting between Workers and Firms, UCL mimeo. [31] Lopes de Melo (2008), Sorting in the labor market: theory and measurement, mimeo Chicago. [32] Marimon R. and F. Zilibotti (1999), Unemployment vs. mismatch of talents: Reconsidering unemployment bene…ts, Economic Journal, 109, 266-291. [33] Moscarini, G. (2005), Job matching and the wage distribution, Econometrica, 73(2), 481-516. [34] Moscarini, G., and F. Vella (2008), Occupational mobility and the business cycle, NBER working paper 13819. [35] Mortensen, D.T. (2000), Equilibrium unemployment with wage posting: "Burdett-Mortensen meets Pissarides", in B.J. Christensen, P. Jensen, N. Kiefer and D.T. Mortensen, eds., Panel Data and Structural Labor Market Models, Amsterdam, Elsevier science. 33

[36] Mortensen, D.T. and C. Pissarides (1999), New developments in models of search in the labor market, in: O.C. Ashenfelter and D. Card, Handbook of Labor Economics 3b, North-Holland, Amsterdam. [37] Nagypal, E. (2005), On the extent of job-to-job transitions, working paper, Northwestern University. [38] Pissarides, C.A. (1994), Search unemployment with on-the-job search, Review of Economic Studies, 61, 457-475. [39] Pissarides, C.A. (2000), Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd edition, MIT Press, Cambridge. [40] Postel-Vinay, F. and J.M. Robin (2002), Equilibrium wage dispersion with worker and employer heterogeneity, Econometrica, 70, 2295–2350. [41] Rosen, S. (1974), Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product di¤erentiation in pure competition, Journal of Political Economy, 82, 34-55. [42] Sattinger, M. (1975), Comparative advantage and the distribution of earnings and abilities, Econometrica, 43, 455-68. [43] Shimer, R. (2005), The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies, American Economic Review, 95, 25-49. [44] Shimer, R. (2006), On-the-job search and strategic bargaining, in: H. Bunzel, B.J. Christensen, G.R. Neumann and J.M. Robin, eds., Structural Models of Wage and Employment Dynamics, conference volume in honor of Dale Mortensen, Elsevier, Amsterdam. [45] Shimer, R. (2007), Reassessing the ins and outs of unemployment, NBER working paper 13421. [46] Shimer, R. and L. Smith (2000), Assortative matching and search, Econometrica, 68, 343-369. [47] Teulings, C.N. (1995), The wage distribution in a model of the assignment of skills to jobs, Journal of Political Economy, 103, 280-315. [48] Teulings, C.N. (2005), Comparative advantage, relative wages, and the accumulation of human capital, Journal of Political Economy, 113, 425-461. 34

[49] Teulings, C.N. and P.A. Gautier (2004), The right man for the job, Review of Economic Studies, 71, 553-580. [50] Teulings, C.N. and T. Van Rens (2008), Education, growth, and income inequality, Review of Economics and Statistics, 90, 89-104.

A

Appendix

A.1

Reducing the number of parameters

Consider the economy described in Section 2.2. Take the expressions for W (x) and x from Gautier, Teulings, and Van Vuuren (2010) for the no commitment case (equation 20), using Sv = 121 and =( + ) yields, 1+ x log ( )2

W (x) = 1

1+ 1+

x

x x

x

1 x (x 2

2x) :

G(x) is given by x (1 +

G (x) = 1

x : x) x

(21)

where x follows from (1).

A.2

fee feu

ratio Rx

u) g (x) xdx (1 + x) =( + ) fee = ( + ) 2 (1 u) x 1+ x =( + ) ln ( x + 1) 1 : x 0

using feu =

A.3

+

(1

Z

x

0

x dx (1 + x)2

yields equation (20).

The proof of Proposition 2

Let x N (0; 2x ) and "x N (0; 2" ). x and "x are independent. Let w The data-generating process for w is, ! 2 jxj

w = !0 21

In their case, the model is even more extended,

ln W E[ln W ]:

=

35

0 Sv.

We just substituted

for this combination.

where ! 0 = ! 2 Ejxj. The regression we run is w = ! 0 + ! 2 (x + "x )2 + : The claim is

where R =

1 ! 0 ! R! 2 Ejxj; 2

Var[x] . Var[x]+Var["xq ]

Claim 1: Ejxj = Proof.

2

Var[x] and ! 0 = ! 2 Ejxj = Var[x]

Let s = x2 =2, then we have x =

p

Z

q 1

0

2

2 xp e 2

2x and dx =

Ejxj = Var[x] = Var[x]

Var[x]. dx

p1 ds. 2s

r Z 2

r

x2 2

1

e s ds

0

2

Note we have ! 0 = ! 2 Ejxj. Claim 2: ! 0 = ! 2 (Var[x]+Var["x ]) Proof. 0 = w = ! 0 + ! 2 E(x + "x )2 = ! 0 + ! 2 (Var[x] + Var["x ]) 2

x ) ;! 0 ! 2 jxj] Note ! 2 ! cov[(x+" : var[(x+"x )2 ] 2 Claim 3: Var[(x + "x ) ] = 2(Var[x]+Var["x ])2 . Proof. Note that Ex4 = 3Var[x]2 , and x is independent q of "x .

Claim 4: cov[(x + "x )2 ; ! 0 ! 2 jxj] = Proof. Since E(! 0 ! 2 jxj) = 0, cov[(x + "x )2 ; ! 0

Var[x]3=2 :

2

!2.

! 2 jxj] = E[(x2 + 2x"x + "2x )(! 0 = E(! 0 x2

! 2 jxj)]

! 2 jxj) Z 1 x2 2 3=2 = Var[x] ! 0 x2 p e 2 dx 0 Z 12 x2 2 Var[x]3=2 ! 2 x3 p e 2 dx 2 0 36

Now we can use the same transformation as we did previously. Let s = x2 . p Z Z 1 2 2 2 1 2 3 2 1=2 s 3=2 E(! 0 x ! 2 jxj ) = x ! 0 p s e ds Var[x] ! 2 p se s ds 0 0 p 2 3 2 2 = Var[x]! 0 p ( ) Var[x]3=2 ! 2 p (2) 2 r 2 = Var[x]3=2 !2: where

is the gamma function and in the last step we use claim 1, ! 0 = ! 2

q

2

Var[x]3=2 .

Proposition 2 ! 0 ! 12 R! 2 Ejxj = 21 R! 0 . Proof. !0 =

! 2 (Var[x] + Var["x ])

Cov[(x + "x )2 ; ! 0 ! 2 jxj] (Var[x] + Var["x ]) Var[(x + "x )2 ] Var[x]3=2 !2 =p 2 Var[x] + Var["x ] 1 = R! 2 Ejxj 2

=

where in the third step, we use claim 3.

B

Robustness checks u (%)

B

W (0)

E xW

x100

commitment

0:4 0:4 0:6 0:6

Ex W W (x)

1 2

2 x (%)

R (%)

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

0:6 3:95 1:8 6:38 0:6 6:28 1:8 10:53

3:62 5:99 6:11 11:01

0:26 0:43 0:42 0:74

0:24 0:40 0:41 0:78

4:80 7:31 4:80 7:31

5:72 8:46 5:72 8:01

1:20 1:35 1:20 1:35

1:17 1:29 1:17 1:44

2:01 3:06 2:01 3:06

2:22 3:29 2:22 3:29

56 28 56 28

62 31 62 31

Table 3: Calibration results for f ee=f eu = 1:3

37

u (%)

B

W (0)

Ex W W (x)

E xW

x100

commitment

0:4 0:4 0:6 0:6

0:6 1:8 0:6 1:8

1 2

2 x (%)

R (%)

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

3:08 4:72 4:82 7:60

2:84 4:48 4:69 7:85

0:37 0:58 0:59 0:95

0:34 0:54 0:57 0:99

4:09 6:04 4:09 6:05

5:53 8:00 5:53 8:01

1:29 1:51 1:29 1:51

1:25 1:44 1:25 1:44

1:57 2:32 1:57 2:32

1:65 2:39 1:65 2:39

44 22 44 22

46 22 46 22

Table 4: Calibration results for f ee=f eu = 1:75

0:6 0:4

B Commitment

u(1 B) vK (1 u) [Y (0) X (%)

1:8

yes

2:37 3:86 Ex Y ] 1:93 8:16

0:6

0:4 yes

0:6

no

yes

no

no

yes

no

2:17 8:38 2:14 12:69

2:51 3:77 1:88 8:16

2:44 3:83 3:60 4:21 4:41 8:16 5:73 12:09 5:47 11:44 2:09 2:86 3:09 2:74 2:93 12:69 12:42 18:78 12:42 18:78

Table 5: Decomposition of output loss due to frictions for f ee=f eu = 1:3

0:6 0:4

B Commitment

u(1 B) vK (1 u) [Y (0) X (%)

yes

1:85 3:05 Ex Y ] 1:52 6:42

1:8 0:6

0:4

0:6

no

yes

no

yes

no

yes

no

1:71 7:36 1:60 10:67

1:93 2:99 1:50 6:42

1:88 7:22 1:57 10:67

2:84 4:43 2:22 9:48

2:69 10:48 2:28 15:45

3:04 4:30 2:15 9:48

3:14 10:11 2:20 15:45

Table 6: Decomposition of output loss due to frictions for f ee=f eu = 1:75

38

C C.1

Web Appendix Flow conditions

A worker accepts any job o¤er with a wage above his current wage and consequently with a mismatch indicator smaller than in his current job. Unemployed workers accept only job o¤ers with x < x. The unemployment rate in this economy is determined by the following equilibrium ‡ow condition (1

u) +

(22)

= 2 xu + u:

The left hand side of (22) measures the in‡ow into unemployment. The …rst term re‡ects workers who loose their job and the second term re‡ects the growth of the labor force (new workers start as unemployed). The right hand side measures the out‡ow. The …rst term is the number of workers who …nd a job and the second term captures the fact that the in‡ow should exceed the out‡ow by u to keep unemployment at a constant fraction of the workforce at the balanced growth (at rate ) path. So for ! 0 this is just a simple steady-state ‡ow equation. This relation can be simpli…ed by de…ning the parameter 2 = ( + ). Then, u=

1 : 1+ x

^ (x). Equation (8) follows from substituting (22) into the Let G [W (x)] 1 G following balanced growth equation, 2 x fu + (1

u) [1

G (x)]g

(1

u)G (x) = (1

u)G (x) :

which tells us that the labor force grows at rate and so does the mass of workers who are employed at a distance x or less from their optimal job type. The …rst term on the left is the in‡ow into this class and the second term is the out‡ow. Flows from one smaller-than-x job to another cancel out. Equation (8) follows from substituting (22) into the following balanced growth equation, 2 x fu + (1

u) [1

G (x)]g

(1

u)G (x) = (1

u)G (x) :

which tells us that the labor force grows at rate and so does the mass of workers who are employed at a distance x or less from their optimal job type. The …rst term on the left is the in‡ow into this class and the second term is the out‡ow. Flows from one smaller-than-x job to another cancel out. 1

C.2

Derivation of the Bellman equations under golden growth

A general way to derive V U and the free entry condition uses a simple accounting identity. First we start with a general discount rate r, and then we let r approach the population growth rate from above. At time 0, Z 1 Z 1 U rt t U E U E V e de = uV + (1 u)EV + e rt V U e t dt uV + (1 u)EV + 0 0 Z 1 = e rt e t (uB + (1 u)EW ) dt 0

The …rst term on the …rst line is the total discounted value created by unemployed workers at time 0; the second term is the total discounted value created by employed workers at time 0; the third term is the total discounted value of all future generations, where each new worker starts his career as an unemployed worker. The second line is an alternative way to aggregate total value in the economy that equals the left hand side because workers are risk neutral. It simply equals the discounted total value (expected wage income + B) of all workers from t = 0 onwards. The above equality is essentially an application of the Fubini theorem. Simplifying the above equation yields, uV

U

+ (1

= (uB + (1 V U + (r Letting r &

u)EV

E

+ V

1 r

1

u)EW )

) uV U + (1

U

r

e(

r)t

e

(

r)t

1 0

1 0

u)EV E = uB + (1

u)EW

gives V U = uB + (1

u)EW:

The derivation for the free entry condition is similar. Suppose that at time 0 the population is 1 and the number of vacancies equals v. Denote the value of a …lled job by V J . Again, there exists an accounting identity for the total value created by …rms in the economy, Z 1 Z 1 J V rt t (1 u)EV + vV + e VV ^e dt = e rt e t ((1 u)(EY EW ) Kv) 0

0

where ^ is the adjusted birth rate for vacancies (which is not important because in equilibrium VV = 0). The expected value of the cross section of …lled and vacant jobs should 2

equal the discounted sum of …rm pro…ts minus the amount of resources spent on vacancies. Since under free entry the expected value of all current and future vacancies equals 0, we get, (r )(1 u)EV J = (1 u)(EY EW ) Kv Letting r &

gives vK = (1

u)(EY

EW ):

The derivation of V E (x) follows Gautier et al. (2010). The Bellman equation for the asset value of employment for a worker employed in a job with mismatch indicator x reads Z x E c V (x) = W (x) + 2 V E (y) V E (x) dy V E (x) V U : (23) 0

Totally di¤erentiating yields

( + ) VxE (x) = The solution to this di¤erential equation reads

cx (x) W : 1+ x

Zx c Wx (y) dy + C0 : ( + ) V (x) = 1+ y E

0

Integrating by parts yields c (x) W ( + ) V E (x) = 1+ x

c (0) + W

Zx 0

c (y) W dy + C0 : (1 + y)2

Evaluation of this equation at x = 0 gives an initial condition that can be used to solve for C0 c (0) + V U : C0 = W Substitution of this initial condition yields

Z c (x) c (y) W W U ( + ) V (x) = + 2 dy + V : 1+ x (1 + y) x

E

0

De…ne Ex W =

Rx 0

c (x) dG b (x). By equation (8), we have W Zx 0

c (y) W x Ex W: 2 dy = 1+ x (1 + y) 3

(24)

Using this expression and V U = V E (x) to evaluate equation (23) at x yields c (x) + c (x) + xEx W uW W = 1+ x u+

V E (x) =

(1 (1

Equation (23) and V U = V E (x) imply Z x 2 V E (x) V U dx = V U (x)

u) Ex W : u)

c (x) : W

0

Substitution of this expression into the Bellman equation for V U yields Z x B + xEx W U V E (x) V U dx = V =B+2 = uB + (1 u) Ex W; 1+x 0 where the …nal step uses u = 1= (1 + x). Finally, consider the free entry condition. De…ne EG Y Rx g (x) W (x) dx, then, 0 K=2

Z

x

fu +

0

=

1

v

u

(EG Y

(1

u) [1

G (x)]g

(25)

Rx 0

(26)

g (x) Y (x) dx and EG W

Y (x) W (x) dx + + 2 vx

EG W ) :

(27)

The term, u + (1 u) [1 G (x)] is the e¤ective labor supply for a type x match. The second term gives the value of a …lled vacancy. It discounts current revenue Y (x) W (x) by the discount rate plus the separation rate plus the quit rate 2 x. The …nal line follows from substituting in (8) and (x = (1 u) =u). This implies that the resources spent on vacancy creation, vK, must in a steady-state equilibrium be equal to the employment rate (1 u) times the expected pro…t of a …lled vacancy, (EG Y EG W ).

C.3

Derivation of wages

This derivation summarizes the results in Gautier et al. (2010). Conditional on x, …rms choose a wage that maximizes the value of a vacancy, ! n h io Y (x) W b (W ) arg max u + (1 u) 1 G W xFb(W ) The FOC with respect to W reads (1

0= u+

(1

u) Gx =Wx h i b (W ) u) 1 G 4

xFx =Wx xFb(W )

1 ; Y (x) W

bW = Gx =Wx and FbW = Fx =Wx . Using Fx = 1=x and some rearrangement where we use G yields, 0 1 (1 u) Gx A [Y (x) W ] : h i+ (28) Wx = @ 1 + x b u + (1 u) 1 G (W ) Use (8) and its derivative with respect to x to write, (1 u+

(1

u) Gx h i= 1+ b u) 1 G (W )

x

;

and substitute this back in (28) to get Wx (x) =

2

(Y (x) 1+

W (x)) : x

This equation is almost identical to equation to the one for no commitment except that the "2" is replaced by a "1" (at the margin the hiring and no quit premia are equal and under no commitment there are no hiring premia). For the solution of the di¤erential equation we refer to Gautier et al. (2010).

C.4

Wages and expected wages

Here we combine and into one parameter (as we do in our matlab program). De…ne, 2 ;x z= ; and x = z= . Note that we can switch back and forth between the model in terms of (x; ) and (z; ) by the fact that Var[x] = Var[z]. G(x) is given by, G (x) = 1

x (1 +

x : x) x

b (z) satis…es Substitution of the expressions for x and x in (21) shows that G z z : (1 + z) z

b (z) = 1 G

The value of z follows from (7), using 1 u = z= (1 + z) and V E (x) = V U . Substituting those variables in the wage equations (18,19) of Gautier, Teulings yields,

5

commitment " 1+ z c (z) = 1 W Ez W =

Z

z

log

# z (1 + z)2 z 3 2 + + z ; 1+ z 2

1+ z 1+ z

c (z) dz g (z) W

0

=1

z

3

=1

3

z+

z

The expression for

1 2

2 2

z

(1 + z) ln (1 + z) :

can be derived from combining z =

2 3 (1 )(1 + z)(1 + z) ln(1 + z)

6(1

(29)

# z 3 2 z (1 + z)2 + + z dz 1+ z 2 # (1 + q)2 3 2 z + q + q dq 1+ z 2

" 2 1+ z 1+ z 1+ z ln 2 1+ z 0 z (1 + z) " Z z 1+ z 1 1+q (1 + q)2 ln 2 3 1+ z z (1 + q) 0

Z

=1

=

2

1 u , u

B) (1 + z)(1 + z) z 6(1 + z) + 3 (2

(6) and (7)

z)(1 + z) +

2

z(4 + 3z)

non-commitment c (z) = 1 W Z Ez W =

0

=1 =1 =1 Again, =

C.5

1+ z 2 z

ln

1+ z 1+ z

z

z

1 z (z 2

c (z) dz g (z) W Z z 1+ z 1+ z 1+ z z ln 2 2 1+ z 0 z (1 + z) Z z 1+ z 1 1+q 2 (1 + q) ln 3 1+ z z (1 + q) 0 1+ z 1 2 ln (1 + z) + z ln (1 + z) 3 2 z

can be derived from z =

1 u , u

(30)

2z) ;

z

1 z (z 2

2z) dz 1 q (q 2

q+ z

2 z) dq

1 2z2 ; 21+ z

(6) and (7),

2 3 (1 B) (1 + z) (1 + z) : 2 (1 + z) (1 + z) z 2 + z 2 (1 ) (1 + z)2 [2 z ln (1 + z)] ln (1 + z)

Variance of x Z

Z Z 1+ x x x2 1+ x Var [x] = x g (x) dx = 2 dx = 3 x x 0 0 0 (1 + x) x (2 + x) 2 (1 + x) log (1 + x) = : 3 x x

2

6

x

x2 dx (1 + x)2

(31)

:

C.6

Measuring

Let Ye (s; c) be the productivity of an s-type worker in a c-type job. We can adjust the production function to be increasing in s; as follows, ln Ye (s; c) = s

1 (s 2

c)2 = s

1 2 x: 2

(32)

The optimal assignment c (s) for worker type s solves the …rst-order condition ln Yec [s; c (s)] = 0, implying that c (s) = s. This speci…cation exhibits all features discussed in Section 3.1. First, in the Walrasian equilibrium, all workers are assigned to their optimal job type, c (s) = s (and hence x = 0) and wages are equal to output. Hence c (s) = s, see equation (10). Second, the function Ye (s; c) exhibits ln Ye (s; s) = ln W absolute and comparative advantage which is required for the derivation of sb and b c as 22 discussed in Section (3.1). Third, the Mincerian rate of return to skill dEx [ln W ] =ds is equal to one. Finally, the parameter in equation (32) is equivalent to the parameter in equation (1) by applying a second-order Taylor expansion to Y (x) and Ye (s; c), around the optimal assignment, x = 0: = Y 00 (0) =Y (0) = Yecc (c; c) =Ye (c; c). The parameter measures the curvature of Rosen’s (1974) well known hedonic system where the isopro…t curve and the indi¤erence curve of the worker are tangent to the locus of market wages and the indi¤erence curve of the worker. This curvature, the second derivative of the production function, is a measure of both the productivity loss due to mismatch and the elasticity of substitution between various workers types. Note that the dimension of this curvature parameter corresponds to that of the mismatch indicator x used in Section (3.1) since the Mincerian rate of return to s is equal to unity in the optimal assignment: ln Yes (s; s) = 1.

C.7

Constructing skill and job complexity levels

We run the following two regressions ln W = ~j + "s + "w ; ln W = ~k + "c + "w ;

(33)

where ~j and ~k are vectors of observed worker and job characteristics respectively, where "s and "c capture unobserved worker and job characteristics respectively, and where "w 22

Comparative advantage requires the cross derivative of ln Y (s; c) to be positive; absolute advantage requires the …rst derivative of ln Y (s; c) with respect to s to be positive for any c. The latter is not globally satis…ed for this polynomial speci…cation, but it is in the optimal assignment s = c.

7

captures the e¤ect of non-optimal assignment on wages and measurement error in wages. It is convenient to normalize our data on ln W; ~j and ~k such that they have zero mean. Hence, it does not make sense to include a constant in these regressions. The estimated parameter vector can then be used to construct indices for the observed worker and job ~k. The non-linearities in the relation between ln W on ~j;and b characteristics sb c ! ! the one hand and j and k on the other are captured by a proper normalization. Then, the skill index s and the job index c satisfy, s = sb + "s ; c=b c + "s ;

Both indices sb and b c have zero mean by construction and are uncorrelated to the unobserved components "s and "c ; respectively.23

23

We apply the following iterative procedure such that if we regress ln W on both s and s2 that the coe¢ cient of the second-order term s2 is zero. First, run ln W = 1 sb1 + 2 sb1 2 + "s1 , where sb1 is E(sj~j) constructed from (33) and where "s1 = s sb1 . Second, we construct a new variable sb2 = 1 sb1 + 2 sb21 E 1 sb1 + 22 sb1 and rerun the …rst regression after substituting s2 for s1 . We repeat these steps until 2 = 0. The same applies to our regression for c. This algorithm therefore normalizes s in such a way that any correlation between sb and "s is eliminated.

8

Sorting and the output loss due to search frictions

firms pay both hiring and no-quit premiums, whereas in the latter case, firms pay only no-quit premiums. ... This externality can potentially be reduced by policies that shift rents from the firms to the workers.2 ..... maximum is higher, see Figure 1, other statistics of wage dispersion (based on the lowest wage) may lead to the ...

352KB Sizes 0 Downloads 153 Views

Recommend Documents

Sorting and the output loss due to search frictions - Coen Teulings
conference in Amsterdam, Essex, UPenn and the SAM meeting in Rouen for useful comments and .... We call x the mismatch indicator. ...... way of estimating ω0.

Sorting and the output loss due to search frictions
this framework, various wage mechanisms can be analyzed like wage posting with full ..... VOETNOOT OVER KAPPA41 Substitution of (11) into condition (10).

Sorting and the output loss due to search frictions
†VU University Amsterdam, Tinbergen Institute, CEPR, Ces%Ifo, IZA, email: .... given up when accepting a job, and (ii) less workers quit from good matches and ...

Stable Marriage and Search Frictions
Jul 5, 2012 - Define x(m,m) = 1− ∑ w∈W x(m,w) and x(w,w) = 1− ∑ m∈M x(m,w). .... Definition (Steady State Matching) .... Utilities given by the bi-matrix w1.

Search frictions, real wage rigidities and the optimal ...
Mar 23, 2013 - and budget policy. Indeed, the labor market is characterized by search frictions and wage rigidities which distort agents' job acceptance behavior and firms' ... 4Abbritti and Weber (2008) estimate the degree of real wage rigidity on O

Dynamic Pricing with Search Frictions
Aug 30, 2017 - 2017 SAET Conference, the 8th Workshop on Consumer Search and Switching Costs and ... 162 million people have provided goods or services through .... In many real-world applications, however, a large number of sellers.

Sorting by search intensity
such a way that the worker can use a contact with one employer as a threat point in the bargaining process with another. Specifically, an employed worker who has been contacted by an outside firm will match with the most productive of the two and bar

An Alternative Approach to Search Frictions
Ricardo Lagos. London School of Economics and New Ymk University ... side of the market, and often also homogeneous of degree one. The thing to note is that .... good characterization of the agents' underlying search behavior. If agents are able ....

How Large are Search Frictions?
Oct 20, 2006 - not observe all factors that are relevant for worker skill and job complexity, and ... identical across the six countries that we consider, but we show that the required ... Recent contributions apply matched worker–firm data to ....

Search frictions, real rigidities and inflation dynamics!
stronger sales and therefore higher marginal costs for the duration of the price contract. .... opportunities, plus the continuation value of the job. ...... in the nonfarm business sector (y), hours of all persons in the nonfarm business sector (nh)

Skill Requirements, Search Frictions and Wage Inequality
Jun 21, 2009 - with high school diplomas and some college education, and ... unobserved skills in response to skill-biased technical change as being ...

Search frictions, real rigidities and inflation dynamics!
a producer%retailer model with identical preferences and technology are exactly the same as in the model ..... benefit of hiring equals its marginal cost, X/q θt!

Search Frictions, Bank Leverage, and Gross Loan ...
Jan 5, 2013 - Page 1 ... my supervisor, Hashmat Khan, for his valuable support and direction. I am also ... Building, 1125 Colonel By Drive, Ottawa, ON, Canada, K1S 5B6. .... They own banks, intermediate and capital goods producing firms,.

Land development, search frictions and city structure
Aug 4, 2014 - land development, this paper provides a complete analysis of spatial configurations of a city with frictional unemployment. To be more precise, we consider a city where all jobs are located in the unique central business district (CBD).

Efficiency in a Directed Search Model with Information Frictions and ...
Mar 31, 2014 - We show that the directed search equilibrium is not constrained efficient in a dy- namic setting .... complement them with the publicly available information. Thus, the ...... correspondence T1,τ on the domain Iτ as. T1,τ (x)=(qτ .

Optimal Labor Market Policy with Search Frictions and ...
reallocation of workers from low to high productivity jobs, hiring subsidies are .... ance in a search model where the accumulation of risk&free savings is the only .... of the results provided that the interest rate at which the planner can transfer

Equilibrium in the Labor Market with Search Frictions
not looking for a job. In the Phelps volume, however, as in the important paper by. McCall (1970), the worker is searching for a wage offer from a fixed distribution of wages, and if she is .... Petrongolo and Pissarides (2008). 6 See Pissarides (198

Frictions Lead to Sorting: a Partnership Model with On ...
Dec 19, 2014 - the degree of complementarity in production, agents' patience and the degree of frictions ...... 10In the Online Appendix, for each possible equilibrium, we present closed-form solutions for densities ...... MIT Press, Cambridge.

What is the True Loss Due to Piracy? Evidence from ...
Apr 10, 2012 - student would switch to Internet piracy even if the government eradicated street piracy. This explains why ... Business Software Alliance's estimated cost of piracy. ..... connection and the availability of BitTorrent (BT) seeds.

Search Frictions in Physical Capital Markets as a ...
Apr 16, 2007 - congestion in physical capital markets, as in the data. ... As the quantitative analysis reveals, the extended model indeed generates ...... As in CF and BGG, we introduce credit frictions through a costly state verification (CSV).