Econometrica Supplementary Material

SUPPLEMENT TO “SEARCH AND REST UNEMPLOYMENT”: APPENDIX B (Econometrica, Vol. 79, No. 1, January 2011, 75–122) BY FERNANDO ALVAREZ AND ROBERT SHIMER

B.1. HAMILTON–JACOBI–BELLMAN DERIVATION THIS APPENDIX SECTION proves that if v(ω) is given by  (65)

ω ¯

v(ω) =

R(ω )Πω (ω ; ω) dω

ω ¯

for an arbitrary continuous function R(·) and if the local time function Πω (·) is given as in Stokey (2009, Proposition 10.4) by

(66)

⎧ ) ) ¯ 2ω (ζ2 eζ1 ω+ζ2 ω¯ − ζ1 eζ1 ω+ζ )(ζ2 eζ2 (ω−ω − ζ1 eζ1 (ω−ω ) ⎪ ¯ ¯ ⎪  ⎪ ⎪ ζ1 ω+ζ2 ω ¯ ζ1 ω+ζ ¯ 2ω ⎪ (ρ + q + δ)(ζ2 − ζ1 )(e ¯ −e ¯) ⎪ ⎪ ⎪ ⎨ if ω ≤ ω < ω  ¯ Πω (ω ; ω) = ) ) ¯ ¯ ⎪ 2 ω )(ζ eζ2 (ω−ω ⎪ (ζ2 eζ1 ω+ζ2 ω¯ − ζ1 eζ1 ω+ζ − ζ1 eζ1 (ω−ω ) 2 ¯ ⎪ ⎪  ⎪ ζ1 ω+ζ2 ω ¯ ζ1 ω+ζ ¯ 2ω ⎪ (ρ + q + δ)(ζ2 − ζ1 )(e ¯ −e ⎪ ¯) ⎪ ⎩ if ω ≤ ω ≤ ω ¯

where ζ1 < 0 < ζ2 are the two roots of the characteristic equation ρ + q + δ = 2 μζ + σ2 ζ 2 , then (ρ + q + δ)v(ω) = R(ω) + μv (ω) +

σ 2  v (ω) 2

The proof proceeds as follows: Differentiating v with respect to ω, we get 

ω ¯



v (ω) =

ω ¯

 

v (ω) =

ω ¯

R(ω )Πω ω (ω ; ω) dω  R(ω )Πω ωω (ω ; ω) dω

ω ¯

      + R(ω) lim Π (ω ; ω) − lim Π (ω ; ω)  ωω ωω   ω ↑ω

© 2011 The Econometric Society

ω ↓ω

DOI: 10.3982/ECTA7686

2

F. ALVAREZ AND R. SHIMER

where we use that Πω is continuous but Πω ω has a jump at ω = ω. Then (ρ + q + δ)v(ω) − μv (ω) − 

ω ¯

=

σ 2  v (ω) 2

R(ω) (ρ + q + δ)Πω (ω ; ω)

ω ¯

σ2  − μΠω ω (ω ; ω) − Πω ωω (ω ; ω) dω 2   2 σ    ω (ω ; ω) − lim Πω ω (ω ; ω) − R(ω) lim Π ω ω ↑ω ω ↓ω 2 

Using the functional form of Πω , we have, for ω < ω, Πω (ω ; ω) = eζ1 ω h˜ 1 (ω ) − eζ2 ω h˜ 2 (ω ) where 







h˜ 1 (ω ) =

) ) − ζ1 eζ1 (ω−ω ) ζ2 eζ2 ω¯ (ζ2 eζ2 (ω−ω ¯ ¯  ζ1 ω+ζ2 ω ¯ ζ1 ω+ζ (ρ + q + δ)(ζ2 − ζ1 )(e ¯ − e ¯ 2 ω¯ )

h˜ 2 (ω ) =

) ) − ζ1 eζ1 (ω−ω ) ζ1 eζ1 ω¯ (ζ2 eζ2 (ω−ω ¯ ¯ ζ1 ω+ζ2 ω ¯ ζ1 ω+ζ (ρ + q + δ)(ζ2 − ζ1 )(e ¯ − e ¯ 2 ω¯ )

Thus for all ω < ω, σ2 (ρ + q + δ)Πω (ω ; ω) − μΠω ω (ω ; ω) − Πω ωω (ω ; ω) 2 2 σ = (ρ + q + δ) − ζ1 μ − (ζ1 )2 eζ1 ω h˜ 1 (ω ) 2 2 2σ − (ρ + q + δ) − ζ2 μ − (ζ2 ) eζ2 ω h˜ 2 (ω ) 2 = 0 where the last equality follow from the definition of the roots ζi . Hence  ω R(ω ) (ρ + q + δ)Πω (ω ; ω) − μΠω ω (ω ; ω) ω ¯

σ2  − Πω ωω (ω ; ω) dω = 0 2

SEARCH AND REST UNEMPLOYMENT

3

Using a symmetric calculation for ω > ω, we have 

ω ¯

R(ω ) (ρ + q + δ)Πω (ω ; ω) − μΠω ω (ω ; ω)

ω



σ2 Πω ωω (ω ; ω) dω = 0 2

Next, differentiating Πω (ω ; ω) when ω < ω and when ω > ω, and letting ω → ω from below and from above, tedious—but straightforward—algebra, gives 

lim Πω ω (ω ; ω) − lim Πω ω (ω ; ω) = −  

ω ↑ω

ω ↓ω

ζ1 ζ2 ρ+q+δ

Then use the expression for the roots: ζ1 ζ2 = −(ρ + q + δ)/(σ 2 /2). Putting this together proves the result.

B.2. INDUSTRY SOCIAL PLANNER’S PROBLEM In this section we introduce a dynamic programming problem whose solution gives the equilibrium value for the thresholds ω ω. ¯ This problem has the interpretation of a fictitious social planner located in¯ a given industry who maximizes net consumer surplus by deciding how many of the agents currently located in the industry work and how many rest, and whether to adjust the number of workers in the industry. The equivalence of the solution of this problem with the equilibrium value of an industry’s worker has the following implications. First, it establishes that our market decentralization is rich enough to attain an efficient equilibrium, despite the presence of search frictions. Second, it gives an alternative argument to establish the uniqueness of the equilibrium values for the thresholds ω and ω. ¯ Third, it connects our results with the decision theoretic literature ¯that analyzes investment and labor demand models with costly reversibility. The industry planner maximizes the net surplus from the production of the final good in an industry with current log productivity x˜ and l workers, taking as given aggregate consumption C and aggregate output Y . The choices for this planner are to increase the number of workers located in this industry (hire), paying v¯ to the households for each of them, or to decrease the number of workers located it the industry (fire), receiving a payment v for each. Increases and decreases are nonnegative, and the prices associated¯with them have the ˜ l) be the value dimension of an asset value, as opposed to a rental. We let M(x

4

F. ALVAREZ AND R. SHIMER

function of this planner; hence,  ∞

 ˜ l) = max E ˜ (67) e−(ρ+δ)t S(x(t) M(x l(t)) + vql(t) dt − v¯ dlh (t) lh lf ¯ 0

  ˜ ˜ l(0) = l = x + v dlf (t) x(0) ¯ subject to

dl(t) = −ql(t) dt + dlh (t) − dlf (t) and d x˜ = μx dt + σx dz

The lh (t) and lf (t) are increasing processes that describe the cumulative amount of “hiring,” and “firing” and hence dlh (t) and dlf (t) intuitively have the interpretation of hiring and firing during period t. The term ql(t) dt represents the exogenous quits that happens in a period of length dt. The planner discounts at rate ρ + δ, accounting both for the discount rate of households and for the rate at which her industry disappears. ˜ l) denotes the return function of the industry social planThe function S(x ner per unit of time and is given by 

Eex˜



˜ l) = max u (C) S(x E∈[0l]

0



Y y

1/θ dy + br (l − E) + δlv ¯

The first term is the consumer’s surplus associated with the particular good, ˜ The obtained by the output produced by E workers with log productivity x. second term is value of the workers who the planner chooses to send back to the household, receiving v for each. The third term is the value of the “sale” of ¯ all the workers if the industry shuts down. Setting q = δ = br = 0, our problem is formally equivalent to Bentolila and Bertola’s (1990) model of a firm deciding employment subject to a hiring and firing cost, and to Abel and Eberly’s (1996) model of optimal investment subject to costly irreversibility, that is, a different buying and selling price for capital. Using the envelope theorem, we find that the marginal value of an additional worker is

1/θ   Y (ex˜ )θ−1  ˜ l) = max u (C) (68)  br + δv Sl (x l ¯

(θ − 1)x˜ + log Y − log l  ≡s + log u (C)  θ where the function s(·) is given by s(ω) = max{eω  br } + δv and is identical to the expression for the per-period value of a worker in our ¯equilibrium, except that δv is in place of (q + δ)v. This is critical to the equivalence between the ¯ ¯ two problems.

5

SEARCH AND REST UNEMPLOYMENT

To prove this equivalence, we write the industry social planner’s Hamilton– ¯ x), ˜ there are two thresholds, l(x) ˜ and l( ˜ Jacobi–Bellman equation. For each x, ¯ that define the range of inaction. The value function M(·) and threshold func¯ tions {l(·) l(·)} solve the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation if the following ¯ two conditions are met: ¯ x)), ˜ l( ˜ employment decays exponentially with the (i) For all x˜ and l ∈ (l(x) quits at rate q and hence¯ the value function M solves (69)

˜ l) = S(x ˜ l) − qMl (x ˜ l) + μx Mx˜ (x ˜ l) + (ρ + δ)M(x

σx2 ˜ l) Mx˜ x˜ (x 2

˜ l) outside the interior of the range of inaction, (ii) For all (x (70)

˜ l) + qlMl (x ˜ l) − μx Mx˜ (x ˜ l) − (ρ + δ)M(x

σx2 ˜ l) ≤ S(x ˜ l) Mx˜ x˜ (x 2

¯ x) ˜ l) ∀l ≥ l( ˜ ˜ l) ∀l ≤ l(x) ˜ and v¯ = Ml (x v = Ml (x ¯ ¯ ˜ ·) is linear outEquation (71) is also referred to as smooth pasting. Since M(x side the range of inaction, a twice-continuously differentiable solution implies ˜ supercontact or that for all x, (71)

¯ x)) ˜ l( ˜ = Mll (x ˜ l(x)) ˜ 0 = Mll (x ¯ According to Verification Theorem 4.1, in Fleming and Soner (1993, Sec˜ l) that satisfies tion VIII), a twice-continuously differentiable function M(x equations (69), (71), and (72) solves the industry social planner’s problem. ¯ If M is sufficiently smooth, finding the optimal threshold functions {l(·) l(·)} ¯ ˜ l) and its can be stated as a boundary problem in terms of the function Ml (x derivatives. To see this, differentiate both sides of equation (69) with respect to l and replace Sl using equation (68):

(θ − 1)x˜ + log Y − log l  ˜ l) = s (ρ + δ + q)Ml (x + log u (C) (73) θ (72)

˜ l) + μx Mxl˜ (x ˜ l) + − qlMll (x

σx2 ˜ l) Mx˜ xl˜ (x 2

If the required partial derivatives exist, any solution to the industry social planner’s problem must solve equations (71)–(73). Moreover, there is a clear relationship between the value function v(ω) in the decentralized problem and the marginal value of a worker Ml in the industry social planner’s problem: LEMMA 3: Assume that θ = 1, that the functions Ml (·) and v(·) satisfy (74)

˜ l) = v(ω) Ml (x

where ω =

log Y + (θ − 1)x˜ − log l + log u (C) θ

6

F. ALVAREZ AND R. SHIMER

¯ and that threshold functions {l(·) l(·)} and the threshold levels {ω ω} ¯ satisfy ¯ ¯ ¯ x) ˜ = log Y + (θ − 1)x˜ − θ(ω − log u (C)) (75) log l( ¯ ˜ = log Y + (θ − 1)x˜ − θ(ω log l(x) ¯ − log u (C)) (76) ¯ ¯ ¯ x)] ˜ l( ˜ solve equations (71)–(73) for all x˜ and l ∈ [l(x) Then Ml (·) and {l(·) l(·)} ¯ if and only if v(·)¯and {ω ω} ¯ solve equations (12). ¯ PROOF: Differentiate equation (74) with respect to x˜ and l to get

2 θ−1 θ−1   ˜ l) = v (ω) ˜ l) = v (ω)  Mlx˜ x˜ (x  Mlx˜ (x θ θ and 1 ˜ l) = −v (ω) Mll (x θ Recall that a solution of equation (12) is equivalent to a solution to equations (39) and (40), and v(ω) ¯ = v¯ and v(ω) = v. The equivalence between ¯ ¯ equation (12) and equations (71)–(73) is immediate, recalling the definitions of μ and σ. Q.E.D. This lemma has important implications. First, it establishes, not surprisingly, that the equilibrium allocation is Pareto optimal. Second, since the industry social planner’s problem is a maximization problem, the solution is easy to characterize. For instance, since the problem is convex, it has at most one solution and hence the equilibrium value of a worker is uniquely defined, for given u (C) and Y . The fact that v is increasing is then equivalent to the concavity of ˜ ·). Finally, notice that Proposition 1 establishes existence and uniqueness S(x of the solution to equation (12) only under mild conditions on s(·), that is, that it was weakly increasing and bounded below. Proposition 1 can be used to extend the uniqueness and existence results of the literature of costly irreversible investment to a wider class of production functions. Currently the literature uses that the production function is of the form xax lal for some constants ax and al with 0 < al < 1 as in Abel and Eberly (1996). Proposition 1 shows that the only assumption required is that the production function be concave in l and that the marginal productivity of the factor l can be written as a function of the ratio of the quantity of the input l to (a power of) the productivity shock x. B.3. HETEROGENEOUS INDUSTRIES This section extends the directed search model to include heterogeneity in households’ human capital. In equilibrium, industries can be divided into different classes. Industries that attract households with high human capital pay

SEARCH AND REST UNEMPLOYMENT

7

high wages, but the stochastic process for their wages is a scaled version of that for an industry that attracts households with less human capital. Still, all industries have the same process for the log full-employment wage ω (measured in utils), and the same rest- and search-unemployment rates. This justifies our fixed effect treatment of U.S. industry wage data in Section 6.1. We prove in this section that in the directed search model with logarithmic utility, the values of the thresholds ω and ω ¯ are the same across industries, ¯ hence the wage in units of goods, is although the level of consumption, and different. We omit a proof of a similar result in the random search model under the assumption that workers with a particular human capital level contact other workers with the same human capital level at rate α, at which point they may join the workers’ industry. We turn now to a description of the directed search model. Households are indexed by one of K human capital types, denoted by hk satisfying 0 < h1 and hk < hk+1 for k = 1 2  K − 1 with hK = 1. For notational convenience, let h0 = 0 and hk ≡ hk − hk−1 . Let Hk denote the cumulative distribution of households’ human capital types, so that there are Hk households with human capital hj ≤ hk , and there are Hk ≡ Hk −Hk−1 households with human capital type hk for k = 1  K. Recall that industries are indexed by j which belong to [0 1]. The meaning of type hk human capital is that such household can work in any industry labeled j ∈ (0 hk ]. Assume (77)

Hk+1 Hk < hk+1 hk

for k = 1  K − 1. We then look for an equilibrium where type hk households work in industries of type j ∈ (hk−1  hk ]. In this equilibrium, we talk of both households and industries of type k. For workers to sort themselves across industries in this way, it must be the case that wages are increasing in industry type, and equation (77) insures that labor supply is in fact decreasing in industry type. Let Lk denote the fraction of members of type k households who are located in type k industries and let L0k denote the fraction located in newly created industries within the k class. Thus Lk ( Hk / hk ) is the number of household members per type k industry, either working or in rest unemployment. Households with different human capital have different consumption and hence different marginal utility. Letting Ck be the consumption per household for those with human capital k, we have that the log full-employment wage for household of type k is (78)

ωk (t) ≡

log Y + (θ − 1) log x(t) − log l(t) + log u (Ck ) θ

8

F. ALVAREZ AND R. SHIMER

where Y is aggregate output, x(t) is industry productivity, and l(t) is the number of workers in the industry. We characterize an equilibrium where the process for ωk is identical for all k. PROPOSITION 7: Assume log utility, u(C) ≡ log C, and that equation (77) ¯ ∗ ) be the equilibrium values for the model without hetholds. Let (L∗  ω∗  ω ¯ erogeneity. Then there is an equilibrium of the model with heterogeneity with ¯ k  ωk ) = (L∗  ω ¯ ∗  ω∗ ) for all k and (Lk  ω ¯ ¯

1/θ hk Hk Ck = Ck Hk hk PROOF: For the processes {ωk (t)} to be identical across industries, the difference in the log of the marginal utilities must be compensated by a difference in the level of the employment per industry, so that any two industries in classes k and k created at the same time and with the same history of shocks have employment lk and lk satisfying log lk (t) − log lk (t) = θ(log u (Ck ) − log u (Ck )) Aggregating across shocks and using the logarithmic utility assumption and the conjecture about the nature of equilibrium, the number of workers located in type k industries is (79)

L∗ Hk Ckθ ≡β hk

for all k = 1  K and some constant β. The distribution f evaluated at the upper bound still satisfies

L∗ θσ 2 σ2  f (ω) f (ω) ¯ = δ 0∗  (80) ¯ − μ+ 2 2 L where L∗0 is the fraction of workers in a new industry, independent of k in the proposed equilibrium. The requirement that the log full-employment wages is ω ¯ in new industries implies (81)

L∗0 Hk Ckθ = Y x0θ−1 e−θω¯ hk

From equation (79), the left hand side is βL∗0 /L∗ . Eliminate L∗0 /L∗ using equation (80) to get (82)

β = φ1 Y

where

φ1 ≡

δx0θ−1 e−θω¯

σ2  θσ 2 f (ω) f (ω) ¯ ¯ − μ+ 2 2

9

SEARCH AND REST UNEMPLOYMENT

In each industry class k, we can solve for the productivity consistent with (l ω Y Ck ) as

(83)

leθω Ckθ x = ξ(l ω Y Ck ) ≡ Y

1/(θ−1)

Then using the production function, output in an industry in such an industry class, with l workers and log full-employment wage ω, is (84)

Q(l ξ(l ω Y Ck )) = Y −1/(θ−1) (eω lCk )θ/(θ−1) min{1 eω /br }θ

Using this notation, we can write the analog of equation (48) as  Y=

K  



k=1

K ⎜ ⎜ =⎝ k=1

hk

(θ−1)/θ

Q l(j t) ξ(l(j t) ω(j t) Y Ck )

θ/(θ−1) dj

hk−1



(θ−1)/θ ∗ L∗ Hk L Hk Q ξ  ω(j t) Y Ck hk hk hk−1

hk

⎞θ/(θ−1) ×

⎟ l(j t) dj ⎟ L∗ Hk ⎠ hk



The second equation follows because Q(· ξ(· ω Y Ck ))(θ−1)/θ is linear in l (equation (84)). To solve this, we change the variable of integration from the name of the industry j to its log full-employment wage ω and number of workers l. Let f˜(ω l) be the density of the joint invariant distribution of workers in industries (ω l), as discussed in Appendix A.4. Notice that under our hypothesis, this distribution is the same for all k. Then ⎛ K ⎜ ⎜ Y =⎝ hk k=1



ω ¯ ω ¯



∞ 0

(θ−1)/θ ∗ L∗ Hk L Hk Q ξ  ω Y Ck hk hk

⎞θ/(θ−1) ×

⎟ l f˜(ω l) dl dω⎟ ⎠ L∗ Hk hk



10

F. ALVAREZ AND R. SHIMER

Since f (ω) =

∞ 0

 Y=

l hk L∗ Hk

K 

f˜(ω l) dl, we can solve the inner integral to obtain 

ω ¯

hk ω ¯

k=1

(θ−1)/θ ∗ L∗ Hk L Hk Q ξ  ω Y Ck hk hk

θ/(θ−1)

× f (ω) dω without characterizing the joint density f˜. Using equation (84) and simplifying yields  K  

ω ¯  ∗ ω ω θ−1 (85) Hk Ck e min{1 e /br } f (ω) dω Y =L ω ¯

k=1

Since total output in the economy is consumed by the households, (86)

Y=

K 

Hk Ck

k=1

Then equation (85) implies  (87)

ω ¯



L =

−1 e min{1 e /br } ω

ω

θ−1

f (ω) dω



ω ¯

This defines L∗ . Next, substitute for Ck in equation (86) using equation (79):  K θ β  (θ−1)/θ 1/θ θ Y = ∗ (88) Hk hk L k=1 Eliminate β using equation (82) to get an expression for total output:

(89)

φ1 Y= L∗

1/(θ−1)  K

θ/(θ−1) H

(θ−1)/θ k

h

1/θ k



k=1

This defines Y . Finally, one can go back to equation (82) to determine β and then return to equation (79) to pin down Ck , closing the model. Note that assumption (77) implies consumption is increasing in k. To prove that a type k household prefers to work on industry k to other industries j = 1  k − 1, we show that wages are increasing in k. This follows because, with logarithmic utility, the actual wage is the product of ω (whose distribution is independent of k) and consumption. Q.E.D.

SEARCH AND REST UNEMPLOYMENT

11

REFERENCES ABEL, A. B., AND J. C. EBERLY (1996): “Optimal Investment With Costly Reversibility,” Review of Economic Studies, 63 (4), 581–593. [4,6] BENTOLILA, S., AND G. BERTOLA (1990): “Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad Is Eurosclerosis?” Review of Economic Studies, 47 (3), 381–402. [4] FLEMING, W. H., AND M. H. SONER (1993): Controlled Markov Processes and Viscosity Solutions. New York: Springer-Verlag. [5] STOKEY, N. L. (2009): The Economics of Inaction: Stochastic Control Models With Fixed Costs. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Unversity Press. [1]

Dept. of Economics, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637, U.S.A.; [email protected] and Dept. of Economics, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637, U.S.A.; robert. [email protected]. Manuscript received January, 2008; final revision received June, 2010.

Supplement to "Search and Rest Unemployment ...

the assumption that workers with a particular human capital level contact other workers with the same ... for all k = 1 K and some constant β. The distribution f ...

103KB Sizes 0 Downloads 169 Views

Recommend Documents

Search and Rest Unemployment
May 28, 2010 - duction technology that is continually hit by idiosyncratic shocks. .... In contrast, the benefit of rest unemployment—the possibility of high .... Although our model is not about business cycles, it too suggests that labor hoarding.

Search and Rest Unemployment
May 28, 2010 - depressed industries may be rest unemployed, waiting for local conditions to ..... To stress this point, we call ω(j, t) the log full-employment wage.

Unemployment and Search Externalities in a Model ...
workers always earn higher wages than low-skilled workers at simple jobs because ... relatively high and persistent unemployment rates for low-skilled workers ..... costs of keeping the vacancy open, the interest on alternative investments and.

equilibrium search unemployment, endogenous ...
Apr 4, 2005 - welfare-state programs requires high employment and high labor force ...... We ignore issues of imperfect monitoring from the public service ...

Introduction to REST and RestHUB - GitHub
2. RestHUBанаRESTful API for Oracle DB querying. 2.1. Overview. RestHub was designed .... For example we want to create a simple HTML + Javascript page.

Supplement to - GitHub
Supplemental Table S6. .... 6 inclusion or exclusion of certain genetic variants in a pharmacogenetic test ..... http://aidsinfo.nih.gov/contentfiles/AdultandAdolescentGL.pdf. .... 2.0 are expected to exhibit higher CYP2D6 enzyme activity versus ...

supplement to study material - ICSI
Ensure that advertisement giving details relating to oversubscription, basis ... Ensure that no advertisement or distribution material with respect to the issue.

A Directed Search Model of Ranking by Unemployment ...
May 17, 2011 - tribution may be quite sensitive to business cycle fluctuations. Shocks on ... Ranking of job applicants by unemployment duration has first been introduced by Blanchard ...... Third, farming-, army- and public-administration-.

A Directed Search Model of Ranking by Unemployment ...
University Carlos III of Madrid & Norwegian School of Management. May 17, 2011 ... Ministry of Science and Technology under Grant Nos. SEJ2007-63098 and 2011/0031/001, ..... the firm to offer a positive net wage to all types of workers.

Unemployment and Business Cycles
Nov 23, 2015 - a critical interaction between the degree of price stickiness, monetary policy and the ... These aggregates include labor market variables like.

Equilibrium search unemployment with explicit spatial ...
mobile. We demonstrate that the size of this area goes continuously to zero when ..... land rents and, after some time, they will have to relocate in cheaper places. ..... To the best of our knowledge, the only urban/labor papers that explicitly deal

supplement to study material - ICSI
(ii) the issuer undertakes to provide market-making for at least two years from ..... buyers if an issuer has not satisfied the basic eligibility criteria and undertakes ...... buyers on proportionate basis as per illustration given in Part C of Sche

Unemployment and Business Cycles
Nov 23, 2015 - *Northwestern University, Department of Economics, 2001 Sheridan Road, ... business cycle models pioneered by Kydland and Prescott (1982).1 Models that ...... Diamond, Peter A., 1982, “Aggregate Demand Management in ...

Rest and Recovery.pdf
Page 2 of 2. Rest and Recovery.pdf. Rest and Recovery.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu. Displaying Rest and Recovery.pdf.

SUPPLEMENT TO “PREFERENCE FOR FLEXIBILITY AND RANDOM ...
Jan 8, 2013 - THEOREM S1: The relation ≽ satisfies Axioms DLR 1–5 if and only if there .... equivalent to maximizing a random utility function that assigns ...

supplement to direct and indirect taxation -
(ii) In case of women resident in India and below the age of 65 years at any .... research expenditure with effect from the 1st day of April, 2008 [S.35(2AB)] - ...... AMENDMENTS RELATED TO SERVICE TAX (CHAPTER V AND VA OF THE.

Supplement to: Competition and Nonlinear Pricing in ...
This note is organized as follows: Section 1 provides an alternative method to derive the optimal allocation for Principal 2, following Rochet and Chone (1998) and Basov (2002). Sec- tion 2 provides the proofs left unsolved in the main paper. In sect

Unemployment and Development
This paper draws on household survey data from countries of all income levels to ..... unlikely that measurement error on this dimension is much of a limitation. ...... Malaysia. 1991, 2000. IPUMS-I. Mexico. 1990, 1995, 2000, 2010, 2015. IPUMS- ...

Unemployment Benefits and Unemployment in the ... - Penn Economics
impact of right-to-work laws on location of manufacturing industry and by Dube et al. (2010) to identify the effect of minimum ...... Subsidies,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 43, 457–495. Shimer, R. (2007): “Reassesing the Ins and Outs of Une

Unemployment Benefits and Unemployment in the ... - Penn Economics
The key feature of the U.S. unemployment insurance system is that unemployment insurance policies are determined at the state level ..... benefit extensions on unemployment that we document. Our point of departure is the analysis in Section 4.7 .....

Supplement to "Robust Nonparametric Confidence ...
Page 1 ... INTERVALS FOR REGRESSION-DISCONTINUITY DESIGNS”. (Econometrica ... 38. S.2.6. Consistent Bandwidth Selection for Sharp RD Designs .

Supplement to "Efficient Repeated Implementation"
the definition of ψ of ˆg) but induces regime Dj in which, by (A.1), j obtains vj j > πθ(t) θt j . But this is a contradiction. Q.E.D. ... Next define ρ ≡ maxi θ a a [ui(a θ)−ui(a θ)] and ¯δ ≡ ρ ρ+ε . Mechanism ˜g = (M ψ) is def