Z-Estimators and Auxiliary Information under Weak Dependence Federico Crudu y University of Groningen and CRENoS December 2010

Abstract In this paper we introduce a weighted Z-estimator for moment condition models in the presence of auxiliary information on the unknown distribution of the data under the assumption of weak dependence. The resulting weighted estimator is shown to be consistent and asymptotically normal. The proposed estimator is computationally simple and shows nice …nite sample features when compared to asymptotically equivalent estimators. JEL Classi…cation: C12, C14, C22. Keywords: Z-estimators, M-estimators, GMM, Generalized Empirical Likelihood, blocking techniques, -mixing.

Corresponding address: Department of Economics and Econometrics, University of Groningen, Nettelbosje 2, 9747 AE, Groningen, The Netherlands. Email: [email protected]. y This paper is based on Chapter 4 of my PhD thesis at the University of York. I am grateful to Francesco Bravo and Fabrizio Iacone for helpful comments on the previous drafts of the paper. I wish to thank Patrick Marsh, Jan Podivinsky, Michalis Stamatogiannis, Dimitris Politis, and Jochen Mierau. Comments from Tom Wansbeek are gratefully aknowledged. This research is partially supported by the Marie Curie Excellence Grant MEXT-CT-2006-042471 and by the RAS Master&Back Program 2006-3066. All remaining errors are my own.

1

1

Introduction

In a number of situations that are relevant in practice, a researcher may have prior knowledge of some features of the distribution of the sample (the population mean, or the median, for example, or other features related to the shape of the distribution), without necessarily knowing the actual distribution function underlying the data. Zhang (1995) extends the standard M-estimation setting to the possibility of including auxiliary information in the form of weights, which are estimated by empirical likelihood (EL). In a more recent paper Bravo (2008, 2010) devises a two step procedure for M-estimation with auxiliary information and extends the results of Zhang (1995) to the more general class of generalized empirical likelihood (GEL) estimators. A series of papers by Imbens and coauthors investigates the use of auxiliary information in the case of microeconometric models (see Hellerstein and Imbens, 1999, Imbens and Lancaster, 1994, Imbens, 1992). Hellerstein and Imbens (1999) estimate a wage regression by means of weighted least squares. The set of weights they use is based on Census data and estimated via EL. Imbens and Lancaster (1994) use macro data as auxiliary information in the context of a GMM estimator. In the statistical literature, similar results are for example related to the work of Kuk and Mak (1989) in the context of median estimation or to Chen and Qin (1993), who also exploit EL probabilities to carry the auxiliary information. Although a number of papers have dealt with this type of problems, little

2

attention has been paid to the case where the data show some time series features (Smith, 2004, is one of the few examples, at least to the knowledge of the author). The purpose of this paper is to introduce a weighted Z-estimator for moment condition models in the presence of weak dependence (Van der Vaart, 2007, p. 41). The proposed method is based on the GEL estimator and consists of two steps: the …rst step estimates the distribution of the data from the auxiliary data by means of GEL procedures; the second step applies the GEL weights to the initial set of estimating equations and computes the parameters of interest. In addition to that, the weak dependence structure of the data is taken care by means of a blockwise approach (Kitamura, 1997). The resulting estimator is e¢ cient in the sense that has the same asymptotic variance of a GMM estimator or a one-step GEL estimator (Smith, 2004) that uses the same amount of information. This paper is meant to be an extension to the time series case of some results of Bravo (2008, 2010) and it is related to an earlier paper of Qian and Schmidt (1999, QS hereafter) and to the aforementioned paper by Smith (2004). The estimators of QS and Smith are asymptotically equivalent to our weighted Z-estimator. However, there are some reasons why the latter may be preferable. Smith proposes a one-step estimator where both the initial moment conditions and the auxiliary information are included into the GEL criterion function. This type of approach implies that the resulting estimator is the solution of a saddle point problem, which is generally computationally very demanding, particularly when the model is very nonlinear. 3

The paper of QS suggests including the auxiliary information into a GMM setting. However, it is well known that GMM could perform very poorly in …nite samples (see Altonji and Segal, 1996, among others), and it is reasonable to think that also QS’s estimator inherits such …nite sample features. In our simulation study we show that the e¢ cient Z-estimator tends to improve the GMM estimator in the majority of the cases we consider. Interestingly, Bravo (2010) shows that, under certain conditions and for the type of auxiliary information considered here, the two step estimator has better higher order properties than the GMM estimator and the one-step GEL estimator1 . The contribution of this paper is twofold. First, we show that the prop posed estimator is n-consistent and asymptotically normal, then we show that the weighted Z-estimator is more e¢ cient than its unweighted counterpart. Second, we provide Monte Carlo evidence on the performance (in terms of bias and mean squared error) of the weighted Z-estimator against its unweighted counterpart; we also show that in …nite samples the weighted estimator improves an asymptotically equivalent GMM estimator. The simulation results are also analyzed with respect to the choice of an arbitrary blocklength and an optimal (i.e. data-driven) blocklength. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Sections 2 and 3 we outline the estimator and the main asymptotic results. In Section 4 we describe the …nite sample properties of three speci…cations of our Z-estimator against two competing estimators. Section 5 contains some concluding re1

Bravo (2010) does not consider weakly dependent data.

4

marks. Proofs and …gures are relegated to the appendix.

2

Z-Estimation and Generalized Empirical Likelihood

Let fxt g be an RLx -valued stationary strong mixing process from an unknown distribution F , and consider a set of di¤erentiable functions,

m ( ) = E (m (xt ; ))

such that m : RLx

RL ! RLm ; and m (

0)

= 0 (see the Appendix for

some additional detail on the mixing process). Moreover, B

0

2 int fBg and

RL , and L is assumed to equal Lm . A Z-estimator for

0,

say ^ ,

satis…es the relationship m ^ ^

where m ^( )=

1 n

Pn

t=1

= inf km ^ ( )k = 0; 2B

(1)

mt ( ) and mt ( ) = m (xt ; ). Furthermore, we take

into account the presence of weak dependence by means of a blockwise approach. Let us assume that M and L are integers and M ! 1 as n ! 1, p M = o ( n), L = O (M ), and L M . The estimator we propose treats the estimation of a set of probabilities and of the parameter of interest separately, in order to reduce the computational complexity and exploit the

5

desirable small sample features of the BGEL estimator. Thus, the blockwise counterpart of (1) is ^ ^ h ^( )= and h

1 b

Pb

i=1

^( ) =0 = inf h

hi ( ), hi ( ) = h (zi ; ), and h (zi ; ) =

where i = 1; :::; b and b =

n M L

(2)

2B

1 M

PM

j=1

m x(i

1)L+j ;

+ 1. Notice that b is the blockwise sample

size, M indicates how many observations are included in a block (i.e. the blocklength), and L denotes the distance between the …rst observation of block i and the …rst observation of block i + 12 . This blockwise approach is a simple method to take into account the time series properties of the data and it simply reduces to rearranging the them (or the associated moment functions) in an appropriate way3 . Let us assume now that there exists some auxiliary information about the unknown distribution of the data, shaped into a certain function f : RLx ! RLf that we can de…ne in terms of a moment condition model, independent of the unknown parameter E (ft ) = 0 for ft = f (xt ) : As for equation (2), we can de…ne its blockwise counterpart 2

As Kitamura (1997) pointed out, treating the data as if they were independent would cause the estimator to be ine¢ cient. 3 The use of blocks does not require postulating a weighting function as in the case of kernel smoothing. In addition, Kitamura (1997) pointed out that for L = 1 (the fully overlapping case) the blockwise structure corresponds asymptotically to the Bartlett kernel and for other choices of L we have di¤erent kernel structures (see also Politis and Romano, 1993).

6

,

as M 1 X f x(i g (zi ) = M j=1

1)L+j

(3)

:

At this stage, our problem is to …nd a suitable way to incorporate the auxiliary information described in (3). In order to do that we follow Bravo (2008, see also Zhang, 1995). This is, we estimate a set of probabilities by means of GEL, using the moment functions in (3). The resulting probabilities are used to weight our initial Z-estimator (2), in order to obtain a blockwise GEL (BGEL) weighted Z-estimator. The subsequent BGEL function is X ^( )= 1 R ( 0 gi ) ; b i=1 b

where gi = g (zi ) and

( ) is the so-called carrier function, concave in its

domain, and normalized to be

1

(0) =

2

(0) =

1, given that

j

( ), j = 1; 2

is the jth derivative (Newey and Smith, 2004). Notice that for log (1

v), ( ) =

exp (v), and ( ) =

( ) =

(1 + v)2 =2 we have the empirical

likelihood case, the exponential tilting case, and the Euclidean likelihood case respectively. They can be considered as special cases of the empirical Cressie(1 + v)(1+ ) = (1 + ) where

Read family of discrepancies ( ) =

is a real

number. Let ^ = arg max R ^( ) 2

7

n

(4)

then one can show that the estimated probabilities are de…ned as

^i = P b

^ 0 gi

1

1

j=1

:

^ 0 gj

The resulting BGEL-weighted estimation functions are then de…ned as

^ ( )= h

b X

^ i hi ( )

i=1

where ^ i is the BGEL estimator for the probability density function as described above. Thus, the corresponding Z-estimator with auxiliary information, ^ , implies ^ h

^ ( ) = 0: = inf h

^

2B

In Section 3 it will be shown that the estimator ^ is consistent and asymptotically Normal, with asymptotic variance V :

V = M(

0 0)

1

S(

0)

B(

where M ( ) = E (@mt ( ) =@ 0 ), B ( ) = E and

1

1

0)

are respectively the variance of m ^(

B(

P1

s= 1

0)

0 0)

(mt

(M (

s

0 ))

1

;

( ) ft0 ) ; and S (

0)

and ^ . From the above expres-

sion it follows that the estimator we propose is asymptotically more e¢ cient than an estimator that does not exploit the available auxiliary information, as its variance is M (

0 0)

1

S(

0 ) (M

(

0 ))

1

. Clearly, the e¢ ciency of the

weighted estimator depends on the relevance of the auxiliary information 8

and, therefore, on the covariance between the original moment function m and the vector of auxiliary moments f , B ( ): thus, the larger the covariance B ( ), the smaller the resulting asymptotic variance V . It is also quite obvious that if the covariance is zero ^ and ^ share the same variance. An alternative approach is due to QS, and it consists of constructing a moment vector that includes the extra moments

m ^f ( ) =

1 n

n X t=1

0

1

B mt ( ) C @ A: ft

(5)

The above model is overidenti…ed, since Lm + Lf > L (notice that we consider Lm = L ) and the associated parameter vector may be estimated by GMM. The resulting estimator is asymptotically equivalent to our weighted Z-estimator. Notice that the standard asymptotic variance for the GMM estimator is G (

0 0)

(

0)

1

G(

1

0)

. In our case G (

0)

= (E (@mt (

0 ) =@

0

where the presence of the zeros depends on the fact that the portion of the moment vector that carries the auxiliary information is independent of the estimand parameter vector. The matrix elements on the main diagonal are S ( is the covariance matrix B ( and V = G (

0 0)

(

0)

1

0 ).

G(

0)

is a 2 2 block matrix, whose

and

, and the o¤ diagonal entry

( 0)

After some simple algebra the result follows, 0)

1 4

: A further method that is similar to

ours is due to Smith (2004), and consists of estimating the parameters, given 4

The result in Qian and Schmidt (1999) is slightly di¤erent, since the initial vector of moments, m in our notation, is overidenti…ed.

9

0

) ; 0) ,

the augmented vector of moments in (5), by means of (smoothed) GEL. Such procedure consists of augmenting the GEL criterion function by the vector of auxiliary moments and simultaneously compute the an estimate of the parameters of interest.5

3

Asymptotic Theory

The following theorems establish consistency and asymptotic normality of the Z-estimator with auxiliary information. Proofs follow some results of Pakes and Pollard (1989), Pakes and Linton (2001), and Bravo (2008). The following lemma establishes consistency and asymptotic normality of the BGEL estimator of the Lagrange multiplier in (4). Lemma 1 Assume 1) fxt gt2Z is a strictly stationary strong mixing sequence, 2(1+ )

2) E kft k

for some small enough

> 0,

3)R ( ) = E ( ( 0 ft )) has a maximum for the interior of the convex set

n

= E (ft ft0 ) is positive de…nite, = 0 and it is unique, 4) zero is in

and ( ) is concave and twice continuously

di¤erentiable about zero and its jth derivative ^ ( ) !p R ( ) for all R

2

n,

j

(0) =

1, j = 1; 2, 5)

then ^ is consistent and normally distributed

p

n^ !d N 0; M

5

1

Smith (2004) assumes that the auxiliary set of moments also depends on , while in our case it does not. The …nal result is di¤erent since the asymptotic variance includes extra terms that involve the …rst derivatives of the auxiliary moments.

10

Theorem 2 and Theorem 3 establish consistency and asymptotic Normality for the e¢ cient Z-estimator ^ . Theorem 2 (Consistency of ^ ) Assume 1) B is a compact set, 2) 8 > 0 there exists " ( ) such that supk

0 k>

km ( )k

" ( ) > 0, 3) sup

2B

km ^( )

op (1). Then, if also the assumptions in Lemma 1 are satis…ed, ^ !p

m ( )k =

0:

Theorem 3 (Asymptotic Normality of ^ ) Assume ^ is consistent; moreover, assume 1) mt ( ) being continuously di¤erentiable in a neighborhood of 0,

N(

0;

), 2) M (

0)

= E (@mt (

0 ) =@

) is continuous and nonsingular,

E kmt ( 0 )k kft k2 < 1, and E sup 2N ( 0 ; ) (k@mt ( ) =@ k kft k) < 1, 3) p nm ^ ( 0 ) !d N (0; S ( 0 )). Then, if assumptions in Theorem 2 are satis…ed p ^ n 0 ! N (0; V ), where 0 0)

V = M(

and B (

0)

=E

P1

s= 1

1

S(

(mt

s

0)

(

B(

0)

1

B(

0 0)

(M (

0 ))

1

;

0 0 ) ft ).

The following corollary is a direct result of Theorem 3. It states that an estimator of the empirical distribution function based on the BGEL probabiliP ties is more e¢ cient than an estimator computed as ^ (x) = n1 nt=1 1 (xt x).

Corollary 4 Let

x). If assumptions in Theorems 2 and 3, p and assumption 1 in Lemma 1 hold, then ^ (z) !p (x) and n (^ (z) (x)) !d P N (0; 2 a0 1 a), where ^ (x) is the BGEL version of ^ (x) = n1 nt=1 1 (xt x), P that is ^ (z) = bt=1 ^ i 1M (zi z). (x) = Pr (xt

11

Proofs are in the appendix.

4

Monte Carlo Experiments

In this section we study the small sample features of our weighted Z-estimator. The main objective of these experiments is to analyze the behaviour of such estimators in terms of bias and mean square error (MSE) as n and the M vary. For convenience we only take into account the case L = 1, and we consider the e¤ect of arbitrary values of M against an optimal M . The optimal M is computed by means of the procedure suggested by Politis and White (2004, see also Patton, Politis, and White, 2009). Let us consider the estimation of a location parameter as in QS

yt =

where

0

0

+ et

is a scalar, and it is assumed to be equal to 1, and et is a zero mean

disturbance. Thus, we want to …nd an estimate for

0

= E (yt ). We also

assume there exists a certain random variable ut , that is known to have zero mean and it is correlated with et . We de…ne then the following equations:

yt = 1 + et ut =

et +

12

p

1

2

t:

The measures we use are both bias and mean square error (MSE).6 Moreover, we choose two speci…cations for the processes et and DGP 1 et = et DGP 2 et =

+ "et ,

1 et 1

Where "it (:7; :2),

1

+

t

= "t

2 et 2

1

+ "et ,

t:

+ "t t

=

t 1

+ "t :

N (0; 1), i = e; . The parameters are

= :8, (

1;

2)

=

= :8 and = :4. We compare the performance of various competing

estimators for n = 16; 64; 256, and M taking values from 2 to 16.7 The optimal M s are computed for both yt and ut : My and Mu .8 In Table 1 we report the average blocklengths for the two DGPs.

n

DGP 1 My

16 64 256

2.79803 7.98632 16.04077

Mu

DGP 2 My

Mu

2.50175 7.11904 15.07853

2.75609 9.59790 22.38312

2.51347 8.93313 21.88946

Table 1: Optimal blocklengths We compute an estimate for

0

in …ve di¤erent ways. The …rst is a simple

sample mean X ^=y= 1 yt : n t=1 n

6

In the …gures, the MSE is multiplied by the sample size. Notice that the case n = M = 16 is not taken into consideration as it is equivalent to M = 1. 8 The blocklength and the number of resulting blocks could be di¤erent for the two series. In order to overcome this issue, the data are wrapped around a circle and extra observations are used from the beginning of the series in order to have the same number of blocks (similar procedures are suggested in Davison and Hinkley, 1997, pp. 396-397). 7

13

The second is an e¢ cient GMM estimator with two moment conditions ^ = arg min g^ ( )0 ^

where g^ ( ) =

1 n

Pn

t=1

yt

0

; ut

1

g^ ( )

. The matrix of weights ^

is a

Newey-West matrix evaluated at a certain consistent estimator of , . The remaining three estimators are weighted averages based on GEL estimators, i.e. the EL, the ET and the EU estimator, b X

^=

^ GEL zi i

i=1

where zi =

PM

j=1

y(i

1)L+j .

Given the auxiliary information wi =

the three BGEL estimators for the probabilities are de…ned as

^ EL = i

PM

j=1

u(i

1)L+j ,

1 EL b 1 + ^ wi ET exp ^ wi

^ ET = P i b

j=1

^ EU = i

where w =

1 b

Pb

i=1

ET exp ^ wj

1 1 b

^ EU (wi

w)

EL ET wi . ^ and ^ are computed numerically, while it is

available a close form solution for ^

EU

. Each weighted estimator is computed

for di¤erent values of M , where M goes from 2 to 16 and for an optimal M . The calculations are carried out in R and are based on 100000 Monte Carlo 14

repetitions. The results of the simulations are summarized in the appendix. Figures 1 to 4 describe the behaviour of the weighted estimators as the blocklength changes compared to those estimators that are independent of M , represented by the horizontal lines. In particular, the thick (dashed, longdashed, or dotdashed) horizontal lines denote the weighted estimators based on My and Mu and are denoted as OptEL, OptET , and OptEU . The thin dashed line indicates the sample mean. We notice that when the sample size is small, the choice of M has a considerable impact on bias and MSE. In general, we …nd that the bias is very small, but, given the scale of the vertical axis, it tends to vary considerably with M when the sample is small (i.e. n = 16; 64). In Figures 2 and 4 we see that the MSE tends to grow with M , while as n increases the slope of the curves corresponding to the EL and ET estimators becomes smaller and collapses to OptEL and OptET . On the other hand, the MSE of the EU-based estimator is upward-sloping also for n = 256. The e¤ect of an arbitrary choice of M may have a large impact on the MSE in small samples. Such an e¤ect is more prominent for the EL case and the EU case. For the latter, it persists also for larger values of n. Overall the EL estimator and the ET estimator that use an optimal blocklength have smaller MSE than GMM. Apart from small values of n, the EU estimator that uses an optimal blocklength is very similar to the GMM estimator. The MSE for the sample mean is, as expected, the largest in the panel. 15

5

Conclusion

In this paper we propose a two step procedure for Z-estimators in the presence of weakly dependent data and auxiliary information based on the estimation of BGEL probabilities. This approach is attractive from di¤erent points of view. First of all, the computation of the BGEL probabilities is very simple, as it contemplates only the convex part of the BGEL problem (this is, the estimation of the Lagrange multiplier ). Moreover, whenever the Z-estimator is asymptotically equivalent to a GMM estimator (QS), it does not entail the well-known small sample e¤ects that a¤ect GMM estimators (see for example Altonji and Segal, 1996). Our asymptotic results state that the resulting Z-estimator is consistent and Normally distributed. The resulting variance depends on the relevance of the auxiliary information. In addition, we demonstrate that the estimator of a distribution based on the BGEL weights enjoys the same favourable features of the abovementioned Zestimator. Furthermore, by means of Monte Carlo experiments, we describe how to apply our approach to a standard time series problem. The laboratory we set is a location parameter estimation problem, similar to what is described in QS (see also Zhang, 1995). We compare three BGEL weighted estimators against a simple sample mean and an augmented GMM estimator, and we analyze their behaviour for di¤erent values of M and n. We argue that an appropriate choice of M is crucial in particular when the sample is small; because of that we advocate the use of data driven procedures for the

16

selection of the blocklength (see Politis and White, 2004). The simulation results suggest that, in general, weighted estimators (in particular those based on ET) combined with an optimal blocklength improve over the competing estimators.

References [1] Altonji, J. G., L. M. Segal (1996): Small-sample bias in GMM estimation of covariance structures, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 14, 353-366. [2] Bravo, F. (2010): E¢ cient M-estimators with auxiliary information, Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference, 140, 3326-3342. [3] Bravo, F. (2009): Blockwise generalized empirical likelihood inference for non-linear dynamic moment conditions models, The Econometrics Journal, 12, 208-231. [4] Bravo, F. (2008): E¢ cient M-estimators with auxiliary information, University of York Working Paper. [5] Chamberlain, G. (1987): Asymptotic e¢ ciency in estimation with conditional moment restrictions, Journal of Econometrics, 34, 305-334.

17

[6] Chen, J. J. Qin (1993): Empirical likelihood estimation for …nite populations and the e¤ective usage of auxiliary information, Biometrika, 80, 107-116. [7] Crudu, F. (2009): GMM, Generalized Empirical Likelihood, and Time Series, Working Paper CRENoS. [8] Davison, A. C., D. V. Hinkley (1997): Bootstrap Methods and their Applications, CUP. [9] Fitzenberger, B. (1997), The moving blocks bootstrap and robust inference for linear least squares and quantile regression, Journal of Econometrics, 82, 235-287. [10] Hansen, L. P. (1982): Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimator, Econometrica, 50, 1029-1054. [11] Hay…eld, rics:

T.,

J. S. Racine (2008). Nonparametric Economet-

The np Package, Journal of Statistical Software 27, URL

http://www.jstatsoft.org/v27/i05/. [12] Hellerstein, J. G. W. Imbens (1999): Imposing moment restrictions from auxiliary data by weighting, Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 114. [13] Ibragimov, I. A., Y. V. Linnik (1971): Independent and Stationary Sequences of Random Variables. Wolters-Noordho¤, Groningen. 18

[14] Imbens, G. W. (1992): An e¢ cient method of moments estimator for discrete choice models with choice-based sampling, Econometrica, 60, 1187-1214. [15] Imbens, G. W., T. Lancaster (1994): Combining micro and macro data in microeconometric models, Review of Economic Studies, 61, 655-680. [16] Kitamura, Y. (1997): Empirical likelihood methods with weakly dependent processes, The Annals of Statistics, 25, 2084-2102. [17] Kuk, A. Y. C., T. K. Mak (1989): Median estimation in the presence of auxiliary information, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B, 51, 261-269. [18] Newey, W. K., D. McFadden (1994): Large sample estimation and hypothesis testing, in Handbook of Econometrics vol. IV, ed. R. Engle and D. McFadden. North Holland. [19] Newey, W. K., R. J. Smith (2004): Higher order properties of GMM and generalized empirical likelihood estimators, Econometrica, 72, 219-255. [20] Newey, W. K., K. West (1987): A simple positive semide…nite heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix, Econometrica, 55, 703-708. [21] Owen, A. B. (2001): Empirical Likelihood, Chapman-Hall.

19

[22] Pakes, A., O. Linton (2001): Nonlinear Methods for Econometrics, LSE lecture notes http://econ.lse.ac.uk/sta¤/olinton/ec481/aet.pdf. [23] Pakes, A., D. Pollard (1989): Simulation and the asymptotics of optimization estimators, Econometrica, 57, 1027-1057. [24] Patton, A., D. N. Politis, H. White (2009): CORRECTION TO “Automatic Block-Length Selection for the Dependent Bootstrap” by D. Politis and H. White, Econometric Reviews, 28, 372-375. [25] Politis, D. N., J. P. Romano, On the Sample Variance of Linear Statistics Derived from Mixing Sequences, Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 45, 155-167. [26] Politis, D. N., H. White (2004): Automatic block-length selection for the dependent bootstrap, Econometric Reviews, 23, 53-70. [27] Qian, H., P. Schmidt (1999): Improved instrumental variables and generalized method of moments estimators, Journal of Econometrics, 91, 145-169. [28] Smith, R. J. (2004): GEL criteria for moment condition models, cemmap Working Paper. [29] Van der Vaart, A. (2007): Asymptotic Statistics, CUP.

20

[30] Zhang, B. (1995): M-estimation and quantile estimation in the presence of auxiliary information, Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference, 44, 77-94.

21

Appendix: Proofs and Figures In what follows we present the proofs of the theorems presented in Section 3 and some auxiliary results. In addition, we use the following notation: !p and !d denote convergence in probability and convergence in distribution; C is a generic positive constant; CS and T denote Cauchy-Schwarz inequality and triangular inequality respectively; k k is the Euclidean norm of . The CLT is meant to be a central limit theorem for strong mixing sequences (see e.g. Ibragimov and Linnik, 1971) and CMT is the continuous mapping theorem. We assume throughout that the following standard strong mixing conditions are satis…ed x

where 00

m Fm 0 =

x

(k) ! 0; k ! 1

Pr (A) Pr (B)j, A 2 F 0 1 , B 2 Fk1 , and P 1 1c < 1 for some m00 ). We also assume 1 k=1 x (k)

(k) = supA;B jPr (A \ B) (xi : m0

constant c > 1:

i

Proof of Lemma 1. Consider again X ^( )= 1 R ( 0 gi ) : b i=1 b

^ ( ) is concave through Notice that R

( ). Moreover, assumptions 2 to

4 match assumptions (i)-(iii) from Theorem 2.7 of Newey and McFadden (1994). Then, consistency of ^ follows. Consider now a mean value expansion of the …rst order conditions of the

22

GEL criterion function, ^ ^ @R 0 =

@

=

b MX b i=1

g+

Since ^ is consistent and _ p Thus, multiplying by n p

0=

1X b i=1 b

=

_ 0 gi gi

1

0

_ gi gi g 0 i

1

^ , we have that

p ^ ^ n M

ng

!

1

^ M _ 0 gi =

1 + op (1).

p ^ op (1) ^ n M

P P p ^ where ^ = M bi=1 gi gi0 =b and g = bi=1 gi =b. Notice that ^ n M = Op (1); therefore, by rearranging

p ^ n = M Finally, by applying CLT to

p

^

1

p

ng + op (1) :

(A.1)

ng and Slutsky theorem, the result follows.

Proof of Theorem 2 (Consistency of ^ ). value expansion of ^i = P

^ 0 gi

1

j

1

23

^ 0 gj

Let us compute a mean

= 0, where ^ is a consistent estimator for :

about

^i =

=

0

1 1B 2 + @ b b 1P 0

b

j

1 1B 2 + @ b b 1P b

j

_ 0 gi g 0 i 1

1

_ 0 gj

1 b

_ 0 gi ^ 0 gi 1

^ 0 gi P

1

_ gj

j

1

j

^ 0 gi

0

P

1 b

1 b

1 b

P

j

P

j

1

2

_ 0 gj 2

1 _ 0 gj g 0 jC A ^ 2

0

1 _ 0 gj ^ 0 gj C A: 2

_ 0 gj

From results of Lemma 1 we obtain

^i =

1 1 ^0 + gi + op (1) b b

(A.2)

1 (1 + op (1)) : b

(A.3)

and ^i =

^ ( )=m From Lemma 1 in Crudu (2009) we have h ^ ( ) + Op (M=n). Then, ^ by adding and subtracting h m ^

^

m ^

and T ^ h

^ + h

^

Moreover, by optimality of ^ and since m (

0)

^

= 0, and by repeated appli-

cation of Lemma 1 in Crudu (2009) and T m ^

m ^ sup km ( ) 2B

m ^ ^

+ (1 + op (1)) km ^(

0)

m ^ ( )k + (1 + op (1)) sup km ^( ) 2B

24

M n M m ( )k + Op n

m(

0 )k

+ Op

:

By Assumption 3 sup

2B

km ( )

m ^ ( )k = op (1); hence

m ^

op (1) :

Since m ( ) is bounded away from zero for k follows that ^ 2 k

0k

0k

>

is arbitrary, ^ !p

< . As

(assumption 2), it 0:

Proof of Theorem 3 (Asymptotic Normality of ^ ). Let us consider P ^ = 0; by replacing the probabilities with the expression in A.2 i ^ i hi 0=

0 1X 1 + ^ gi + op (1) hi ^ b i

and mean value expand hi ^

0 =

X

0

X

0 1 + ^ gi @hi (

i

where _

0,

for ^ being consistent

0 1 + ^ gi + op (1) hi ^

i

=

about

0

^

0

@hi _ 0)

+

@

^

0

1

^ ^ A + op (1) h

^ ( ) = M P hi ( ) g 0 =b. Then, . Let us de…ne B i i

25

by appropriate rescaling and (A.1)

0 =

p ^( )+B ^ ( 0 ) ^ 1 ng nh 0 0 X @hi _ 0X 1 @hi ( +@ +^ gi b i @ @ i

p

+op (1)

p

0)

^ ^ nh

1

=bA

p

n ^

0

= A1 + A 2 + A3

where A1 = A2 =

X

p

^( nh

0 @hi _ =@ + ^

0)

^( +B

X

0)

gi @hi (

^

1

p

0 ) =@

i

i

A3 = op (1)

p

^ ^ nh

ng; !

=b

p

n ^

;

0

:

p ^ From assumption 3 and Lemma 1 in Crudu (2009) nh ( 0 ) !d N (0; S ( 0 )) p and ng !d N (0; ). Then, after simple calculations, we get A1 !d N (0; W ), where

W =

I;

= S(

0)

B( B(

0)

0)

1

1

0

B S ( 0) B ( @ B ( 0 )0

B(

0 0)

26

0)

10 CB A@

I 1

B(

0

0)

1 C A

Let us now focus attention on A2 . By Lemma 1 in Crudu (2009) and T

^0 1 b

X

@hi _ gi

i

0

@

1 X @mt ft n t @

^

_ + Op

0

M n

X @mt ( ) ^ 1 sup ft + op (1) : n t 2B @ 0

Thus, ^0 1 b

X

By CMT and assumption 3

@hi _ gi

op (1) :

@

i

p ^ ^ nh

is Normally distributed. Thus, its

order of magnitude is Op (1) and A3 = op (1). Finally,

M(

0 0)

p

n ^

0

=

^( B

I;

0

1 p ^ B nh ( 0 ) C @ p A + op (1) ng

1

0)

and p

n ^

0

=

M(

0 0)

1

which implies, by CLT applied to p

n ^

0

!d N 0; M (

0 0)

^( B

I;

p

0)

0

1 p ^ B nh ( 0 ) C @ p A+op (1) ng

1

ng, assumption 3 and CMT,

1

S(

27

0)

B(

0)

1

B(

0 0)

(M (

0 ))

1

:

Proof of Corollary 4. From results in Lemma 1 and Theorem 2 we have 1X ^ (z) = 1M (zi b t=1 b

g0 ^

^ b (z)

0

z) 1 + ^ gi + op (1) M X p gi 1M (zi nb t=1 b

1

Then, by adding and subtracting

z) + op

1 p n

(x) and multiplying both sides by

p

n,

we get p

n (^ (z)

(x)) =

= !

p

1X gi 1M (zi (x)) ng b t=1 0 1 p (x)) C B n (^ b (z) @ A p ng p

n (^ b (z)

a ^0

1; dN

0;

2

a0

The result follows by CLT applied to

p

sky theorem.

28

1

b

0^

z) + op (1)

a :

n (^ b (z)

(x)) and

p

ng and Slut-

n=64

0.002 bias 0.001

-0.005 -0.007

0.000

-0.006

bias

-0.004

0.003

-0.003

n=16

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

2

4

6

8

M

10 M

n=256

EL,OptEL

-2e-04

ET ,OptET EU ,OptEU GMM

-1e-03

-6e-04

bias

Mean

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

M

Figure 1: Bias of the Z-estimators for DGP 1 29

12

14

16

n=64

40

MSE

30 15

20

20

25

MSE

35

60

40

45

80

n=16

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

2

4

6

8

M

10 M

n=256

EL,OptEL 80

ET ,OptET EU ,OptEU

60

GMM

0

20

40

MSE

Mean

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

M

Figure 2: MSE of the Z-estimators for DGP 1 30

12

14

16

n=64

-0.0012

-0.0008

bias

0.0000 -0.0010

bias

0.0010

-0.0004

n=16

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

2

4

6

8

M

10 M

n=256

3e-04

EL,OptEL ET ,OptET EU ,OptEU

1e-04

Mean

-1e-04 -3e-04

bias

GMM

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

M

Figure 3: Bias of the Z-estimators for DGP 2 31

12

14

16

n=64

MSE 5

5

10

10

MSE

15

15

20

20

n=16

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

2

4

6

8

M

10 M

25

n=256

EL,OptEL 20

ET ,OptET EU ,OptEU

15

GMM

5

10

MSE

Mean

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

M

Figure 4: MSE of the Z-estimators for DGP 2 32

12

14

16

Z$Estimators and Auxiliary Information under Weak ...

The set of weights they use is based on Census data and estimated via EL. ..... (see e.g. Ibragimov and Linnik, 1971) and CMT is the continuous mapping.

219KB Sizes 0 Downloads 130 Views

Recommend Documents

Weak Atomicity Under the x86 Memory Consistency ...
Feb 16, 2011 - Keywords Software Transactional Memory, x86 Memory Model. 1. Introduction ... C++: Catch fire due to data race, any result allowed ... clude only programs with Transactional Reads Unprotected Writes. Copyright is held by ...

Weak Atomicity Under the x86 Memory Consistency ...
Feb 16, 2011 - Programming Techniques Concurrent Programming. General Terms ... In contrast to SLA work in these language level mem- ory models, there ...

Auxiliary Membership.pdf
Page 1 of 1. American Legion Auxiliary. World's largest women's patriotic service organization. MEMBERSHIP APPLICATION. APPLICANT INFORMATION.

On Deliberation under Incomplete Information and the Inadequacy of ...
School of Computer Science .... sensing by using online sensors instead of specific sensing actions. ..... interpreter for high-level programs with sensing. In.

On Deliberation under Incomplete Information and the Inadequacy of ...
School of Computer Science and Engineering ... Keywords. Agent programming, deliberation, semantics, situation cal- culus ... Golog to specify agent programs as described in Section 2, .... online configurations (δ0 = δ, σ0 = σ),..., (δn, σn) s

Business Auxiliary Services.pdf
as amended by Clause (f) of Section 107 and Clause (2) of Section 109 of. Finance Act, 2015 ... legislative competence to enact the said amendments since the activity of ... under Entry 51 of List II of Schedule VII to the Constitution. The case of .

lobbying under asymmetric information
home firm can convey this information to the policymaker via costly lobbying. ... This is the system that we have. I didn't .... 6 We use Brander-Spencer (1985) framework since its the simplest best-known model in trade. ..... costs as expenses like

Competitive Screening under Heterogeneous Information
equilibrium outcome under duopoly often lies between the monopoly and the perfectly competitive outcome, and that (ii) when .... competitive outcomes.10 Frictions in our model have a different nature (they are informational). Faig and Jerez (2005) ..

Competitive Screening under Heterogeneous Information
of sales. Firms then have to design their menu of products accounting for consumers' choices of which firm to ..... the best offer available), expected sales to each type k depend on the rank Fk(uk) of the indirect ..... value for quality in televisi

under conditions of limited information
of location; as regional economies in developing countries are very open, ... input-output accounts, one that has been rarely implemented given the .... Banking and Finance. 9. ... development of a Wales-Rest of the U.K. interregional table.

Call Center Outsourcing Contracts Under Information Asymmetry
combinations of these contract features enable client firms to better manage vendors when there is information asymmetry about worker productivity. In particular, we focus on how different contracts can coordinate by yielding the system-optimal capac

Parimutuel betting under asymmetric information
May 24, 2006 - and a prior probability distribution over states that is common for all bettors. .... any bettor bets against his private signal, regardless of the content of the ..... the first bet means that it is never profitable for the second bet

Auxiliary Power Unit.pdf
Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. Auxiliary Power Unit.pdf. Auxiliary Power Unit.pdf. Open. Extract.

Subject-Auxiliary Inversion
Jun 26, 2013 - The treatment of English auxiliary verbs epitomizes the stark contrast between the original generative view of syntax as an autonomous formal ...

auxiliary verb examples pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect ...

Weak and strong reflexives in Dutch - CiteSeerX
by stipulating two overlapping binding domains. I want to argue, however, that syntactic approaches are on the wrong track, and that semantic and pragmatic ...

HAMILTONIAN PDE'S AND WEAK TURBULENCE ...
The mathematical tools are basic ones, essentially Fourier series and ODE's. References. [1] Bourgain, J. ... E-mail address: [email protected]. 1.

HAMILTONIAN PDE'S AND WEAK TURBULENCE ...
The mathematical tools are basic ones, essentially Fourier series and ODE's. FDP/MAPMO-UMR 7349, ... E-mail address: [email protected]. 1.

Weak Negations and Neighborhood Semantics
chaining these equalities together gets us what we want. Corollary 3.7. If a consecution A ⊣ B is invalid in a logic L, then any neigh- borhood model canonical for ...

Split Intransitivity and Variable Auxiliary Selection in ...
Mar 14, 2014 - Je suis revenu–j'ai revenu `a seize ans, j'ai revenu `a Ottawa. ... J'ai sorti de la maison. 6 ..... 9http://www.danielezrajohnson.com/rbrul.html.

Topology and Control Innovation for Auxiliary ... - Research at Google
provide a constant current (CC) driving current preferably for the best light output ... As the Internet of Things (IoT) continues to proliferate, connected and smart .... communicate (via wireless network) and interact with the environment (via ...