Corporate governance and the informativeness of risk disclosure: evidence from MENA emerging markets

Abstract: Our paper examines whether corporate governance characteristics influence firms’ decision to disclose informative risk information voluntarily. Our sample includes 320 listed firms in nine MENA emerging markets corresponding to more than 780 observations over a three year period, 2007 to 2009. Our study offers several significant contributions to the growing risk disclosure literature. It provides the first empirical evidence that information driven by some corporate governance mechanisms is likely to shape the perceived relevance of narrative risk information. Our findings suggest that board composition and board size enhance the informativeness of risk disclosure in that it helps investors impound more information about future earnings changes into stock prices. In contrast concentrated ownership, managerial ownership and institutional ownership seem to weaken investors’ reliance on this information. Such impact is not detected in the presence of CEO/Chairperson role duality.

Keywords: risk disclosure; earnings informativeness; corporate governance; future earnings; MENA emerging markets

JEL Classification: G14, G15, G32

1

1. Introduction A significant body of research suggests that effective governance structure significantly influences disclosure quality and leads to greater corporate transparency (Dechow et al., 1996; Beasley, 1996; Shleifer and Vishny, 1997; Klein, 2002 and Beekes and Brown, 2006). The link between governance mechanisms and the quality of accounting information is based on the view that corporate governance influences the reliability of firm disclosure through its influence over management activities, their opportunistic behavior and the integrity of the financial reporting process (Watts and Zimmerman, 1986). Actually, the separation of ownership and control leads to agency conflicts between corporate managers and shareholders (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Insiders and controlling shareholders -better informed about corporate opportunities and uncertainties- have greater incentives to expropriate wealth from minority investors and to withhold private information from outsiders (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997). Such an opportunistic behavior should be reduced when corporate governance becomes more effective. Strong governance mechanisms should alleviate the moral hazard (hidden action) and the adverse selection (hidden information) problems resulting from a severe information gap between managers, shareholders and potential investors (Bushman et al., 2004). Accordingly, a rich information environment is at the heart of better structured governance mechanisms. This information might be useful for investors seeking to reduce information uncertainty by enabling them to anticipate corporate prospects. It should also build a trustworthy relationship between a company and the business community (e.g. Financial analysts, creditors…), helps investors in making informed investment decisions and improves the market liquidity by reducing the cost of capital. Nevertheless, in the absence of strong monitoring mechanisms on managerial behavior, managers could mislead outsiders by providing accounting information which does not portray the true underlying risk and rewards of the business. Accordingly, the ‘informativeness’ of corporate disclosure and their ultimate effect on share prices may differ considerably depending on the firm level governance and on the ways the information is prepared, conveyed and used (Hossain and Reaz, 2007). Recent trends in the accounting literature examined how corporate governance characteristics influence firm's propensity to reveal sensitive information such as risk reporting in a regulated environment (Solomon et al. 2000; Taylor et al. 2008). Studies like Zhang et al. (2013), Abraham and Cox (2007) and Bushee and Noe (2000) provide evidence that ownership structure is an important monitoring mechanism. Institutional investors, as pressure groups, encourage managers to provide a high amount of risk information. However, the existence of a dominant group of shareholders gives rise to possible collusion between dominant owners and managers that reduces the incentives and ability of concentrated owners to monitor managerial actions (Ho and Wong, 2001; Chen and Jaggi, 2000). While this possibility can lead to lower corporate disclosures, a good board composition can outweigh their entrenchment incentives (Abraham and Cox, 2007). Such evidence remains, though, limited on how corporate governance structure influences the extent of total risk disclosure. Little is known about how it might influence the investors’ perceived relevance of risk information. The most recent studies on the usefulness of risk disclosure suggest that investors tend to impound such information into their pricing decision in a manner that it either affects their perceived risk (e.g. Bao and Datta, 2014; Kravet and Muslu, 2013) or improves the market liquidity and reduces the information asymmetry (e.g. Miihkinen, 2013 and Campbell et al., 2014). Given these evidences on the usefulness of various risk factor disclosures for investors in assessing corporate risk, it is argued that the content of risk information shall satisfy an early-warning function and more specifically a forecasting function for outsiders (Dobler, 2008). This should result in a better assessment of the firm’s future performance. 2

Despite these recent compelling evidence, little attention has been paid to distinguish mandatory from voluntary risk disclosure in either observing how the strength of a firm’s governance influence the amount of risk disclosure or in how risk disclosure practice impact on market indicators (Elshandidy and Neri, 2015). It is theorized indeed that these two forms of disclosure have different incentives and distinct observed usefulness (Jorgensen and Kirschenheiter, 2012). As risk disclosure activity exhibits a piecemeal approach, it relies on voluntary risk reporting beyond specific mandatory disclosures and allows for managerial discretion. Managerial incentives and governance attributes are likely to play a major role in shaping the amount of risk disclosures and their informativeness (Dobler, 2008). Additionally and more importantly, no comprehensive empirical study to date has investigated how the monitoring function of corporate governance impacts the information content and the credibility of firms' risk disclosure, causing more/less risk information to be impounded into the share price. Accordingly, our paper is a way forward in seeking an empirical assessment of the interaction between governance characteristics and the informativeness of risk information conveyed in a voluntary basis. Our study fills this gap in the literature. The objective of our paper is to examine how corporate governance structure, including concentrated ownership structure, institutional ownership, managerial ownership, board size, board composition and duality of leadership (CEO/Chairman) interact with voluntary risk disclosure to influence investors’ ability to anticipate future earnings growth. We refer to voluntary risk information as any information about risk that appears in the narrative sections of annual reports other than those required by the international financial reporting standards (IFRS). We measure the extent of voluntary risk disclosure in the management discussion and analysis section by calculating the number of sentences providing risk information and using a manual based content analysis methodology. We define risk disclosure informativeness as the effect of voluntary risk information on the association between current stock returns and future earnings changes: informative risk disclosure should help investors impound more information about future earnings changes into stock prices. Our study contributes to the recent international accounting literature on risk disclosure using a longitudinal approach to assess the extent to which the perceived relevance of risk reporting is conditional on some corporate governance attributes and monitoring mechanisms. From an academic perspective, corporate governance is a considerably researched topic in the accounting literature (Cohen et al., 2004). However, the impact of corporate governance on the value-relevance of accounting information in general and risk disclosure in particular remains unexplored. Wang and Hussainey (2013), a closely related study, show that governance-driven voluntary disclosures of forward-looking statements enhance the share price informativeness with respect to future earnings. Yet several important questions remain unanswered. Specifically, we still have no knowledge of which firm-specific governance mechanisms matter for risk disclosure informativeness. Unlike Wang and Hussainey (2013), we believe that not all aspects of corporate governance and monitoring mechanisms may enhance informed trading by ensuring the production of informative risk disclosure. Additionally, considering a single country context (UK) does not confirm the robustness of the evidence not only across multiple developed markets but also among emerging markets. Yu (2011) argues that the impact of firm-specific governance on gathering and trading private information can vary with the degree of investor protection offered by country-level governance.

3

Elshandidy et al. (2014) suggest also that international differences in voluntary risk reporting practices depend on the country's legal system and its cultural values. From a contextual perspective, reviewing risk reporting studies highlights some gaps in the literature. First recent studies address risk reporting in developed countries with established risk reporting legislations and little is known about developing countries, such as MENA emerging economies, where risk reporting regulations are limited to the risk financial factor and thus provided on a voluntary basis. Additionally, despite their growing importance, stock markets in the MENA region have been widely ignored by international investors and academic research until the early 2000s (Bley, 2011). This is mainly due to imposed restrictions on foreign stock ownership, the lack of common accounting standards and limited corporate governance and transparency. As a consequence, and due to the difficulty of obtaining sufficient and reliable market data, researchers did not deeply focus on these regional financial markets. Unlike developed capital markets (e.g. NYSE, LSE, TSE), MENA emerging markets are also characterized by heterogeneous size, activity and the levels of informational efficiency, which are basically caused by market depth and corporate governance factors (Ben Othman and Zeghal, 2010; Lagoarde-Segot and Lucey, 2008). This paper contributes as such to the risk disclosure literature by highlighting the interaction between risk disclosure informativeness and some governance structure in 9 MENA emerging markets. We offer new empirical evidence inconsistent with the contention that accounting information is less relevant in the emerging markets because stock prices may fail to reflect all available information due to some market imperfections. We show that risk information associated with good board characteristics (large size and high proportion of non-executive directors) enhances the market's ability to anticipate future earnings growth. Conversely, ownership structure as analyzed through ownership concentration, managerial ownership and institutional investors decreases the association between risk disclosure and the investor's ability to anticipate future earnings growth. The CEO/chairman duality has no impact on the informativeness of risk disclosure. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 discusses the theoretical framework and surveys the related literature. Section 3 describes the research methodology used in the study. Descriptive statistics are described in Section 4. Section 5 presents the substantive test results and the robustness checks. Section 6 concludes, discusses limitations, and suggests avenues for future research 2. Background, literature review and hypotheses development 2.1. Background The corporate governance debate is relatively nascent in MENA countries. It is only in the last decade that an Arabic word for ‘corporate governance’, HAWKAMAH, emerged (Saidi, 2011). A good governance system and its enforcement have become key priorities of the regional authorities, particularly after the financial crash of 2006. The main weakness blamed to be responsible for the 2006 crash was capital market uncertainty and the inadequacy of information held by a plethora of investors in relation to their investments. There existed barriers to efficient information transmission through these markets and relatively limited corporate disclosure requirements. Investors were “ill-informed” and had often access to unreliable financial information (Harrison and Moore, 2012). Therefore, strengthening the corporate governance practices of listed companies was a rationale starting point. Enhancing the financial literacy of investors and improving the information flow to the investing public were at the heart of the corporate governance reform agenda. 4

Regulators devoted considerable efforts to increase the transparency, efficiency, depth, integration, and liquidity of MENA equity markets. (McNally, 2011). While the regulatory and the institutional frameworks for corporate governance in the MENA countries are already in place, it is not yet recognized as a public policy concern of increasing importance in the region. Actually, MENA security markets show relatively weak regulatory frameworks and limited role of market forces. Listed companies in these markets present four main characteristics: concentration of ownership (due to family/state active role as the owner of listed companies, either directly or through sovereign investment vehicles), family ownership and control (dominance-of control-oriented shareholders), bank-based corporate finance (banks are the most important source of external funds) and underdeveloped capital markets compared to the banking sector (foreign participation is limited) (Aloui and Rejichi, 2012). Recent surveys (OECD, 2014; 2012) highlight also that the MENA region lacks for best corporate governance practices compared to the OECD’s governance principles and to the implemented mechanisms in developed countries. Controlling shareholders is the dominant governance attribute in listed MENA corporations. Owners are in most cases engaged in corporate management, and even in firms run by external managers, insiders benefit from high decision-making positions. The conflicts of interest are then more pronounced between minority shareholders and controlling shareholders. The latter is able to abuse corporate resources by extracting private benefits to the detriment of other shareholders (Ben Othman and Zeghal, 2010). These aspects, among others1, are likely to have a negative impact not only on liquidity and trading, but also on corporate transparency and its reporting activity. When an owner effectively controls a firm, he/she also controls the production of the firm’s accounting information and reporting policies (BenNaceur and Laabidi, 2009). MENA companies are characterized additionally by a major role of the board of directors, the absence of call for a separation between the chair of the board and the chief executive officer (CEO), limited protection of the shareholders’ rights and the absence of board independence (Turki and Ben Sedrine, 2012). This specific institutional milieu suggests that disclosure policy is not as developed in MENA emerging markets as in the developed countries. There might be little chances for existing governance practices to increase the credibility of the accounting information. Corporate disclosure and in particular risk information might consequently fail in diminishing the information asymmetry between managers and market participants. More efforts are still needed to promote the “transparency, disclosure, protection of non-controlling shareholders, directors’ independence, qualifications, and compensation” in their stock markets (Ben Naceur and Laabidi, 2009; p. 4). Corporate governance mechanisms in MENA corporations should additionally ensure the alignment of the interests of controlling shareholders with those of minority shareholders (Ben Othman and zegha, 2010). 2.2. Relevant literature and research hypotheses Agency theory suggests that conflicts of interest arise between managers and outside shareholders due to the dissociation between ownership and control (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). In this regard, control mechanisms and corporate governance represent instruments to mitigate these conflicts. Both are likely to counter managerial power and to improve accountability (O’Sullivan, 2000). Useem (1996) presents ownership structure and in particular ownership concentration as a main control mechanism.

1

significant departure from the efficient market hypothesis, limited role of market forces..etc.

5

Shareholders with significant holdings, had become in the recent decades, agents of corporate control and critical to effective business leadership and corporate transparency. Corporate disclosure activity stems from the board of directors (Gul and Leung, 2004), and corporate annual reports are prepared by the board. Therefore, the governance structure of the board can be expected to influence disclosure policy. These two aspects -corporate ownership and board structure- bring forth expectations concerning relationships with the level and the value relevance of disclosure in the annual report (Abraham and Cox, 2007). To examine the impact of governance mechanisms on the informativeness of narrative risk disclosure in annual reports we focus on the following corporate control and board’s characteristics. 2.2.1. Risk disclosure practices and ownership structure The relationship between corporate disclosure and ownership structure is mainly scrutinized according to ownership diffusion/concentration and the presence of managerial/institutional ownership. 2.2.1.1 Ownership concentration

The growing body of risk disclosure literature invokes the agency theory to draw the ownership structure as a determinant of the extent of risk disclosure. For example Konishi and Ali (2007) and Mohobbot (2005) contend that in concentrated ownership structures, risk information will not be somehow disclosed via annual reports, but rather communicated in the board room meetings or privately shared with financial analysts. This is consistent with the contention that high ownership concentration probably decreases firms' willingness to provide risk disclosure to outside investors. As a result, there will be less material risk disclosure available to the public. Abdul Hamid and Nordin (2013) explain that in a concentrated ownership owners might not need additional disclosure, as they are more closely related to board members, as well as the management and hence couldn’t be bothered by the extent of any type of disclosure. Empirical risk disclosure literature provides inconclusive results. Bauwhede and Willekens (2008) and Kajüter (2006) find a negative association between ownership concentration and risk reporting, while Mohobbot (2005), Konishi and Ali (2007), Miihkinen (2012), Mokhtar and Mellett (2013) and Oliveira et al. (2011) find no relationship between the two variables. In a related vein, Fan and Wong (2002) and Donnelly and Lynch (2002) suggest that ownership concentration influences the level of information asymmetry between managers and outside investors, which in turn influences managers’ accounting choices and consequently the informativeness of accounting information. Empirically, the findings seem to be mitigated. For example, Firth et al. (2007) find that concentration of ownership is negatively associated with the informativeness of earnings in the eyes of the minority investors while Yeo et al. (2002) and Sarikhani and Ebrahimi (2011) show a positive relationship between the two variables and Sánchez-Ballesta and García-Meca (2007) reported an insignificant impact on earnings informativeness. Drawing from the agency theory, we formulate the following hypothesis: H1. The informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure with respect to future earnings in annual reports is significantly weaker for companies with concentrated ownership.

6

2.2.1.2. Managerial ownership

Managerial ownership refers to the proportion of shares owned by corporate managers. The agency theory considers managerial ownership as a possible solution for the conflicting interests between the principle (shareholders) and the agent (managers). Management holding is believed to reduce the agency costs associated with the separation of ownership and control. This should reduce the need to closely monitor the firms' managers as well as investors' information needs (Gelb, 2000). Jensen and Meckling (1976)’s interest alignment hypothesis suggests conversely, that outside shareholders may ask for increased monitoring and accountability as managerial ownership (i.e., ownership by executive directors) decreases. This monitoring constrains managers to reveal more information than what is required by law or regulation. Recent risk disclosure literature provides evidence consistent with Jensen and Meckling (1976). Marshall and Weetman (2007) assert that high levels of insider control, as measured by the percentage of closely held shares, are associated with low extent of risk disclosure. Brown et al. (2011) and Deumes and Knechel (2008) suggest also that firms with greater (lower) inside (outside) ownership are likely to be more (less) secretive and less (more) transparent. Their findings support their arguments in that they showed that managers of firms with high levels of insider control have less incentive to disclose more risk information. In addition, managerial ownership affects the value relevance of accounting information. Warfield et al. (1995) maintain that because accounting-based constraints are less prevalent for firms with great level of managerial ownership (and thus low agency costs), managerial manipulation of accounting numbers is less likely for such firms. Their findings indicate that the information content of accounting disclosures increases with the level of managerial ownership. The empirical evidence of Lichtenberg and Pushner (1992), Mehran (1995), Xu and Wang (1999) and Mitton (2002) indicate also a positive association between disclosure quality and management ownership consistent with the convergence of interest hypothesis. Agrawal and Mandelker (1990), Jensen and Murphy (1990), Slovin and Sushka (1993) and Loderer and Martin (1997), Gabrielsen et al. (2002) provide, in contrast, evidence of a negative association consistent with the ‘entrenchment’ hypotheses. Sarikhani and Ebrahimi (2011) find no significant relationship between the management ownership and earnings informativeness. Based on the interest alignment hypothesis, we state the following hypothesis: H.2: The informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure with respect to future earnings in annual reports is significantly weaker for companies with a high level of management ownership. 2.2.1.3. Institutional ownership

Institutional investors hold a large block of shares in the equities of large companies. “The primary types of institutional investors include public and private pension funds, mutual funds, insurance companies, investment funds and funds managed by banks or foundations” (Kochhar and David, 1996; p. 458). Unlike individual investors, institutional shareholders are more sophisticated and manage their investment professionally. Their participation in corporate ownership is believed to improve firm value due to more effective monitoring (Vishny and Shleifer, 1986). Chung and Zhang (2011) notice that institutional shareholders play an important role in improving corporate governance worldwide. Firms with large shareholders are more likely to be monitored than those with diffuse ownership. 7

With the significant resources and expertise they have, institutional owners have strong capabilities to monitor corporate managers and to prevent them from making non-value maximizing decisions or behaving opportunistically (Tihanyi et al., 2003; Velury and Jenkins, 2006). Within the risk disclosure literature, institutional ownership is expected to curb corporate managers from restraining risk information disclosure. Prior work of Chalmers and Godfrey (2004) and Taylor et al. (2008) argue that increased risk information may be a result of institutional owners’ pressure, which behaves as a substitute for effective corporate governance. Empirical studies did not, though support this agency perspective on the role of institutional holding. For example, Bushee and Noe (2000) and Solomon et al. (2000) find no relationship between the extent of long-term horizon institutional ownership and corporate risk disclosure in annual reports. These findings show that institutional investors hold a neutral view toward the need of risk disclosure. Abraham and Cox (2007) find that the relationship between institutional investors and risk reporting depends on the category of institutional owners. Results indicate that in-house managed pension funds are negatively related to risk disclosure supporting previous argument that long-term institutions can benefit from a mosaic of information from private channels (Guercio and Hawkins, 1999; Bushee and Noe, 2000). On the other side, institutional ownership by life assurance funds is positively related to risk disclosure, suggesting that short term institutions prefer firms that report more risk information because risk disclosure allows more accurate securities valuation and therefore frequent trading strategies. Recently Zhang et al. (2013) provide some conflicting evidence with Abraham and Cox’s (2007) findings. They report no relationship between long term institutional ownership and risk disclosure categories. Only a positive association is found between short term institutional owners and some risk categories, but not those that seem relevant for investors, namely future-oriented risk and negative risk performance disclosures. Institutional investors are also shown to have an impact on accounting information quality (Chung et al., 2002; Sarikhani and Ebrahimi, 2011). In particular, consistent with the active monitoring hypothesis, large institutional investors are better informed and firms are likely to engage in less opportunistic earnings management improving, hence, the informativeness of accounting earnings. The presence of institutional investors will also deter managers from performing strategic behavior towards earnings forecast information and constrains them to disclose relevant financial information (Ajinkya et al., 2005). Given shareholder activism and the monitoring potential of institutional shareholders, we formulate the following hypothesis: H.3: The informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure with respect to future earnings is stronger for firms with high institutional ownership. 2.2.2. Risk qisclosure practices and board structure The board of directors plays an important role in enforcing governance standards within publicly held companies. It is considered as “the most important internal control device seeking to control and monitor management in order to deter management from opportunistic behavior” (Rose, 2007, p. 404). Previous accounting literature suggests that several board characteristics may influence corporate disclosure.

8

2.2.2.1. Board size

Corporate governance literature contends that board size is an important market -based factor which ensures that all major stakeholders receive reliable information about firm value. It should also motivate managers to maximize firm value instead of pursuing personal objectives (Luo, 2005). On one hand, Bassett et al. (2007) assert that a small board lacks for sufficient expertise and may suffer from chief executive officer (CEO) dominance. This impairs the board's ability to meet corporate governance responsibilities and involves high agency costs. On the other hand, the agency theory and the resource dependence theory predict that large boards, enjoy wide expertise and more diversified knowledge which results in more effective board’s monitoring role (Luo, 2005; Linsley et al., 2006; Singh et al., 2004). Consequently, enhanced managerial monitoring associated with larger and experimented boards can have a positive influence on corporate disclosures, including risk information and performance (Bozec and Bozec, 2012). In this regard, Elzahar and Hussainey (2012) suggest that large boards with wide expertise and particularly those with financial and accounting background, are more motivated to screen their efforts in risk management and to signal this information to shareholders. The empirical evidence on the association between board size and risk disclosure is inconclusive. Some studies (Elzahar and Hussainey, 2012) find no relationship between board size and risk reporting while others find a positive association (Laksmana, 2008; Elshandidy et al, 2013; Mokhtar and Mellett, 2013; Ntim et al., 2013). This reflects the increase of board members' awareness regarding their duties to enhance corporate disclosure. Large board size is likely to increase the diversity of the members’ expertise and guarantees a high level of compliance with the accountability paradigm. As for the value relevance studies, results seem to be also inconclusive. For example, while Vafeas (2000) finds a negative relationship between the board size and earnings informativeness, Dimitropoulos and Asteriou (2010), Sarikhani and Ebrahimi (2011) and Firth et al. (2007) find no significant association between these two variables. Based on these arguments and congruent with the agency theory and the resource dependence theory we formulate the following hypothesis: H4. The association between voluntary risk disclosure and share price anticipation of future earnings is stronger for firms with a large board size. 2.2.2.2. Board composition

Board composition is also emphasized as an important corporate governance mechanism in the accounting literature. The Agency theory proposes that board composition may have an impact on corporate disclosure activity. Abraham and Cox (2007) argue that the board of directors includes a mix of inside and outside directors with variant tendencies toward information disclosure. On the one hand, inside directors are full time corporate employees and occupy an executive position within the firm. Because of the nature of their tasks, it may be difficult for the insiders-board members to monitor managers’ actions. They lack sufficient incentives regarding enhanced corporate disclosure because of their stewardship within the firm and their behavior which may be open to more scrutiny (Abraham and Cox, 2007; Leftwich et al., 1981). On the other hand, outside non-executive directors are expected to provide independent advices to executive directors.

9

They are believed to play a crucial role in monitoring managers’ performance and limiting their opportunism which may lead to reduced agency conflicts between managers and owners (e.g., Fama, 1980; Fama and Jensen, 1983; Walsh and Seward, 1990). Because they aim to signal their competence to other potential employers and to maintain their reputational capital, non-executive directors are expected to be more effective in fulfilling shareholder preferences for accountability and transparency. Therefore more disclosure is expected if they are actually carrying out their greater control and monitoring of managerial decisions. Their dominance would provide more power to force managers to disclose more private information (Haniffa and Cooke, 2002; Eng and Mak, 2003). Empirically, the association between board composition and disclosure is controversial. Some studies find a positive association between independent board of directors and the level or the quality of voluntary corporate disclosure (Boesso and Kumar, 2007; Chen and Jaggi, 2000; Donnelly and Mulcahy, 2008; Forker, 1992; Gul and Leung, 2004; Cheng and Courtenay, 2006; Khlif et al. 2014; Wang and Hussainey, 2013) while others end to an insignificant relationship between the two variables (Deumes and Knechel, 2008; Ho and Wong, 2001; Haniffa and Cooke, 2002; Vandemele et al., 2009). Focusing on risk reporting, Abraham and Cox’s (2007) reveal that different types of non-executive directors fulfil different functions regarding corporate disclosure policy. First, the coefficient on dependent non-executive directors is negative and insignificant, suggesting that despite the benefits (knowledge, specific expertise…) they may bring to the firm, grey directors do not promote risk disclosure. Second, findings show a significant positive relationship between the number of independent non-executive directors and the level of risk disclosure, suggesting that independent directors in great numbers are important in the transmission of risk information to investors. Barakat and Hussainey, (2013) and Elshandidy et al. (2013) find similar results with respect to the positive effect of the proportion of independent non-executive directors relative to board size on the voluntary release of risk information. Allini et al (2014) and Elzahar and Hussainey (2012) find, though insignificant association between the two variables. With respect to value relevance literature, Dimitropoulos and Asteriou (2010), Firth et al. (2007) and Petra (2007) observe that independent non-executive directors are positively associated with earnings quality. Sarikhani and Ebrahimi (2011) report in contrast, no significant association between outside participation on the board and the return earnings relationship. Based on the above arguments and consistent with the agency theory and the signaling theory, we postulate that: H5. The informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure with respect to future earnings is stronger for firms with high proportion of non-executive directors. 2.2.2.3. CEO/Chairman duality

Role duality occurs if the chief executive officer (CEO) holds the chairman position of the board at the same time resulting in a unitary leadership structure. According to the agency theory, concentration of decision-making power due to the unitary leadership structure can significantly reduce the monitoring function of the board. Fama and Jensen (1983) suggest that this combination of positions signals the absence of separation of decision management and decision control and may erode board independence. Barako et al. (2006) argue that this unitary leadership structure may facilitate opportunistic behavior by the CEO because of his dominance over the board. 10

Therefore, it is posited that for the board to be effective, it is important to separate the CEO and chairman positions. Forker (1992) suggests that duality may be detrimental to the quality of disclosure. Actually, the dominant personalities may resist some governance and control mechanisms such as audit committee and non-executive directors, which may place pressure on the board and impair their governance role regarding disclosure policies. Ho and Wong, (2001) believe that separating the CEO and the board chairman position deters managers from withholding unfavorable information. Ghazali and Weetman (2006) note likewise that separating CEO responsibilities and roles from those of the board chair should support transparency and adequate disclosure in financial reporting. Empirical studies provide mixed results. Some studies report a negative association between role duality and corporate voluntary disclosure (Forker, 1992; Haniffa and Cooke, 2002; Gul and Leung, 2004; Khlif et al., 2014; Wang and Husainey, 2013). Other studies find an insignificant association between CEO duality and voluntary disclosure (Cheng and Courtenay, 2006; Ho and Wong, 2001). Based on risk disclosure literature, Elzahar and Hussainey (2012), Mokhtar and Mellett (2013) and Vandemele et al., (2009) find a non-significant association between role duality and voluntary risk reporting which confirm that role duality is a potential threat to disclosure quality. Regarding the literature that examined the economic consequences for CEO/Chairman role duality Firth et al (2007), Petra (2007) and Sarikhani and Ebrahimi (2011) find that the duality of the chairman and CEO have no significant impact on discretionary accruals and the earnings response coefficients respectively. They show that the duality of the CEO and chairman roles cause no decrease in earnings informativeness. Based on the arguments above and consistent with the agency theory, we formulate our sixth hypothesis as follows: H6. The informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure with respect to future earnings is weaker for firms with CEO/Chairman duality. 3. Methodology 3.1. Sample selection and data collection This paper examines the extent to which the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure differs between strongly and weakly governed firms for a sample of firms listed in MENA emerging markets. The original sample covered twelve MENA countries; however, we use some filtering rules. Mainly, we drop Israel from our initial sample because in this country firms are dually listed and provide annual reports in conformity with the SEC requirements (10-K form). Bahrain and Qatar were also dropped because their capital markets include mostly financial and investment corporations and due to severe issues of data availability. Our final sample comprises companies from nine MENA emerging capital markets, including Egypt, Jordan, Kuwait, Morocco, Oman, Saudi Arabia, Tunisia, Turkey and UAE that are periodically listed from 2007 to 2012. The choice of this period of analysis is triggered by the steady growth in GDP per capita in the region during these recent years as well as the dynamism in their stock markets with a considerable increase in market capitalization and total value traded.

11

The firms included in our sample, had to satisfy the three conditions: First, it had to belong to a non-financial sector. Financial firms such as banks, insurance firms and investment firms were excluded because their reports are not comparable to those of non-financial firms. Second, this study focuses on annual reports and no other media of financial communications such as interim reports. Third, the non-financial firm, had to have at least one annual report, from 2007-2009. We chose 2009 as the end year for the study because the level of corporate risk disclosure is linked to share price anticipation of earnings and accounting and return data are required for at least three years ahead (Year 2012). The initial number of available annual reports varies from year to year. For example, the total number of firms in 2007 is 328. This number increases in 2008 to 335 firms. Then it is reduced to 327 firms in 2009. We matched the selected companies with the Thomson one database codes from which we gathered financial information such as stock prices, earnings per share and asset growth. Some firms have no Thomson one code. Thus, they have no accounting and return data. These firms were excluded from the selected sample. In the second stage we collected governance variables with respect to ownership structure and board characteristics from Thomson one database as well as corporate annual reports and we dropped other firms from our sample because of some missing information. Before we perform the regression analysis, outliers are censored to avoid any undue influence of extreme observations. Outliers are defined in the present study as the top and bottom 1% of observations for the distribution of any of the regression variables. After these series of sample-filtering steps the sample is reduced from 990 to 785 observations regarding the regression model that examines ownership structure hypotheses and 789 observations related to board characteristics hypotheses. The resulting panel includes 320 companies. The average number of annual reports per company is about 2.5. 3.2. Research design 3.2.1. Regression model specification To assess the effect of corporate governance on risk disclosure informativeness, we follow prior studies and, particularly, Kothari and Sloan (1992) and Collins et al. (1994). Based on the concept that earnings lack of timeliness in recognizing economic events compared to stock returns, these papers, add future earnings and some control variables into the regression of current returns on current earnings. This regression model is used as a benchmark in several recent studies (e.g. Banghoj and Plenborg, 2008; Gelb and Zarowin, 2002; Hussainey and Walker, 2009; Lundholm and Myers, 2002; Schleicher et al 2007) when examining the amount of information about future earnings impounded into stock prices. Collins et al (1994) applied the following specification: N

N

k 1

k 1

Rt  b0  b1 X t   bk 1 X t  k   bk  N 1 Rt  k  b2 N  2 EPt 1 b2 N 3 AGt Where: Rt: stock return for year t Rt+1, Rt+2, Rt+3: stock returns for year t+1, t+2, t+3 respectively. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2, Xt+3: are defined as the earnings change for year t, t+1, t+2, t+3 respectively. AGt: is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. EPt-1: is the period t-1’s earnings over price at the start of period t. 12

To test our hypotheses we interact all right-hand side variables in Collins et al (1994) regression model with risk disclosure (RD) variable and all corporate governance variables (Govi) each one a part so that we detect the simultaneous effect of these explanatory variables on the association between stock return and future earnings. This yields to the following regression model: Where: 3

3

Rt  b0  b1 X t   bk 1 X t  k   bk  4 Rt  k  b8 EPt 1 b9 AG t  b10 RDi, t  b11[ RDi, t * X t ]  k 1

k 1

3

3

k 1

k 1

 bk 11[ RDi, t * X t  k ]   bk 14 [ RDi, t * Rt  k ]  b18 [ RDi, t * EPt 1 ] b19 [ RDi, t * AG t ]  3

3

b20Govi  b21[Govi * X t ]   bk  21[Govi * X t  k ]   bk  24 [Govi * Rt  k ] b28 [Govi * EPt 1 ] k 1

k 1

3

 b29 [Govi * AG t ]  b30 [Govi * RDi, t * X t ]   bk  30 [Govi * RDi, t * X t  k ]  k 1

3

 bk  33 [Govi * RDi, t * Rt  k ] b37 [Govi * RDi, t * EPt 1 ]  b38 [Govi * RDi, t * AG t ]  et

k 1

      

Rt : stock return for year t is the buy-and-hold returns from six months before the financial year-end to six months after the financial year-end. Xt : earnings change per share deflated by the share price at the start of the return window for period t Xt+1, Xt+2, Xt+3: the earnings change per share for year t+1, t+2, t+3 respectively deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. Rt+1, Rt+2, Rt+3: stock return for year t+1, t+2, t+3 are calculated as buy-and-hold returns for the 12-months period AGt: The growth rate of total book value of assets for period t EPt-1: is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. RD: Risk disclosure variable defined as the natural logarithm of the number of riskrelated sentences, respectively, for Operation risk, Empowerment risk, Information processing and technology risk, Integrity risk and Strategic risk based on a manual content analysis. Following Linsley and Shrives (2006), a broad definition of risk is adopted to identify risk disclosures. We coded risk disclosures any sentence that informs the reader about “any opportunity or prospect, or of any hazard, danger, harm, threat or exposure, that has already impacted or may impact upon the company, as well as the management of any such opportunity, prospect, hazard, harm, threat, or exposure”. Similar to Linsley and Shrives (2006) and Elzahar and Hussainey (2012), we had to adhere to some decision rules. First, because the definition of risk is broad, disclosures had to be explicitly mentioned and not merely implied. Moreover, we coded risk disclosure sentence any disclosure that is repeated each time it is discussed. Any sentence with more than one possible classification was classified into the category most emphasized within the sentence. We then generated an aggregated score for risk disclosure for each firm by counting the number of risk-related sentences in corporate annual reports. We relied on the coding instrument used by Linsley and Shrives (2006). 13

Since our focus is on voluntary risk disclosure, we removed financial risk category from the initial coding grid. Most MENA emerging markets adopted the international financial reporting standards (IFRS) and are providing the mandatory information about their market risk (Currency, liquidity and credit risks). The disclosure index (appendix A) reflects five categories of voluntary risk information (mentioned above) whereby 32 items were identified. Since content analysis is inevitably subjective, the coding method has to be reliable and agreement procedures should be adopted to draw valid conclusions (Bowman, 1984). Reproducibility is arguably the most important interpretation of reliability in content analysis (Krippendorff, 2004). To ensure reproducibility, we used one single coder to perform content analysis. Then, to increase confidence that the interpretation of a written document corresponds to objective reality, we used in the next stage an experienced researcher familiar with the technique of content analysis to code, independently, a sub sample of 5 firms. The sub samples were selected randomly from the yearly pool of observations from 2007 to 2009 for a total of 15 observations. Before we began the study, we discussed risk disclosure and research objective with the coder to familiarize him with relevant literature. Additionally, we provided the coder with a set of rules to replicate the pretest coding and in the process, we clarified and refined the rules as needed. As the coder and the researcher independently coded the initial sample, we used tests of inter rater reliability to check for consistency in coding, a proxy for accuracy. Consistent with Hayes and Krippendorff (2007) and Krippendorff (2010), we relied on Krippendorff’s alpha test, which is considered to be the most appropriate test of inter rater reliability. The test generated a Kalpha of 0.889, a satisfactory level of inter-rater reliability for this intra-class agreement coefficient. It is customary to require Kalpha= 0.80 as the cut off point for a good reliability test, with a minimum of 0.67 (Krippendorff, 2004). 

Govi: corporate governance vector including: - Ownership concentration variable (OwCi,t): The proportion of equity held by the top-five largest shareholders, including financial institutions, firms’ inside shareholders (directors and executives) and other outside block shareholders consistent with previous studies such as Jiang et al (2011); Hossain et al (2006); Lakhal, (2006) and Makhija and Patton, (2004). -

Managerial ownership variable (MOwi,t): The proportion of equity held by managers and executive directors consistent with extent studies such as Gul et al (2002) and Hossain et al (2006).

-

Institutional ownership variable (InOwi,t): The total number of shares held by institutions to the total number of shares outstanding per sample firm, consistent with Abraham and Cox (2007); Barako (2007); Elzahar and Hussainey (2012) and Zhang et al. (2013).

-

Board size variable (BS): the number of directors sitting on the board at the end of each year. This measure is consistent with Abdel-Fattah et al. (2008); Elzahar and Hussainey (2012); Hussainey and Al-Najjar, (2011); Lakhal (2005) and Singh et al. (2004).

-

Board composition (NED): The proportion of non-executive directors relative to the Board size consistent with Abraham and Cox (2007); Elshandidy et al (2013); Elzahar and Hussainey (2012) and Vandemele et al (2009). 14



The CEO/Chairman role duality (Dual): a dummy variable that we defined as 1 if CEO is the Chairman and 0 otherwise.

Controlling variables -

Financial leverage: Consistent with Banghoj and Plenborg (2008), Elshandidy et al (2013) leverage is the book value of equity scaled by total liabilities.

-

Firm size: Firm size is the natural logarithm of corporate net sales (turnover) congruent with Abraham and Cox (2007) and Linsley and Shrives (2006).

-

Profitability: Firm profitability is the natural logarithm of the return on equity (ROE) which is defined as the [Net profit after tax/Shareholders funds] *100% in accordance with Elshandidy et al (2013) and Elzahar and Hussainey (2012).

-

Industry sector: Industry sector is a dummy variable defined as 1 if the firm is classified into one of the nine broadly defined industry sectors and 0 otherwise.

4. Descriptive statistics We provide in Table 1 summary statistics for our samples with observations coming from the year 2007 to 2009. The mean current return ranges between 2.9 and 3 percent. The mean current earnings per share change varies between 0.5 and 0.9 percent of the price. The aggregated mean of future earnings change is respectively 0.23 and 0.5 percent of the price for the three periods ahead t+1, t+2 and t+3. These statistics suggest a decline in future performance in t+1, t+2 and t+3 compared to the performance of the current period. We find also a lower mean future return with respect to t+1 periods compared to current return. There is a reverse and an increase in the mean stock returns for period t+2 and t+3 (compared to t+1) which indicate changes in corporate performance over the sample time period. As additionally reported in table 1, the mean of corporate asset growth rate extends from 12.2 to 12.7 percent and the standard deviation is about 0.17 suggesting that there is little variation in the asset growth rate among our sample firms. The level of risk disclosure is on average 27 sentences and the standard deviation is on average 21.3 reflecting a fairly low disclosure score over our period of analysis as well as considerable dispersion among our sample firms. As for governance variables, first ownership concentration ranges from 12.14 percent to 94.98 percent with a mean (median) of 61.8 (65) percent and a standard deviation about 19.38. We argue that corporate ownership is highly concentrated for our sample of Middle Eastern and North African firms though the considerable variation among them. Second, managerial ownership ranges from 13.37 percent to 79.93 percent. It has a mean of 13.37 percent and a standard deviation about 19.97. This shows that managers do not hold large stakes in corporate ownership, despite the large spread among the observations. Similarly, we notice that the extent of institutional owners is low with a mean of 13.29 and a considerable dispersion of 15.44.

15

Table.1 Panel A. Summary descriptive statistics for continuous variables (longitudinal data)

Var. Mean. S.D Min. 0.029 0.457 -0.597 Rt 0.005 0.045 -0.075 Xt 0.001 0.040 -0.073 Xt+1 0.004 0.042 -0.069 Xt+2 0.002 0.034 -0.064 Xt+3 0.008 0.449 -0.605 Rt+1 0.100 0.363 -0.363 Rt+2 0.044 0.284 -0.346 Rt+3 0.127 0.178 -0.089 AGt 0.888 1.346 -0.01 Ept-1 27.483 21.307 1 RD 61.808 19.386 12.14 OwC 13.373 19.979 0 MOw 13.299 15.449 0 InOw 50.950 74.577 -0.078 Lev 0.83 Size (M$) 662.338 1949.595 26.606 152.193 0.05 Profit

25% -0.340 -0.015 -0.018 -0.016 -0.010 -0.339 -0.174 -0.185 -0.009 0.03 13 50.04 0 0.56 2.949 22.43 7.33

Median -0.044 0.002 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.067 0.028 -0.004 0.0833 0.17 22 65 3.309 9 25.191 117.07 14.71

75% 0.316 0.025 0.021 0.023 0.019 0.284 0.303 .25 0.228 1.14 36 77.1 18.5 19.61 69.458 437.39 25.6

Max. 0.926 0.090 0.072 0.084 0.062 0.869 0.812 0.554 0.491 4.05 145 94.98 78.93 77.422 456.497 25101.77 92.90

Obs. 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785 785

Table 1 reports the summary statistics for the sample firms using data pooled across the three year sample period. The earnings per share measure is a Reuters’ fundamentals item, calculated by dividing ‘earnings for ordinary-full tax’ by the number of shares outstanding. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-and-hold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the total number of risk related sentences. Unlogged values are reported. In subsequent regressions the natural logarithm is used. OwC is the proportion of equity held by the top-five largest shareholders. MOw is the proportion of equity held by managers and executive director. InOw is the total number of shares held by institutions to the total number of shares outstanding per sample firm. Profit is measured by the Return on Equity (ROE). Likewise, unlogged values are reported and in subsequent regressions the natural logarithm is used.

With respect to board characteristics, Board size (BS) ranges from 2 members of directors to 23 members of directors with a mean of 8.20 and a standard deviation of 2.42. Board composition in non-executive (outside) directors ranges from 0 to 100 percent with an average of 68.10 percent. This refers to a relatively good level of independence for the board in listed MENA companies. The CEO/chairman role duality exists among 29.78 percent of our sample firms. 70.22 percent of observations opted for a separate position which is likely to foster board monitoring role.

16

Table.1 Panel B. Summary descriptive statistics for continuous variables (Pooled data)

Var. Mean. S.D 0.030 0.527 Rt 0.009 0.111 Xt 0.004 0.114 Xt+1 0.005 0.103 Xt+2 0.006 0. 086 Xt+3 0.062 0.609 Rt+1 0.154 0.565 Rt+2 0.084 0.474 Rt+3 0. 122 0.173 AGt 0.90 1.374 Ept-1 27.343 21.255 RD 8.209 2.426 BS 68.108 23.643 NED 52.412 76.679 Lev Size (M$) 658.017 1936.599 26.792 151.942 Profit

Min. -0.921 -0.310 -0.521 -0.441 -0.401 -0.943 -0.860 -0.816 -0.090 -0.01 1 2 0 -0.078 5.48 0.05

25% -0.342 -0.016 -0.018 -0.016 -0.010 -0.329 -0.171 -0.181 -0.014 0.04 13 7 50 3.753 21.75 7.25

Median -0.047 0.002 0.000 0.000 0 -0.061 0.024 0 0.081 0.19 22 8 70 25.673 117.015 14.44

75% 0.312 0.025 0.021 0.022 0.018 0.299 0.304 0.252 0.223 1.08 35 9 87.5 70.857 422.37 25.59

Max. 1.815 0.659 0.566 0.507 0.426 0.878 0.851 0.558 0.470 4.17 145 23 100 456.497 25101.77 98.729

Obs. 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789 789

Table 1 reports the summary statistics for the sample firms using data pooled across the three year sample period. The earnings per share measure is a Reuters’ fundamentals item, calculated by dividing ‘earnings for ordinary-full tax’ by the number of shares outstanding. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-and-hold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the total number of risk related sentences. Unlogged values are reported. In subsequent regressions the natural logarithm is used. BS is the number of directors sitting on the board at the end of each year. NED is the proportion of non-executive directors relative to the Board size. Financial leverage Lev is defined as book value of equity scaled by total liabilities. Size is measured by corporate revenues. Profit is measured by the Return on Equity (ROE). Likewise, unlogged values are reported and in subsequent regressions the natural logarithm is used.

Table.1 Panel C. Summary descriptive statistics for dummy variable (longitudinal data)

DUAL 0 1

Frequency

Percent

Cum.

Obs

554 235

70.22 29.78

70.22 100.00

789 789

Dual is defined as 1 if CEO is the Chairman and 0 otherwise.

Table 2 presents pairwise Pearson correlations for all regression variables. P values are given in parentheses. Correlations are estimated using longitudinal and pooled data across the threeyear sample period. The correlation between current Returns (Rt) and current earnings growth (Xt) is strong and significant at the 1% level suggesting that current earnings are perceived as value relevant. The correlation between Rt and Xt+1 is weaker, but still significant at the 1 % level. The correlations between current returns Rt and future earnings change for t+2 and t+3 (Xt+2 and Xt+3) are not significant. These results may provide evidence of prices leading earnings by only one period. Current return is also correlated with future returns of period t+1 while Rt is uncorrelated with Rt+2 and Rt+3. Future returns (Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3) are significantly correlated with future earnings growth (Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3), consistent with Collins et al. (1994). These correlations indicate that future returns should not influence the results except through their role as a proxy for the measurement error in future earnings. 17

We noticed significant and negative correlation between current earnings (Xt) and future earnings growth for 3 periods of analysis. Similarly, Xt+1 is significantly and negatively related to Xt+2 and Xt+3. This may suggest potential multi-collinearity problems within the independent variables. The variable inflation factor (VIF) did not raise a serious colinearity problem significant problems among the explanatory variables. The mean VIF is about 1.12 and the computed VIF for each predictor variable is largely under 5. AGt and Ept-1 seem to be also good error measurement proxies. The theory indicates that an errors-invariables proxy should be highly correlated with the measurement error but uncorrelated with the dependent variable. This is the case for these two control variables. As reported in table 2, the correlation coefficients between Rt in one hand and AGt as well as Ept-1 in the other hand are insignificant. Risk disclosure level is positively and significantly associated with current stock returns at the level of 10%. This may suggest that corporate risk disclosure activity in MENA emerging markets is induced by stock price performance. Lundholm and Myers (2002) and Banghoj and Plenborg (2008) find in the same way a positive and significant correlation between current returns and the disclosure score. As for ownership structure, institutional ownership (InOw) is negatively correlated with future returns of t+2 and t+3 periods at the level of 10%, suggesting that institutional demand exercises a pressure on stock prices which is likely to reduce future stock returns. Pairwise testing reveals that Institutional ownership is positively correlated with ownership concentration and negatively related to managerial ownership at 1% level. These correlations suggest that firms with high level of institutional owners have concentrated ownership but less management ownership. Table 2 panel A reports a positive association between managerial ownership (MOw) and future returns (Rt+2) at the 5% level consistent with the view that management ownership positively impact firm value. Ownership concentration is positively associated with the level of risk disclosure indicating that large shareholders ‘pressure is likely to improve corporate reporting practice.

18

Table.2 Panel A: Pearson correlations: shareholding structure (longitudinal Data) Rt

Xt

Xt+1

Xt+2

Xt+3

Rt+1

Rt+2

Rt+ 3

EPt–1

AGt

RD

InsOw

MOw

Rt Xt

1.000 0.156*** (0.000)

1.000

Xt+1

0.108*** (0.002)

-0.203*** (0.000)

1.000

Xt+2

-0.023 (0.505)

-0.044 (0.210)

-0.146*** (0.000)

1.000

Xt+3

0.020 (0.569)

-0.035 (0.327)

-0.075** (0.034)

-0.138*** (0.000)

1.000

Rt+1

-0.254*** (0.000)

-0.025 (0.472)

0.137*** (0.000)

0.157*** (0.000)

-0.060* (0.093)

1.000

Rt+2

-0.004 (0.904)

0.026 (0.466)

0.017 (0.628)

0.106*** (0.002)

0.118*** (0.000)

-0.171*** (0.000)

1.000

Rt+3

0.055 (0.119)

0.040 (0.253)

-0.007 (0.835)

0.104*** (0.003)

0.065* (0.066)

0.039 (0.265)

0.046 (0.192)

1.000

EPt–1

-0.024 (0.489)

-0.079** (0.025)

-0.030 (0.389)

-0.063* (0.075)

-0.039 (0.266)

0.015 (0.662)

0.004 (0.906)

-0.061* (0.087)

1.000

AGt

0.042 (0.233)

0.077** (0.030)

-0.021 (0.543)

-0.009 (0.784)

0.026 (0.464)

-0.051 (0.150)

0.112*** (0.001)

-0.091** (0.010)

0.077** (0.029)

1.000

RD

0.067* (0.057)

-0.019 (0.587)

0.005 (0.886)

0.031 (0.373)

-0.018 (0.608)

0.072** (0.043)

-0.054 (0.126)

-0.001 (0.957)

0.164*** (0.000)

0.014 (0.689)

1.000

InsOw

-0.005 (0.869)

-0.000 (0.988)

0.008 (0.821)

0.025 (0.472)

-0.033 (0.355)

0.004 (0.896)

-0.0590* (0.098)

-0.064* (0.069)

-0.008 (0.809)

-0.052 (0.138)

0.025 (0.481)

1.000

MOw

-0.023 (0.515)

-0.000 (0.981)

0.052 (0.142)

-0.034 (0.336)

-0.016 (0.642)

0.053 (0.133)

0.088** (0.012)

0.024 (0.489)

0.038 (0.283)

0.056 (0.115)

-0.048 (0.175)

-0.122*** (0.000)

1.000

OwC

0.038 (0.284)

0.047 (0.188)

0.005 (0.873)

0.050 (0.157)

0.011 (0.755)

0.136*** (0.000)

0.024 (0.501)

0.015 (0.670)

0.121*** (0.000)

0.052 (0.142)

0.097*** (0.006)

0.148*** (0.000)

0.046 (0.193)

OwC

1.000

Table 2 presents Pearson Correlations for all regression variables using panel data across the three year sample period. P-values are given in parentheses. The number of observations is 785. The earnings per share measure is a Reuters’ fundamental item, calculated by dividing ‘earnings for ordinary-full tax’ by the number of shares outstanding. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-and-hold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. OwC is the proportion of equity held by the top-five largest shareholders. MOw is the proportion of equity held by managers and executive director. InsOw is the total number of shares held by institutions to the total number of shares outstanding per sample firm.

19

With respect to board characteristics, pairwise testing in table 2 panel B showed that board size (BS) is significantly and positively related to the earnings of period t-1. In contrast, there is negative correlation between BS and current and future earnings growth for t+2’s period at the levels of 5%. These univariate results may indicate that the larger is corporate board size the smaller is firms’ current and future earnings changes. Board size seems to be likewise significantly and negatively associated with the amount of non-executive directors sitting on the board. This shows that large sized board in our sample includes a low amount of nonexecutive directors. Non-executive directors are significantly and positively associated with the future returns for t+2’s period, though it is negatively correlated with future earnings growth for the same period. This suggests that firms with high proportion of independent members on board have higher future returns despite the lower earnings growth for t+2. In contrast, firms with high number of independent directors have more important future earnings change for t+3. As for the CEO/Chairman role duality, it is negatively correlated with future returns (Rt+1, Rt+3) and the proportion of NED showing that firms with role duality exhibit lower stock performance and involve less proportion of outside directors.

20

Table.2 Panel B: Pearson correlations: board characteristics (Pooled Data) Rt Xt

Rt 1.000 0.134*** (0.000)

Xt

Xt+1

Xt+2

Xt+3

Rt+1

Rt+2

Rt+ 3

-0.287*** (0.000) 0.017 (0.632)

1.000 -0.203*** (0.000)

1.000

Xt+3

-0.018 (0.603)

-0.105*** (0.003)

-0.058* (0.098)

-0.219*** (0.000)

1.000

Rt+1

-0.223*** (0.000) 0.010 (0.776)

-0.019 (0.586)

0.111*** (0.001)

-0.099*** (0.005) 0.056 (0.114)

1.000

0.071** (0.045)

0.195*** (0.000) -0.014 (0.687)

-0.150*** (0.000)

1.000

Rt+3

0.014 (0.682)

0.036 (0.305)

-0.026 (0.461)

-0.019 (0.576)

0.032 (0.368)

0.037 (0.289)

1.000

EPt–1

-0.017 (0.618)

-0.036 (0.306)

-0.012 (0.730)

0.141*** (0.000) -0.036 (0.300)

-0.021 (0.548)

-0.038 (0.279)

-0.052 (0.138)

AGt

-0.036 (0.312) 0.064* (0.071) -0.030 (0.385) 0.041 (0.241) 0.015 (0.672)

0.007 (0.839) -0.003 (0.922) -0.086** (0.015) 0.026 (0.465) -0.031 (0.372)

0.006 (0.866) -0.005 (0.869) -0.051 (0.151) 0.028 (0.433) 0.025 (0.476)

0.041 (0.247) 0.021 (0.543) -0.071** (0.044) -0.069* (0.051) 0.007 (0.837)

-0.007 (0.833) 0.003 (0.920) -0.023 (0.519) 0.102*** (0.003) -0.033 (0.346)

-0.000 (0.979) 0.078** (0.028) -0.082* (0.020) 0.056 (0.111) -0.074** (0.037)

0.061* (0.086) -0.083** (0.018) -0.098*** (0.005) 0.061* (0.083) -0.045 (0.203)

-0.085** (0.016) -0.012 (0.731) 0.003 (0.931) -0.019 (0.585) 0.026 (0.449) -0.070** (0.047)

Xt+2

Rt+2

RD BS NED Dual

AGt

RD

BS

NED

Dual

1.000

0.097*** (0.006) 0.008 (0.820)

Xt+1

EPt–1

0.083** (0.019)

1.000 -0.013 (0709) 0.144*** (0.000) 0.182*** (0.000) -0.122*** (0.000) 0.187*** (0.000)

1.000 -0.024 (0.488) -0.047 (0.178) -0.024 (0.498) -0.010 (0.765)

1.000 0.050 (0.156) -0.010 (0.762) -0.009 (0.794)

1.000 -0.136*** (0.000) 0.014 (0.680)

1.000 -0.274*** (0.000)

1.000

Table 2 presents Pearson Correlations for all regression variables using panel data across the three year sample period. P-values are given in parentheses. The number of observations is 789. The earnings per share measure is a Reuters’ fundamental item, calculated by dividing ‘earnings for ordinary-full tax’ by the number of shares outstanding. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-and-hold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. BS is the number of directors sitting on the board at the end of each year. NED is the proportion of non-executive directors relative to the Board size. Dual is defined as 1 if CEO is the Chairman and 0 otherwise.

21

5. Empirical results and the robustness checks 5.1. Ownership structure and risk disclosure informativeness We focus mainly on three corporate ownership characteristics. We hypothesize that concentrated ownership, managerial ownership and institutional ownership are likely to shape (increase/decrease) the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure. We provide our regression estimates based on a panel analysis2 5.1.1. Concentrated ownership and the informativeness of risk disclosure Table 3 reports the main findings of H1 testing that predicts a weaker value relevance of voluntary risk disclosure when interacted with the ownership concentration level. The informativeness of risk disclosure with respect future earnings is given by the coefficient on RD ∗ ∑3K=1 Xt+K . The coefficients on RD*Xt+2 are positive and significant at the level of 1% and 10% when controlling for corporate risk and profitability respectively. Since RD*Xt+i and RD*Rt+i together proxy for the revealed future earnings, and because the individual years of future earnings are highly correlated, a more powerful test examines the joint significance of RD*Xt+2 and RD*Rt+2 for the regression that controls for corporate size. The partial F-test of the joint significance of these variables have p-values of 0.0125 which confirms the anticipated idea that risk disclosures published in the annual report reveal information about future earnings for two years ahead. There is, accordingly, evidence on risk disclosure informativeness with respect to future earnings change. The incremental impact of ownership concentration on the informativeness of risk disclosure is given by the coefficients on OwC*RD*∑𝟑𝑲=𝟏 Xt+K. The coefficients on the interaction terms OwC *RD*Xt+1 and OwC *RD*Xt+2 are negative and significantly different from zero at the levels of 1% and 5% in all cases. The joint significance test of OwC*RD*Xt+2 and OwC*RD*Rt+2 returns a value of 10.89 with a p-value of 0.000 in the regression model that controls for corporate size. These findings indicate that a high level of ownership concentration moderates the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure as predicted in H1. They show that the amount of voluntary risk information impounded into the current stock price is lower for firms with less diffused ownership because investors perceive it as less relevant. Increased ownership concentration is likely to intensify agency problems and worsen the credibility of firms’ information environments. Investors prefer to rely on other sources of information such as block owners trading to anticipate future earnings growth. These results give support to our first hypothesis and are consistent with Yu (2011) and Piotroski and Roulstone (2004) who showed that a high ownership concentration enhances the relative amount of firm-specific information in stock prices. As substantial shareholders, they do have superior access to private information and consequently, their trading can convey a timely and accurate firmspecific information into stock prices. 2

Before we run the multiple regressions based on Panel data, we perform several specification tests in order to insure that the regression specification fits the data. We address five main concerns: the question of whether to pool the data or not, the tests for individual and time effects, the normality, the heteroskedasticity and the serial correlation of error terms.

22

In contrast, our results are not in line with Hossain et al. (2006) and Mak and Li (2001) who indicate that outside block ownership has a significant and positive effect on voluntary disclosure informativeness. Table 3. The effect of ownership concentration on the informativeness voluntary risk disclosure

Model Intercept Xt Xt+1 Xt+2 Xt+3 Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 AGt Ept-1 RD RD*Xt RD*Xt+1 RD*Xt+2 RD*Xt+3 RD*Rt+1 RD*Rt+2 RD*Rt+3 RD*AGt RD*Ept-1 OwC OwC *Xt OwC *Xt+1 OwC *Xt+2 OwC *Xt+3 OwC *Rt+1 OwC *Rt+2 OwC *Rt+3 OwC *AGt OwC *Ept-1 OwC *RD*Xt OwC *RD*Xt+1 OwC *RD*Xt+2 OwC *RD*Xt+3 OwC *RD*Rt+1 OwC *RD*Rt+2 OwC *RD*Rt+3 OwC *RD*AGt OwC *RD*EPt-1 Year Dummies Adj R2 Observations

Exp. Sign (?) (+) (+) (+) (+) (–) (–) (–) (–) (+) (?) (?) (+) (+) (+) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (–) (–) (–) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

Financial Leverage 0.143 (0.639) -8.065* (0.075) -6.625 (0.142) -4.427 (0.366) 4.717 (0.357) -1.742*** (0.000) -0.511 (0.378) -0.212 (0.726) 0.287 (0.792) -0.200 (0.224) 0.064 (0.106) 0.203 (0.156) 0.182 (0.198) 0.365*** (0.008) 0.100 (0.528) 0.080 (0.145) 0.076 (0.302) 0.034 (0.344) 0.014*** (0.001) 0.001 (0.417) -0.002 (0.973) 2.109* (0.053) 2.348** (0.032) 1.281 (0.276) -0.832 (0.511) 0.269** (0.014) 0.010 (0.941) -0.041 (0.778) -0.052 (0.844) 0.038 (0.290) -0.020 (0.313) -0.062*** (0.001) -0.054*** (0.002) -0.011 (0.421) -0.018** (0.033) -0.023* (0.061) -0.000 (0.905) -0.000** (0.012) -0.000** (0.018) Yes 39.33% 785

Firm Size 0.052 (0.866) -4.948 (0.272) -3.489 (0.473) -3.008 (0.543) 2.693 (0.594) -2.137 (0.000) -0.898 (0.097) 0.462 (0.478) 0.232 (0.830) -0.107 (0.503) 0.070* (0.061) 0.094 (0.471) 0.075 (0.618) 0.183 (0.131) 0.057 (0.718) 0.081 (0.165) 0.159 (0.017) 0.003 (0.968) 0.013*** (0.004) 0.000 (0.997) 0.016 (0.811) 1.450 (0.180) 1.650 (0.162) 0.964 (0.411) -0.364 (0.769) 0.365*** (0.001) 0.087 (0.496) -0.196 (0.200) -0.033 (0.900) 0.022 (0.511) -0.007 (0.669) -0.039** (0.037) -0.013 (0.411) -0.009 (0.556) -0.023** (0.018) -0.043*** (0.000) 0.006 (0.675) -0.000 (0.107) -0.000 (0.315) Yes 42.73% 785

Profitability 0.225 (0.443) -4.523 (0.288) -5.572 (0.192) -4.292 (0.344) 6.623 (0.139) -1.787*** (0.000) -0.874* (0.094) -0.048 (0.929) -0.126 (0.907) -0.099 (0.520) 0.067* (0.072) 0.058 (0.653) -0.036 (0.777) 0.233* (0.100) 0.154 (0.307) 0.105** (0.031) 0.108 (0.114) 0.037 (0.295) 0.010** (0.015) 0.000 (0.602) 0.003 (0.959) 1.419 (0.170) 2.137** (0.041) 1.233 (0.251) -1.391 (0.215) 0.250*** (0.004) 0.120 (0.336) -0.063 (0.625) 0.053 (0.837) 0.014 (0.674) -0.017 (0.230) -0.047** (0.022) -0.035** (0.041) -0.036* (0.062) -0.032*** (0.000) -0.033*** (0.008) -0.002 (0.654) -0.000 (0.186) -0.000 (0.240) Yes 43.97% 785

Table 3 presents fixed effects regression results for panel data. Heteroscedasticity-consistent p-values are given in parentheses. The dependent variable is current period return, Rt. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-andhold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of

23

the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. OwC is the proportion of equity held by the top-five largest shareholders. Financial leverage, firm size and profitability are control variables (their regression estimates are not tabulated). The significance levels (twotail test) are: *= 10 %, ** =5 % and *** = 1 %.

5.1.2. Managerial ownership and the informativeness of risk disclosure Table 4 highlights the main findings of H2 testing that predicts a weaker risk disclosure informativeness when interacted with the level of management ownership. The coefficients on RD*Xt+2 are positive and significant at the levels of 5% and 10 % in the presence of financial leverage and firm size variables. These results suggest that risk disclosure convey relevant information about corporate prospects which are impounded into stock prices. The incremental impact of managerial ownership on risk disclosure informativeness is given by the coefficients on MOw*RD*∑𝟑𝑲=𝟏 Xt+K. The coefficient on the interaction term MOw*RD*Xt+1 are negative and significantly different from zero at the levels of 5% in all specifications. We notice also a negative and significant coefficient on the interaction term MOw*RD*Xt+3 at the level of 5% when we control for corporate profitability. Management ownership seems to weaken the informativeness of risk disclosure with respect future earnings for one year and three years ahead. Investors do believe that managers are most likely to withhold or manage firm risk information and divert private benefits from outside investors. They consider that owner-managers and directors make value, reducing decisions in order to safeguard their positions in the firm, therefore expropriating wealth from outsiders and decreasing the quality of information reported. Market participants react adversely by questioning the credibility of conveyed risk information and prefer to rely on other sources of information to predict future earnings growth other than those driven by an increased managerial ownership. These findings corroborate our second hypothesis (H2) and are consistent with Karamanou and Vafeas (2005), Hossain et al. (2006) and Yeo et al. (2002) who find a significant negative relationship between managerial ownership and the quality of financial disclosure practice using US and Singaporean data. Our results are also in line with those of Wang and Hussainey (2013) which indicate that inside owners are more likely to have advance access to forward-looking information, hence reducing the firm management’s incentive to disclose such information voluntarily in annual reports. Table 4. The effect of managerial ownership on the informativeness voluntary risk disclosure

Model Intercept Xt Xt+1 Xt+2 Xt+3 Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 AGt Ept-1 RD RD*Xt RD*Xt+1

Exp. Sign (?) (+) (+) (+) (+) (–) (–) (–) (–) (+) (?) (?) (+)

Financial Leverage 0.194 0.542 2.494*** 0.263 1.081 -0.743*** -0.400*** -0.375** 0.100 -0.074* 0.062 0.189* 0.041

(0.127) (0.558) (0.009) (0.779) (0.258) (0.000) (0.009) (0.026) (0.515) (0.090) (0.109) (0.061) (0.638)

Firm Size 0.180 0.857 2.868*** 0.309 1.070 -0.652*** -0.370** -0.347** 0.120 -0.056 0.073** 0.131 -0.002

Profitability (0.146) (0.330) (0.003) (0.734) (0.210) (0.000) (0.018) (0.033) (0.422) (0.239) (0.050) (0.154) (0.978)

0.276** 1.114 3.043*** 0.080 0.599 -0.760*** -0.322** -0.208 0.104 -0.072* 0.066* 0.021 -0.165

(0.026) (0.199) (0.001) (0.927) (0.449) (0.000) (0.022) (0.196) (0.484) (0.091) (0.075) (0.862) (0.125) 24

RD*Xt+2 RD*Xt+3 RD*Rt+1 RD*Rt+2 RD*Rt+3 RD*AGt RD*Ept-1 MOw MOw*Xt MOw*Xt+1 MOw *Xt+2 MOw*Xt+3 MOw *Rt+1 MOw *Rt+2 MOw *Rt+3 MOw *AGt MOw *Ept-1 MOw *RD*Xt MOw *RD*Xt+1 MOw *RD*Xt+2 MOw *RD*Xt+3 MOw *RD*Rt+1 MOw *RD*Rt+2 MOw *RD*Rt+3 MOw *RD*AGt MOw *RD*EPt-1 Year Dummies Adj R2 Observations Observations

(+) (+) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (–) (–) (–) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

0.255** 0.195 0.013 -0.037 0.015 0.011*** -0.000 -0.003** -0.007 0.019 0.008 -0.027 0.009* 0.001 0.002 0.000 0.001 -0.002 -0.005** -0.001 -0.002 -0.000 -0.000 0.000 -0.000 -0.000* Yes 24,19% 785 785

(0.035) (0.138) (0.680) (0.338) (0.659) (0.003) (0.822) (0.035) (0.811) (0.511) (0.782) (0.365) (0.080) (0.751) (0.723) (0.998) (0.105) (0.529) (0.014) (0.778) (0.246) (0.590) (0.905) (0.869) (0.490) (0.083)

0.215* 0.132 -0.023 -0.057 0.013 0.010*** -0.000 -0.003** -0.015 0.005 0.011 -0.025 0.005 0.001 0.001 -0.000 0.001* -0.001 -0.004** -0.001 -0.000 0.000 -0.000 0.000 -0.000 -0.000* Yes 24.66% 785 785

(0.080) (0.287) (0.474) (0.144) (0.707) (0.003) (0.681) (0.029) (0.631) (0.851) (0.667) (0.353) (0.284) (0.811) (0.804) (0.895) (0.057) (0.664) (0.022) (0.807) (0.807) (0.796) (0.986) (0.810) (0.379) (0.083)

0.186 0.204 -0.035 -0.036 -0.018 0.008** -0.000 -0.002 -0.012 0.003 0.024 -0.002 0.005 0.001 -0.003 -0.001 0.001 -0.001 -0.003** -0.001 -0.004** -0.000 -0.000 0.001 -0.000 -0.000 Yes 30.89% 785 785

(0.145) (0.137) (0.237) (0.342) (0.670) (0.041) (0.919) (0.151) (0.700) (0.907) (0.335) (0.928) (0.308) (0.829) (0.595) (0.771) (0.162) (0.613) (0.032) (0.620) (0.034) (0.893) (0.792) (0.376) (0.801) (0.394)

Table 4 presents fixed effect regression results for panel data. Heteroscedasticity-consistent p-values are given in parentheses. The dependent variable is current period return, Rt. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-andhold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. MOw is the proportion of equity held by managers and executive directors. Financial leverage, firm size and profitability are control variables (their regression estimates are not tabulated). The significance levels (two-tail test) are: *= 10 %, ** =5 % and *** = 1 %.

5.1.3. Institutional ownership and the informativeness of risk disclosure Table 5 reports main findings regarding the third hypothesis (H3) testing that predicts a stronger informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure for firms with high institutional ownership. Our results provide evidence of risk disclosure informativeness with respect to future earnings for two years ahead. The coefficients on the interaction term RD*Xt+2 are positive and significant in all the models at the levels of 1% and 5%. This suggests that corporate risk reporting convey value relevant information to market participants that are useful in anticipating future earnings growth.

25

The incremental impact of institutional ownership on risk disclosure informativeness is given by the coefficients on interacted variables InOw*RD*∑𝟑𝑲=𝟏 Xt+K. Findings in table 5 reject our third hypothesis in that it indicates that the informativeness of risk disclosure is a decreasing function of the level of institutional ownership. The coefficients on InOw*RD*Xt+1, InOw*RD*Xt+2 and InOw*RD*Xt+3 are negative and significantly different from zero at the levels of 1%, 5% and 10%. While the agency theory suggests that institutional shareholders fulfil a monitoring function, this does not appear to include pressuring firms to increase relevant risk disclosure. This weakened association occurs because investors believe that institutional owners are sophisticated and have advantages in acquiring and processing information. Such information is reflected in future earnings regardless of the extent of risk information conveyed to the market. This situation yields a less rich information environment and would impose lower informational synchronization as these investors' ownership increases. Consequently, market participants seem to question the informativeness of conveyed risk information driven by a high concentration of institutional ownership. Our findings are consistent with Abraham and Cox (2007) argument and evidence that these institutions can benefit from a mosaic of non-public non-material information and reveal a preference for firms with a lower than average level of risk reporting. Our results are in contrast inconsistent with Wang and Hussainey (2013) who reported an insignificant relationship between institutional investors and the level of voluntary disclosure regarding future earnings; They suggest that, as powerful investors, institutional owners might have other more efficient means of communicating with the firm’s management; for example, oneto-one meetings. Table 5. The effect of institutional ownership on the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure

Model Intercept Xt Xt+1 Xt+2 Xt+3 Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 AGt Ept-1 RD RD*Xt RD*Xt+1 RD*Xt+2 RD*Xt+3 RD*Rt+1 RD*Rt+2 RD*Rt+3 RD*AGt RD*Ept-1 InOw InOw*Xt InOw*Xt+1 InOw*Xt+2 InOw*Xt+3 InOw*Rt+1 InOw*Rt+2

Exp. Sign (?) (+) (+) (+) (+) (–) (–) (–) (–) (+) (?) (?) (+) (+) (+) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

Financial Leverage 0.151 (0.245) 0.457 (0.655) 1.458 (0.168) 0.119 (0.902) 0.633 (0.538) -0.674*** (0.000) -0.458*** (0.002) -0.415** (0.009) 0.029 (0.865) -0.026 (0.559) 0.064* (0.092) 0.307*** (0.008) 0.208* (0.072) 0.331*** (0.001) 0.147 (0.222) 0.032 (0.338) -0.020 (0.566) 0.029 (0.353) 0.009** (0.043) -0.000 (0.843) -0.001 (0.591) 0.029 (0.530) 0.112*** (0.004) 0.056 (0.182) 0.036 (0.435) -0.002 (0.689) 0.006 (0.332)

Firm Size 0.109 0.725 1.640 0.198 0.554 -0.618*** -0.419*** -0.347** 0.041 -0.04 0.073** 0.227** 0.139 0.292*** 0.162 0.008 -0.034 0.021 0.009** -0.000 -0.000 0.026 0.116*** 0.058 0.030 -0.004 0.007

Profitability (0.381) (0.429) (0.118) (0.840) (0.559) (0.000) (0.005) (0.025) (0.810) (0.930) (0.043) (0.025) (0.193) (0.005) (0.150) (0.825) (0.333) (0.496) (0.025) (0.868) (0.808) (0.493) (0.002) (0.160) (0.500) (0.454) (0.292)

0.246 1.540* 1.723* 0.151 0.097 -0.761*** -0. 382*** -0.237 0.042 -0.030 0. 067* 0.124 0.051 0.285** 0.105 0.002 -0.009 -0.000 0.007* 0.001 -0.000 0.003 0.093** 0 048 0.062 0.000 0.006

(0.053) (0.096) (0.085) (0.869) (0.914) (0.000) (0.006) (0.108) (0.796) (0.463) (0.069) (0.327) (0.707) (0.017) (0.428) (0.943) (0.779) (0.986) (0.089) (0.369) (0.793) (0.925) (0.014) (0.230) (0.180) (0.941) (0.381) 26

InOw*Rt+3 InOw*AGt InsOw*Ept-1 InOw*RD*Xt InOw*RD*Xt+1 InOw*RD*Xt+2 InOw*RD*Xt+3 InOw*RD*Rt+1 InOw*RD*Rt+2 InOw*RD*Rt+3 InOw*RD*AGt InOw*RD*EPt-1 Year Dummies Adj R2 Observations

(?) (?) (?) (?) (–) (–) (–) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

-0.003 0.004 -0.001 -0.010** -0.016*** -0.013*** -0.005* -0.001 -0.002* 0.000 0.000 -0.000 Yes 24.57% 785

(0.646) (0.598) (0.315) (0.027) (0.000) (0.003) (0.079) (0.200) (0.061) (0.341) (0.207) (0.423)

-0.003 0.004 -0.001 -0.011*** -0.016*** -0.011*** -0.005 -0.000 -0.002** 0.000 0.000 -0.000 Yes 24.89% 785

(0.544) (0.582) (0.255) (0.006) (0.000) (0.008) (0.111) (0.457) (0.032) (0.290) (0.127) (0.228)

-0.006 0.002 -0.001 -0.008** -0.013*** -0.011*** -0.007** -0.001 -0.002** 0.000 0.000* -0.000* Yes) 32.15% 785

(0.276) (0.760) (0.290) (0.027) (0.000) (0.001) (0.030) (0.112) (0.035) (0.152) (0.090) (0.059)

Table 5 presents fixed effects regression results for panel data. Heteroscedasticity-consistent p-values are given in parentheses. The dependent variable is current period return, Rt. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-andhold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. InOw is the total number of shares held by institutions to the total number of shares outstanding per sample firm. Financial leverage, firm size and profitability are control variables (their regression estimates are not tabulated). The significance levels (two-tail test) are: *= 10 %, ** =5 % and *** = 1 %.

To summarize, ownership structure as examined through the level of ownership concentration, managerial ownership and institutional investors decrease the informativeness of risk disclosure. These findings corroborate our first and second hypotheses and reject our third assumption. This may be explained by the fact that ownership in our sample firms is on average highly concentrated (the mean is 61.80%), with lower presence of institutional investors (the mean is 13.29%) and inside owners (13.37%). In such situation, corporation tends to issue less relevant risk disclosure as block holders do not have to rely on external disclosures to the same extent as companies with dispersed ownership, management interest are not aligned with shareholders and the low presence of institutional owners may prevent them from fulfilling their monitoring role. 5.2. Board characteristics and risk disclosure informativeness We basically address three corporate board characteristics. We hypothesized that the amount of non-executive directors, board size and the CEO/Chairman duality may impact (increase/decrease) the informativeness of risk disclosure with respect to future earnings. We provide coefficients estimates based on pooled OLS regression. 5.2.1. Non-executive directors and the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure Table 6 covers main regression findings for our fourth hypothesis. It provides estimates of the impact of the proportion of non-executive directors sitting on the board and the informativeness of risk disclosure. Risk disclosure does not seem to be informative about future earnings. The coefficients on the interaction terms RD*∑3k=1 Xt+k are though positive (except for RD*Xt+1), insignificant. The coefficient on RD*Rt+1 is positive and significant at the levels of 10% and 5%, mainly when controlling for financial leverage and firm size. 27

The partial F-test of the joint significance of RD*Xt+1 and RD*Rt+1 is only significant in the specification model that controls for corporate size at the level of 10%. The coefficients of interest are NED*RD*∑3k=1 Xt+k . These terms emphasize how the amount of non-executive directors influences the informativeness of voluntary risk information. In support of hypothesis 5, the coefficients on the interaction term NED*RD*Xt+1 are significantly positive at the levels of 1% and 5%. Our findings suggest that outside directors sitting on the board enhance the value relevance of risk disclosure in that their interactions impact positively risk disclosure informativeness about future earnings for one year ahead. There is no evidence of such impact for t+2 and t+3 periods. Accordingly, a high number of non-executive directors provides investors with assurance over annual report narratives. They are believed to be more influential in terms of the board decision making and particularly in enhancing the quality of corporate voluntary disclosure. Risk reporting is considered hence as a credible source of information for investors to predict future earnings growth. These findings corroborate our fifth hypothesis and are consistent with Wang and Hussainey (2013). They showed that higher proportions of non-executive directors are more likely to disclose relevant information related to future earnings, suggesting that greater financial reporting expertise exists on such boards. Our results are whereas inconsistent with Yu (2011) findings, which indicate that the information about expected future earnings growth do not appear to be effectively incorporated into the stock price for firms with optimal board structure (e.g. Board independence, board size, role duality). The insignificant association suggests that the quality of the board is a form of internal oversight that does not urge managers to offer information on a voluntary basis. Table 6. The effect of non-executive directors on the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure

Model

Exp. Sign

Intercept Xt Xt+1 Xt+2 Xt+3 Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 AGt Ept-1 RD RD*Xt RD*Xt+1 RD*Xt+2 RD*Xt+3 RD*Rt+1 RD*Rt+2 RD*Rt+3 RD*AGt RD*Ept-1 NED NED*Xt NED*Xt+1 NED*Xt+2 NED*Xt+3

(?) (+) (+) (+) (+) (–) (–) (–) (–) (+) (?) (?) (+) (+) (+) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

Financial Leverage -0.278*** -1.309 0.888 0.119 -0.741 -0.381** 0.320* -0.017 0.067 0.007 0.066*** 0.355 -0.287 0.424 0.470 0.097* -0.087 0.031 -0.027 -0.001 0.001* 0.001 -0.010*** -0.003 -0.001

0.004 0.153 0.315 0.899 0.482 0.023 0.061 0.952 0.112 0.289 0.006 0.340 0.407 0.219 0.258 0.094 0.166 0.754 0.150 0.386 0.051 0.765 0.000 0.346 0.651

Firm Size -0.285*** -1.187 0.633 0.127 -0.363 -0.404** 0.242 -0.123 0.034 0.005 0.070*** 0.091 -0.471 0.189 0.294 0.137** -0.026 0.025 -0.014 -0.001 0.001** -0.008* -0.011*** -0.004 -0.003

Profitability 0.004 0.199 0.473 0.891 0.729 0.016 0.153 0.543 0.465 0.532 0.004 0.814 0.202 0.607 0.513 0.027 0.685 0.757 0.409 0.561 0.046 0.069 0.000 0.134 0.244

-0.323*** -1.308 0.543 0.196 -0.527 -0.386** 0.217 -0.020 0.062 0.005 0.064*** 0.440 -0.128 0.411 0.447 0.102 -0.104 0.022 -0.034 -0.000 0.001** 0.003 -0.006 -0.003 0.000

0.001 0.156 0.558 0.832 0.618 0.022 0.202 0.927 0.129 0.498 0.008 0.279 0.731 0.247 0.291 0.105 0.117 0.793 0.173 0.667 0.047 0.502 0.207 0.433 0.944 28

NED*Rt+1 NED*Rt+2 NED*Rt+3 NED*AGt NED*Ept-1 NED*RD*Xt NED*RD*Xt+1 NED*RD*Xt+2 NED*RD*Xt+3 NED*RD*Rt+1 NED*RD*Rt+2 NED*RD*Rt+3 NED*RD*AGt NED*RD*EPt-1 Adj R2 Observations

(?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (+) (+) (+) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

0.001 0.140 -0.002 0.104 -0.003 0.328 -0.000 0.146 -0.000 0.518 0.005* 0.066 0.009*** 0.002 -0.004 0.168 -0.000 0.821 -0.001** 0.024 0.000 0.608 0.000 0.521 0.000 0.342 0.000 0.909 12.72% 789

0.002* 0.070 -0.000 0.558 -0.002 0.186 -0.000 0.462 0.000 0.651 0.008*** 0.008 0.010*** 0.001 -0.003 0.316 0.000 0.853 -0.001*** 0.009 -0.000 0.892 0.000 0.403 0.000 0.689 -0.000 0.593 12.49% 789

0.001 -0.003* -0.003 -0.000 0.000 0.004 0.007** -0.004 -0.001 -0.001** 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.000 12.12% 789

0.158 0.051 0.157 0.354 0.448 0.191 0.029 0.161 0.747 0.040 0.372 0.409 0.360 0.476

Table 6 presents OLS regression results for pooled data. Heteroscedasticity-consistent p-values are given in parentheses. The dependent variable is current period return, Rt. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-andhold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. NED is the proportion of non-executive directors relative to the board size. Financial leverage, firm size and profitability are control variables (their regression estimates are not tabulated). The significance levels (two-tail test) are: *= 10 %, ** =5 % and *** = 1 %.

5.2.2. Board size and the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure In table 7 we present multiple regression estimates for our fifth hypothesis which examine the effect of board size on risk disclosure informativeness. The coefficients on RD*∑3k=1 Xt+k exhibit a negative sign and are mostly insignificant except for the interaction term RD*Xt+3 which are significantly different from zero at the levels of 5% and 1%. These findings indicate that risk information which are not driven by the number of board directors appear to reduce the share price forecast of future earnings. Estimates of primary interest are given by the coefficients on the interaction terms BS*RD*∑3k=1 Xt+k. Consistent with our prior expectation, results revealed a positive and significant effect of risk disclosure driven by board size on the market’s ability to anticipate future earnings growth for three years ahead. Such results indicate that firms with large board size are more likely to disclose significantly useful voluntary information about corporate opportunities and risks. Investors seem to trust risk information conveyed by firms with a large board size as it reflects a diverse expertise and is likely to guarantee a higher level of compliance with the accountability paradigm. These findings, therefore, support our fifth hypothesis. They are consistent with Wang and Hussainey (2013) who showed that large board size is associated with more informative information about future earnings in corporate annual reports. On the contrary, our results are inconsistent with Ferrreira et al. (2011) and Yu (2011) who failed to provide evidence that stock prices are more informative about future earnings growth in firms with a large board size.

29

Table 7. The effect of board size on the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure Model Intercept Xt Xt+1 Xt+2 Xt+3 Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 AGt Ept-1 RD RD*Xt RD*Xt+1 RD*Xt+2 RD*Xt+3 RD*Rt+1 RD*Rt+2 RD*Rt+3 RD*AGt RD*Ept-1 BS BS*Xt BS*Xt+1 BS*Xt+2 BS*Xt+3 BS*Rt+1 BS*Rt+2 BS*Rt+3 BS*AGt BS*Ept-1 BS*RD*Xt BS*RD*Xt+1 BS*RD*Xt+2 BS*RD*Xt+3 BS*RD*Rt+1 BS*RD*Rt+2 BS*RD*Rt+3 BS*RD*AGt BS*RD*EPt-1 Adj R2 Observations

Exp. Sign (?) (+) (+) (+) (+) (–) (–) (–) (–) (+) (?) (?) (+) (+) (+) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (+) (+) (+) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

Financial Leverage -0.093 -4.297 5.231 3.750 10.780** 0.128 -0.543 0.104 -0.130 0.032 0.081*** 1.837 -1.266 -1.185 -3.475** -0.143 0.123 -0.047 0.047 -0.008 -0.014* 0.274 -0.802 -0.494 -1.451*** -0.043 0.101* -0.040 0.019 -0.002 -0.106 0.244 0.174 0.480*** 0.017 -0.027 0.016 -0.007 0.000 9.89% 789

0.373 0.260 0.200 0.351 0.013 0.806 0.223 0.877 0.321 0.383 0.001 0.119 0.339 0.362 0.015 0.375 0.408 0.824 0.348 0.356 0.096 0.538 0.117 0.326 0.006 0.482 0.088 0.612 0.271 0.413 0.434 0.142 0.282 0.006 0.355 0.166 0.523 0.302 0.404

Firm Size -0.088 0.398 -4.892 0.191 4.270 0.292 4.350 0.275 9.423** 0.032 0.162 0.755 -0.404 0.368 -0.083 0.901 -0.057 0.655 0.027 0.462 0.079*** 0.002 1.952* 0.090 -1.106 0.404 -1.620 0.211 -3.106** 0.032 -0.128 0.424 0.132 0.373 -0.009 0.966 0.025 0.606 -0.007 0.430 -0.014 0.102 0.304 0.485 -0.681 0.179 -0.564 0.257 -1.297** 0.015 -0.044 0.467 0.091 0.125 -0.020 0.791 0.014 0.393 -0.001 0.511 -0.126 0.340 0.216 0.194 0.198 0.216 0.440** 0.012 0.017 0.366 -0.024 0.220 0.009 0.694 -0.005 0.391 0.000 0.478 10.11% 789

Profitability -0.154 0.160 -6.449* 0.096 7.549* 0.072 5.209 0.193 13.063*** 0.004 0.078 0.881 -0.889* 0.065 0.179 0.791 -0.021 0.86 0.038 0.291 0.071*** 0.005 2.430** 0.037 -1.717 0.207 -1.611 0.213 -3.941*** 0.007 -0.131 0.413 0.200 0.183 -0.057 0.789 0.010 0.825 -0.010 0.285 -0.013 0.110 0.573 0.197 -0.965* 0.063 -0.619 0.214 -1.662*** 0.002 -0.039 0.519 0.134** 0.029 -0.038 0.628 0.007 0.651 -0.002 0.309 -0.183 0.171 0.289* 0.091 0.226 0.160 0.534*** 0.002 0.016 0.399 -0.038* 0.056 0.014 0.568 -0.003 0.641 0.000 0.288 10.90%

Table 7 presents OLS regression results for pooled data. Heteroscedasticity-consistent p-values are given in parentheses. The dependent variable is current period return, Rt. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-andhold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. BS is the number of directors sitting on the board at the end of each year. Financial leverage, firm size and profitability are control variables (their regression estimates are not tabulated). The significance levels (twotail test) are: *= 10 %, ** =5 % and *** = 1 %.

30

5.2.3. CEO/Chairman duality and the informativeness of risk disclosure Table 8 summarizes main findings regarding our hypothesis 6 testing. We predicted a weaker impact of CEO/Chairman duality on voluntary risk disclosure informativeness. There is evidence on risk disclosure informativeness with respect to future earnings of period t+1 given the significant coefficients on RD*Xt+1. The coefficients on the interaction term RD*Rt+3 are likewise positive and significant at the levels of 5% and 10% and the joint significance test for the slope coefficients on RD*Xt+3 and RD*Rt+3 yielded a significant F statistic at the level of 5%. These findings suggest that risk reporting activity which is not related to the presence of the CEO/chairperson duality is informative about future earnings growth. The incremental impact of the role duality on the information content of risk disclosure is given by the coefficients on interacted variables DUAL*RD*∑𝟑𝑲=𝟏 Xt+K. Findings rejected our hypothesis H7 in that the coefficients of the interaction terms are insignificant in all the specifications even though they exhibit the predicted sign. There is hence no evidence that risk disclosure driven by role duality is less informative about future earnings. Risk reporting related to role duality impacts negatively and significantly the credibility of current earnings at the level of 1%. Firms with the same person occupying the roles of chairman and CEO have then significant credibility problems with their financial reports and in particular with information about corporate risk. The stock market places lower credibility on such information, presumably because the CEO/chairperson is likely to compromise the board independence and to seek private interests. Thereby, this situation can lead to conflicts of interest that encompass the accounting system and the voluntary release of useful information. Our results are in line with Yu (2011) findings, which indicate that there is no effect of the board leadership structure (as examined through board quality index) on the earnings’ information content of stock prices. They are also consistent with some recent voluntary and risk disclosure literature such as Cheng and Courtenay (2006), Elshandidy et al (2013), Elzahar and Hussainey (2012) and Mokhtar and Mellet (2013) which failed to confirm that role duality is a potential threat to disclosure quality. These results in turn do support neither agency theory nor the signaling theory. Table 8. The effect of role duality on the informativeness of voluntary risk disclosure

Model Intercept Xt Xt+1 Xt+2 Xt+3 Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 AGt Ept-1 RD RD*Xt RD*Xt+1 RD*Xt+2 RD*Xt+3 RD*Rt+1 RD*Rt+2

Exp. Sign (?) (+) (+) (+) (+) (–) (–) (–) (–) (+) (?) (?) (+) (+) (+) (?) (?)

Financial Leverage -0.158** -3.871*** -1.412 -1.179 -1.764 -0.240 0.128 -0.467** 0.015 0.000 0.061** 1.608*** 0.759* 0.473 0.633 0.005 -0.048

0.041 0.000 0.287 0.347 0.162 0.156 0.389 0.029 0.512 0.966 0.013 0.000 0.070 0.233 0.111 0.915 0.335

Firm Size -0.173** -3.773*** 1.603 -0.555 -1.692 -0.187 0.214 -0.414* 0.057 0.004 0.066*** 1.492*** 0.793* 0.091 0.691 0.005 -0.018

Profitability 0.028 0.001 0.220 0.661 0.189 0.276 0.168 0.051 0.163 0.837 0.008 0.000 0.068 0.835 0.121 0.915 0.724

-.213*** -3.485*** -0.768 -0.854 -1.317 -0.259 0.067 -0.387* 0.043 0.000 0.054** 1.624*** 0.775* 0.442 0.593 0.004 -0.049

0.010 0.002 0.556 0.512 0.323 0.130 0.676 0.066 0.179 0.976 0.027 0.000 0.058 0.265 0.137 0.926 0.322 31

RD*Rt+3 RD*AGt RD*Ept-1 DUAL DUAL*Xt DUAL*Xt+1 DUAL*Xt+2 DUAL*Xt+3 DUAL*Rt+1 DUAL *Rt+2 DUAL *Rt+3 DUAL *AGt DUAL *Ept-1 DUAL *RD*Xt DUAL *RD*Xt+1 DUAL *RD*Xt+2 DUAL *RD*Xt+3 DUAL *RD*Rt+1 DUAL *RD*Rt+2 DUAL *RD*Rt+3 DUAL *RD*AGt DUAL *RD*EPt-1 Adj R2 Observations

(?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?) (-) (-) (-) (?) (?) (?) (?) (?)

0.176** -0.006 -0.000 0.026 5.327*** 0.626 1.525 0.943 0.045 0.128 0.623* -0.010 0.007 -1.961*** -.345 -.273 -.437 -.019 -.050 -.239 .002 -.003 10.39% 789

0.015 0.442 0.982 0.551 0.004 0.733 0.393 0.662 0.869 0.644 0.099 0.867 0.733 0.001 0.588 0.652 0.564 0.827 0.583 0.051 0.906 0.567

0.139* -0.018 -0.001 0.024 4.320** 1.568 0.224 1.783 -0.036 0.066 0.401 -0.013 0.001 -1.717*** -0.637 0.172 -0.719 0.011 -0.049 -0.165 0.001 -0.001 10.66% 789

0.058 0.133 0.754 0.572 0.016 0.415 0.906 0.440 0.896 0.813 0.293 0.811 0.951 0.003 0.335 0.788 0.368 0.903 0.595 0.178 0.923 0.794

0.161** -0.014 -0.000 0.023 6.065*** 1.109 1.166 0.820 0.039 0.071 0.704* -0.027 0.004 -2.215*** -0.510 -0.126 -0.467 -0.017 -0.033 -0.256** 0.006 -0.002 11.44% 789

0.026 0.131 0.938 0.589 0.001 0.533 0.513 0.695 0.884 0.796 0.060 0.630 0.842 0.000 0.415 0.834 0.529 0.842 0.711 0.034 0.730 0.693

Table 8 presents OLS regression results for pooled data. Heteroscedasticity-consistent p-values are given in parentheses. The dependent variable is current period return, Rt. Rt, Rt+1, Rt+2 and Rt+3 are calculated as buy-andhold returns (inclusive of dividends) over a 12-month period, starting six months after the end of the previous financial year. Xt, Xt+1, Xt+2 and Xt+3 are defined as earnings change deflated by price. Both current and future earnings changes are deflated by the price at the start of the return window for period t. EPt–1 is defined as period t–1’s earnings over price six months after the financial year-end of period t–1. AGt is the growth rate of the total book value of assets for period t. RD is the natural logarithm of the total number of risk related sentences. Dual is a dummy variable defined as 1 if CEO is the Chairman and 0 otherwise. Financial leverage, firm size and profitability are control variables (their regression estimates are not tabulated). The significance levels (two-tail test) are: *= 10 %, ** =5 % and *** = 1 %.

In summary, our results evidenced that good board structure (large size and high proportion of non-executive directors) enhances risk disclosure informativeness about future earnings. Investors believe that board diversity increases members’ expertise, eliminates environmental uncertainties and enhances the richness of information environment. Market participants also think that non-executive directors can restrain the managerial self-serving behavior and ensure useful risk reporting in anticipating future earnings growth. Regarding board leadership, role duality does not seem to impact risk disclosure informativeness with respect to future earnings. Even more, investors seem to question the credibility of voluntary risk information and perceive current earnings as less value relevant for firms characterized by the presence of a dominant person.

32

5.3. Robustness checks: The endogenous nature of corporate governance choice and the informativeness of risk information Recent academic research addressed an important question of whether good corporate governance has a first order effect on some outcome variables (e.g. Firm performance, firm valuation, financial reporting quality, share price informativeness). According to Beyer et al. (2010), given the endogenous nature of the corporate information environment, the firms’ governance mechanisms, and some observed outcomes, it is hard to make an assessment of the causal connection and recognize the exact impact that one mechanism would have on another one. Our main concern arises from the potential endogeneity problem between risk disclosure informativeness and firm-level governance structure. The causality might run from risk disclosure informativeness to corporate governance improvement, or other omitted firm characteristics could impact both voluntary risk disclosure informativeness and corporate governance. For example, Durnev et al. (2004) suggest that information conveyed by share prices can affect firm governance mechanisms as it signals to the capital markets on the need to react when management decisions are inadequate. More informative disclosure can serve as a disciplining mean in that it enhances external monitoring mechanisms (shareholder lawsuits, institutional investor pressure, and the market for corporate control) as well as the internal monitoring role of the board (Ferreira et al. 2011; Holmström and Tirole, 1993). If governance structure regressors are inferred to be endogenously determined, failure to incorporate exogenous determinants of the association between share price informativeness and corporate governance choices will result in correlated omitted variables problem. Standard OLS regression will provide inconsistent parameters due to the correlated omitted variables’ problem. The common econometric solution to endogeneity issue is the use of instrumental variables’ specification procedure. Instrumental variables should be associated with endogenous regressors but unrelated to the error term in the structural equation (Habib and Azim 2008). Winship and Morgan (1999) and Larker et al (2007) argue that while this approach is theoretically strong, in practice, it is difficult to find an instrumental variable that is correlated with assignment to treatment level but not the outcome. Larcker and Rusticus (2010) showed that OLS estimates provide better parameter estimates than two-stage least square approach if the chosen instrumental variables do not conform to the standard definition of instrumental variables. The selection of adequate instruments in the present study is challenging because we use multiple endogenous variables as measures of corporate governance, that is, ownership concentration, institutional ownership, executive director ownership, board size, board composition and role duality. In addition, since our board structure data have mostly no time variation, there is no appropriate way to address the issue of causality directly. We address the potential endogeneity problems using first time and firm fixed effects regressions that control for unobserved sources of firm heterogeneity. The fixed effects results go a long way towards dismissing omitted variable explanations as a source of endogeneity (Ferreira et al, 2010). The second way to mitigate the problem of causality is to add appropriate control variables consistent with Lehn et al., (2007) and Larcker et al., (2007). Specifically, we included some of the joint exogenous determinants of firm-level corporate governance choices and earnings response coefficients determinants which are firm financial leverage level (debt to equity ratio), firm size (natural logarithm of corporate revenue) and 33

corporate profitability (natural logarithm of the return on equity ROE) in all of our regression equations. As for our pooled OLS regression that examines board characteristics we follow the Larcker and Rusticus (2010) and Frank (2000)’s alternative approach. Their method involves assessing how large the endogeneity issue (unmodeled variable) has to be to change the OLS coefficient estimates and, in particular, how large it has to be to make the coefficient statistically insignificant. Unlike the instrumental variable approach that is meant to reduce bias in the coefficient estimates, Frank (2000) and Frank et al. (2008) method is used to assess the sensitivity of a coefficient and its standard error to the inclusion of a confounding variable. They specified a minimum threshold necessary for an omitted confounding variable to invalidate the significant results of a variable of interest in an ordinary least square regression model. Frank (2000) offered an improvement over previous applications of sensitivity analysis and suggests that for a confounding variable to impact the statistical inference, it should be correlated with both the independent variable and the dependent variable (controlling for the other variables). For the purpose of our sensitivity test we calculate the impact of the confounding variables on the significant coefficients of two endogenous independent variables with respect board characteristics (BS and NED). While, by definition, we do not have access to the unobserved and unmodeled variable, we do have other control variables: financial leverage ratio, firm size and profitability. We are able, therefore, to calculate the impact of the inclusion of each control variable on the significant coefficient on the interaction terms NED*RD*Xt+1 and BS*RD*Xt+3. Likewise, the impact of each control variable is the product of the partial correlation between the endogenous board characteristics’ measures and the control variables and the correlation between the dependent variable (Rt) and the control variable (taking out partially the effects of the other control variables). Frank et al. (2013) suggest that for a valid inference, the impact of a confounding and unmodeled variable should not exceed the estimated impact threshold, otherwise the coefficients on the explanatory endogenous variables would be considered as fragile. Table 9 reports the results of our sensitivity analysis. The threshold value for the proportion of non-executive directors is 0.0364 which suggests the correlation between the dependent variable (Rt) and the endogenous independent variable (NED*RD*Xt+1) with the unobserved confounding variable each only need to be about 0.190 (√0.036) for the OLS result to be overturned. Given that our control variables are interacted with predictors in the augmented Collins et al (1994) regression of current returns on future earnings, we follow Frank (2000)’s approach in addressing the specific case of multiple confounds. Frank (2000) used the square root of the multiple correlation between x and cv (r(x.cv)) and the square root of the multiple correlation between y and cv.(r(y⋅cv)) to assess the impact of confounding variables. It is worth noting that in our case r(y⋅cv) and r(x.cv) are the r2 statistics from the regressions of current returns and the predictor of interest on controlling variables3.

3

In comparing the ITCV to the distribution of impact scores for the control variables we implicitly assume that the confounding variable is similarly correlated with the other control variables.

34

Firm size (0.21) and corporate profitability (0.175) have the largest impact on our regression coefficients. Indeed, the impact of financial leverage, firm size and corporate profitability are respectively 58 percent, 476 percent and 382 percent of the ITCV for the interacted variable NED*RD*Xt+1. These results suggest that these control variables are important covariates to be included in the model, although comparable covariates, in and of themselves, would not alter the inference with regard to the variable of interest. Accordingly, our statistic inference with respect to the joint effect of the proportion of non-executive directors and risk disclosure on share price anticipation of future earnings is robust to the problem of omitted variable. The threshold single value for Board size (BS) is about 0.0345 suggesting each of the relevant correlations needs to be about 0.185 (√0.0345) for the OLS result to be overturned. Similarly, firm size (0.227) and profitability (0.167) exhibit the largest impact on our OLS regression coefficients. Moreover, the impact of financial leverage, firm size and corporate profitability are 135 percent, 558 percent and 386 percent respectively of the ITCV for the interacted predictor BS*RD*Xt+3. These control variables are therefore important covariates and have to be included in the model, although comparable covariates, in and of themselves, would not alter the inference with regard to the variable of interest. Accordingly, our statistic inference with respect to the joint effect of the board size and risk disclosure on share price anticipation of future earnings is robust to the problem of unmodeled variables. These findings cleared, then the concern with regard to causal inference in our pooled OLS regression and confirmed that the estimated coefficients are valid as we controlled for the observed strong covariate. Table 9. The impact of unmodeled variables

OLS REG

Explanatory(endogenous)/Control Variables Constant BC1: NED*RD*Xt+1 BC2: BS*RD*Xt+3 Impact thresholds (BC1) Impact thresholds (BC2) Impact of control (BC1) Reliability (Impact/ITCV) Impact of control (BC2) Reliability (Impact/ITCV)

Financial leverage -0.278*** 0.009*** 0.480***

Firm size

Profitability

-0.285*** 0.010*** 0.440**

-0.323*** 0.007** 0.534***

0.057 1.58 0.081 2.35

0.21 5.76 0.227 6.58

0.175 4.82 0.167 4.86

0.0364 0.0345

For the two endogenous independent variables, an impact statistic is calculated (ITCV) indicating the minimum impact of an unobserved variable that is needed to render the coefficient statistically insignificant. The ITCV is defined as the product of the correlation between the endogenous independent variables (BC1 and BC2) and the unmodeled variable and the correlation between the dependent variable (current stock returns) and the control variables (partialling out the effect of the other control variables). The sign of the impact measure indicates how the inclusion of the control variable affects the coefficient for the endogenous independent variables (BC1 and BC2) respectively. The impact results also help in assessing the likelihood that such an unmodeled variable exists. The sign of the impact score indicates how the inclusion of each control variable affects the coefficient of each endogenous independent variable. A positive impact score indicates that inclusion of the control variables makes the coefficient on the endogenous independent variable more positive or less negative. A negative impact score has the opposite effect. Impact/ITCV is the reliability of the control variable.

35

6. Conclusion This study aims to test whether corporate governance mechanisms influence the informativeness narrative risk disclosure in annual reports for a sample of MENA emerging markets. We defined the informativeness of risk disclosure as the extent to which the level of voluntary risk information improves the amount of future earnings news impounded into share prices. Our main hypotheses predict that voluntary risk disclosures informativeness might be weaker for concentrated ownership, in the presence of managerial ownership and CEO/Chairman duality. In contrast, the informativeness of risk disclosure might be positively influenced by the presence of institutional owners, the amount of non-executive directors and large-sized boards. Our empirical findings are based on large samples of annual reports electronically available for roughly 320 non-financial firms listed in nine MENA emerging markets. We generated our estimates from year by year OLS and panel regressions whereby we controlled for the cross-sectional effects of some determinants of voluntary disclosure as well as the earnings response coefficients such as risk, firm size and profitability. Consistent with some recent studies, we highlighted the cross sectional time series dynamics in risk disclosure by adopting a longitudinal approach. We found that good board structure (large size and high proportion of non-executive directors) enhances the information content of risk disclosure. In contrast, ownership structure as examined through the level of ownership concentration, managerial ownership and institutional investors seems to decrease the informativeness of risk information. The presence of CEO/chairman duality had no impact on the value relevance of risk disclosure. Although this study is one of the pioneering researches that investigated the impact of corporate governance on the usefulness of voluntary risk disclosure in anticipating future earnings, it still suffers from some caveats. First, we believe that the process of analyzing annual report narratives has scope for further refinement. While our current methodology equates disclosure quality with the amount of information provided, we think that future studies should differentiate risk disclosure that provides favorable from those that provide unfavorable earnings news. Another refinement is to discriminate between the sub-categories of risk disclosure which could be extremely useful for studying the effect of governance mechanisms on each type of risk related disclosures. Also, given that the corporate governance definition of good best practices is still ambiguous and unresolved (Brickley and Zimmerman, 2010), the internal and external governance measures might suffer from measurement bias. As risk reporting is still a fertile area not only for empirical but also for conceptual and analytical research, we think that there are many refinements and other dependent variables that could be investigated in future research. In particular, corporate audit environment (audit committee composition, external auditor independence, etc.…), categories of institutional investors (short term/long term investors), different types of block-holding (i.e., in institutions, in financial firms, in nonfinancial firms, and by individuals) and the presence of litigation costs may also have differing effects on the perceived relevance of risk disclosure. Finally, while our study provides interesting results about the cross sectional time series effect of corporate governance on the informativeness of risk disclosure in the context of MENA emerging markets, cross-country differences in risk reporting informativeness are uncovered by this study. Accordingly, future research may fill this gap and empirically examine some countrylevel governance factors that explain these differences.

36

References AbdelFattah, T. M. H., Dixon, R., Woodhead, A., (2008), “Corporate governance and voluntary disclosure in emerging capital markets: evidence from Egypt”. Working Paper, Durham University, Durham. Abdul Hamid, M., Nordin, N. (2013) “Corporate Risk Management, Firm Characteristics, Ownership Structure, and Governance Attributes of Banks: A Case of Malaysia”. Prosiding Perkem, 8(2), 655 – 660. Abraham S., Cox, P. (2007) “Analysing the determinants of narrative risk information in UK FTSE 100 annual reports”. The British Accounting Review , 39, 227–248 Agrawal A., Mandelker, G. N. (1990). “Large Shareholders and the Monitoring of Managers: The Case of Antitakeover Charter Amendments”. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 25(2), 143-161 Ajinkya, B., Bhojraj, S., Sengupta P., (2005). “The association between outside directors, institutional investors and the properties of management earnings forecasts”. Journal of Accounting Research, 43(2), 343-376. Allini, A, Hussainey, K., Manes Rossi, F. (2014). The board’s role in risk disclosure: An exploratory study in Italian listed government-owned companies. ERRN 9th European Risk Conference, Naples University. Aloui C., Rejichi, I. Z. (2012) “Hurst exponent behavior and assessment of the MENA stock markets efficiency”. Research in International Business and Finance, 26, 353– 370 Amico, A. (2014), “Corporate Governance Enforcement in the Middle East and North Africa: Evidence and Priorities”, OECD Corporate Governance Working Papers, No. 15, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jxws6scxg7c-en Banghoj J., Plenborg T., (2008) “Value relevance of voluntary disclosure in the annual report”. Accounting and Finance, 48, 159-180. Bao Y., Datta A., (2014) “Simultaneously Discovering and Quantifying Risk Types from Textual Risk Disclosures”. Management Science, 60(6), 1371-1391. Barakat A., Hussainey K. (2013) “ Bank governance, regulation, supervision, and risk reporting: Evidence from operational risk disclosures in European banks”. International Review of Financial Analysis, 30, 254–273. Barako, D. G. (2007). “Determinants of voluntary disclosure in Kenya companies annual reports”. African Journal of Business Management, 1(5), 113-128. Barako, D.G., Hancock P., Izan, H.Y. (2006) “Factors influencing voluntary corporate disclosure by Kenyan companies”. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 14 (2), 107–125. Bassett M., Koh, P. S., Tutticci, I. (2007), “The association between employee stock option disclosures and corporate governance: evidence from an enhanced disclosure regime”. British Accounting Review, 39(4), 303-322. Bauwhede H. V., Willekens M., (2008). “Disclosure on Corporate Governance in the European Union”. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 16(2), 101-115. Beasley, M. (1996). “An Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Board of Director Composition and Financial Statement Fraud”. The Accounting Review, 71(4), 443-465. Beekes, W. A., Brown P., (2006). “Do better-governed Australian firms make more informative disclosures?”. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 33(3-4), 422-450. Ben Naceur S., Laabidi. C. (2009) “Middle East and North Africa Region: Financial Sector and Integration”. Resource, 5(6.5), 5-7. Ben Othman H., Zeghal. D., (2010) “Investigating transparency and disclosure determinants at firm-level in MENA emerging markets”. Int. J. Accounting, Auditing and Performance Evaluation, 6(4), 368-396.

37

Beyer, A, D. Cohen, T. Z. Lys, and Walther B. R., (2010) “The financial reporting environment: review of the recent literature”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, 296-343. Bley, J. (2011). “Are GCC stock markets predictable”? Emerging Markets Review, 12(3), 217– 237. Boesso G., Kumar K., (2007) “Drivers of corporate voluntary disclosure: A framework and empirical evidence from Italy and the United States”. Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 20(2), 269 – 296. Bowman, E. H. (1984). “Content analysis of annual reports for corporate strategy and risk”. Interfaces, 14, 61-71. Bozec, R., Bozec, Y. (2012). The use of governance indexes in the governance–performance relationship literature: International evidence. Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences, 29,79–98. Brickley, J. A., Zimmerman, J. L. (2010). Corporate governance myths: Comments on Armstrong, Guay, and Weber. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50(2–3), 235‑245. Brown P, W. Beekes, Verhoeven P., (2011) “Corporate governance, accounting and finance: A review”. Accounting and Finance, 51, 96–172 Bushee, B. J., Noe, C. F. (2000). “Corporate Disclosure Practices, Institutional Investors, and Stock Return Volatility”. Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 171-202. Bushman, R., Piotroski J., Smith A., (2004) “What Determines Corporate Transparency?” Journal of Accounting Research, 42, 207-252. Campbell, J. L., Chen, H., Dhaliwal, D. S., Lu, M., and Steele, L. B. (2014). “The information content of mandatory risk factor disclosures in corporate filings”. Review Accounting Study,19, 396–455 Chalmers, K., Godfrey, J. M. (2004). “Reputation costs: the impetus for voluntary derivative financial instrument reporting”. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 29(2), 95‑125. Chen, C., Jaggi B., (2000) “Association Between Independent Non-Executive Directors, Family control and Financial Disclosures in Hong Kong”. Journal of Accounting and PublicPolicy, 19, 285-310. Cheng, C., Courtenay M., (2006) “Board Composition, Regulatory Regime and Voluntary Disclosure”. The International Journal of Accounting, 41, 262-289. Chung K. H., Zhang H.. (2011) “Corporate Governance and Institutional Ownership”. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46, 247-273. Chung, R., Firth, M., Kim, J. (2002). Institutional monitoring and opportunistic earnings management. Journal of Corporate Finance, 8(1), 29‑48. Cohen, J. R., Krishnamoorthy, G., and Wright, A. (2004). The corporate governance mosaic and financial reporting quality. Journal of Accounting literature, 87-152. Collins, D.W., Kathari, S.P., Shanken, J., Sloan R.G., (1994). “Lack of timeliness and noise as explanations for the low contemporaneous return– earnings association”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 18, 289–324 Dechow, P. M., Sloan, R. G., and Sweeney, A. P. (1996). Causes and consequences of earnings manipulation: An analysis of firms subject to enforcement actions by the SEC. Contemporary accounting research, 13(1), 1-36. Deumes R., Knechel, W. R., (2008) “Economic Incentives for Voluntary Reporting on Internal Risk Management and Control Systems”. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, 27(1), 35–66 Dimitropoulos, P E., Asteriou, A.D. (2010). "The effect of board composition on the informativeness and quality of annual earnings: Empirical evidence from Greece." Research in International Business and Finance, 24(2), 190-205 Dobler, M. (2008). “Incentives for risk reporting-A discretionary disclosure and cheap talk approach”. The International Journal of Accounting, 43(2), 184–206. 38

Donnelly, R., Lynch C., (2002). “The Ownership Structure of UK Firms and the Informativeness of Accounting Earnings”. Accounting and Business Research, 32, 245-257. Donnelly, R., Mulcahy, M. B. (2008). “Board Structure, Ownership, and Voluntary Disclosure in Ireland”. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 16(5), 416–429. Durnev, A., Morck R., Yeung B., (2004). “Value enhancing capital budgeting and firm specific return variation”, Journal of Finance, 59(1), 65-105. Elshandidy T., Fraser I., Hussainey K., (2013). “Aggregated, voluntary, and mandatory risk disclosure incentives: Evidence from UK FTSE all-share companies”. International Review of Financial Analysis, 30, 320–333 Elshandidy, T., Fraser I., Hussainey K., (2014), “What drives mandatory and voluntary risk reporting variations across Germany, UK and US?” The British Accounting Review. Forthcoming. Elshandidy, T., Neri, L., (2015), “Corporate Governance, Risk Disclosure Practices, and Market Liquidity: Comparative Evidence from the UK and Italy”. Corporate Governance: An International Review. Forthcoming Elzahar H., Hussainey K, (2012) “Determinants of narrative risk disclosures in UK interim reports”. The Journal of Risk Finance, 13 (2), 133 - 147 Fama, E. F. (1980). “Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm”. Journal of Political Economy, 88(2), 288‑307. Fama, E. F., Jensen, M. C. (1983). “Separation of ownership and control”. Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 301-325. Fan, J. P. H., Wong, T. J. (2002). “Corporate ownership structure and the informativeness of accounting earnings in East Asia”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33(3),401‑425. Ferreira, D. Ferreira A., Raposo M., Clara C., (2011). “Board structure and price informativeness." Journal of Financial Economics, 99(3), 523-545. Ferreira, M., Massa M., Matos P., (2010). “Shareholders at the gate? Institutional investors and cross-border mergers and acquisitions”. Review of Financial Studies, 23, 601–644. Firth, M., Fung P. M. P., Rui O. M., (2007), “Ownership, two-tier board structure, and the informativeness of earnings-Evidence from China”, Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 26, 463-496 Forker, J. J. (1992). “Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality”. Accounting and Business Research, 22(86), 111‑124. Frank, K. A., Sykes, G., Anagnostopoulos, D., Cannata, M., Chard, L., Krause, A., & McCrory, R. (2008). “Does NBPTS Certification Affect the Number of Colleagues a Teacher Helps With Instructional Matters”? Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 30(1), 3‑30. Frank, K.A., (2000). “Impact of a confounding variable on a regression coefficient”. Sociological Methods and Research, 29, 147–194. Frank, K.A., Maroulis, S., Duong, M., and Kelcey, B. (2013). “What would it take to Change an Inference?: Using Rubin’s Causal Model to Interpret the Robustness of Causal Inferences”. Education, Evaluation and Policy Analysis. 35: 437-460. Gabrielsen, G., Gramlich, J. D., Plenborg, T. (2002). “Managerial Ownership, Information Content of Earnings, and Discretionary Accruals in a Non–US Setting”. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 29(7-8), 967‑988. Gelb, D. S., Zarowin P. (2002). “Corporate disclosure policy and the informativeness of stock prices”. Review of Accounting Studies, 7 (1): 33–52. Gelb, S.D., (2000). “Corporate signaling with dividends, stock repurchases, and accounting disclosures: an empirical study”. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 15, 99–121. Ghazali, N.A.M., Weetman P., (2006). “Perpetuating traditional influences: Voluntary disclosure in Malaysia”. Journal of International Accounting Auditing and Taxation, 15 (2), 226-248. 39

Guercio, D. D., Hawkins J., (1999). "The motivation and impact of pension fund activism," Journal of Financial Economics, 52(3), 293-340. Gul, F. A., Leung, S. (2004) “Board leadership, outside directors expertise and voluntary corporate disclosures”. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 23(5), 351–379. Gul, F. A., Lynn S. G., Tsui J. S. L. (2002). “Audit quality, management ownership and the informativeness of accounting earnings”. Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance, 17, 25-49. Habib, A., Azim, I. (2008). “Corporate governance and the value-relevance of accounting information: Evidence from Australia”. Accounting Research Journal, 21(2), 167‑194. Haniffa, R., T. Cooke (2002), “Culture, corporate governance and disclosure in Malaysian corporations”. ABACUS, 36(3), 317- 773. Harrison, B., Moore, W. R. (2012). “Stock Market Efficiency, Non-Linearity, Thin Trading and Asymmetric Information in MENA Stock Markets”. Economic Issues Journal Articles, 17(1), 77‑93. Hayes, A. F., Krippendorff K., (2007).“Answering the call for a standard reliability measure for coding data.” Communication Methods and Measures, 1, 77-89. Ho, S.S.M., Wong K.S., (2001). “A study of the relationship between corporate governance structure and the extent of voluntary disclosure”. Journal of International Accounting Auditing & Taxation, 10 (2), 139-156. Holmström, B., Tirole, J. (1993), “Market liquidity and performance monitoring”. Journal of Political Economy, 101 (4), 678 – 709. Hossain M, Courtenay S. M., Luo S., (2006), “The effect of voluntary disclosure, ownership Structure and proprietary cost on the return–future earnings relation”. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 14, 501–521. Hossain, M., Reaz, M. (2007). “The determinants and characteristics of voluntary disclosure by Indian banking companies”. Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management, 14(5), 274‑288. Hussainey K., Walker M., (2009) “The effects of voluntary disclosure and dividend propensity on prices leading earnings.” Accounting and Business Research, 39(1), 37-55. Hussainey, K., Al-Najjar, B. (2011) “Future-oriented narrative reporting: determinants and use”. Journal of Applied Accounting Research, 12 (2), 123-138. Jensen, M. C., Murphy, K. J. (1990). “Performance Pay and Top-Management Incentives”. Journal of Political Economy, 98(2), 225‑64. Jensen, M.C., Meckling W.H., (1976). “Theory of the firm; managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360. Jiang, H., Habib, A., Hu, B. (2011). “Ownership concentration, voluntary disclosures and information asymmetry in New Zealand”. The British Accounting Review, 43(1), 39‑53. Jorgensen, B. N. & Kirschenheiter, M. T. (2012). “Interactive discretionary disclosures”. Contemporary Accounting Research, 29(2), 382-397. Kajüter, P. (2006). “Risk disclosure of listed firms in Germany: a longitudinal study”. Paper presented at the 10th Financial Reporting & Business Communication Conference Cardiff Business school. Karamanou, I., Vafeas, N. (2005). The Association between Corporate Boards, Audit Committees, and Management Earnings Forecasts: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of Accounting Research, 43(3), 453‑486. Khlif, H., Samaha, K., Hussainey, K. (2014). ‘The impact of board characteristics and audit committee on voluntary disclosure: a meta-analysis’. Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, forthcoming.

40

Klein, A. (2002). “Audit Committee, Board of Director Characteristics, and Earnings Management”. Journal of accounting and economics, 33(3), 375-400. Kochhar, R., David, P. (1996). “Institutional Investors and Firm Innovation: A Test of Competing Hypotheses”. Strategic Management Journal, 17(1), 73‑84. Konishi, N., Ali, M. M. (2007). “Risk reporting of Japanese companies and its association with corporate characteristics”. International Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Performance Evaluation, 4(3), 263‑285. Kothari, S., Sloan R., (1992). “Information in prices about future earnings: implications for earnings response coefficients”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 15, 143–171. Kravet T.D, Muslu V. (2013) “Textual Risk Disclosures and Investors’ Risk Perceptions”. Review of Accounting Studies, 18(4), 1088-1122. Krippendorff, K. (2010). “Krippendorff's alpha”. In N. Salkind (Ed.), Encyclopedia of research design. (pp. 669-674). Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications, Inc. Krippendorff, K., (2004). “Content Analysis: An Introduction to Its Methodology”. Second ed. Sage, Beverly Hills. Lagoarde-Segot, T., Lucey, B. M. (2008). “The Capital Markets of the Middle East and North African Region: Situation and Characteristics”. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 44 (5), 68‑81. Lakhal, F. (2005). “Voluntary earnings disclosures and corporate governance: Evidence from France”, Review of Accounting and Finance, 4(3), 64-85. Lakhal, F. (2006). « Les publications volontaires des résultats et le comportement des analystes financiers en France ». 27ème Congrès de L’AFC. Available on the internet at http://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00558062

Laksmana, I. (2008). “Corporate Board Governance and Voluntary Disclosure of Executive Compensation Practices”. Contemporary Accounting Research, 25(4), 1147‑1182. Larcker, D. F., Richardson, S. A., Tuna, I. (2007). “Corporate governance, accounting outcomes, and organizational performance”. The Accounting Review, 82(4), 963-1008. Larcker, D. F., Rusticus, T. O. (2010). “On the use of instrumental variables in accounting research”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 49(3), 186‑205. Leftwich, R. W., Watts R. L., Zimmerman J. L. (1981): “Voluntary Corporate Disclosure: The Case of Interim Reporting”. Journal of Accounting Research, 19(3), 50-77. Lehn, K., Patro, S., Zhao, M. (2007). “Governance indexes and valuation: Which causes which?” Journal of Corporate Finance, 13, 907–928. Lichtenberg, F R., Pushner, G. M., (1994). "Ownership structure and corporate performance in Japan," Japan and the World Economy, 6(3), 239-261. Linsley, P., Shrives, P., (2006) “Risk reporting: A study of risk disclosure in the annual reports of UK companies”. The British Accounting Review, 38(4), 387–404. Loderer, C., Martin K., (1997), “Executive Stock Ownership and Performance: Tracking Faint Traces”, Journal of Financial Economics, 45, 223−255 Lundholm, R. J., Myers L. A., (2002) “Bringing the future forward: the effect of disclosure on the return-earnings relation”. Journal of Accounting Research, 40 (3): 809–39. Luo, Y. (2005), "How does globalization affect corporate governance and accountability? A perspective from MNEs". Journal of International Management, 11, 19-41. Mak, Y.T., Li, Y., (2001). “Determinants of corporate ownership and board structure: evidence from Singapore”. Journal of Corporate Finance, 7, 235–256. Makhija, A.K., Patton, J.M., (2004). “The impact of firm ownership structure on voluntary disclosure: Empirical evidence from Czech annual reports”. Journal of Business, 77, 457-492. Marshall, A. P., Weetman P., (2007). “Modelling transparency in disclosure: the case of foreign exchange risk management”. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 34(5 & 6), 705– 739. 41

McNally, (2011), “Corporate Governance: A Growing Concern in the MENA Region”. Available on internet at www.menacitylawyers.com Mehran, H., (1995), “Executive Compensation Structure, Ownership and Firm Performance”, Journal of Financial Economics, 38, 163−184. Miihkinen A. (2012) “What drives quality of firm risks disclosure? : the impact of a national disclosure standard and reporting incentives under IFRS”. The International Journal of Accounting, 47 (4), 437-468 Miihkinen, A. (2013). “The Usefulness of Firm Risk Disclosures under Different Firm-Riskiness, Investor-Interest, and Market Conditions”. Advances in International Accounting, 29(2): 312331. Mitton, T. (2002). “A cross-firm analysis of the impact of corporate governance on the East Asian financial crisis”. Journal of financial economics, 64(2), 215-241. Mohobbot, A. (2005). “Corporate risk reporting practices in annual reports of Japanese companies”. Japanese Journal of Accounting, 16(1), 113-133. Mokhtar E.S., Mellett H., (2013) "Competition, corporate governance, ownership structure and risk reporting". Managerial Auditing Journal, 28 (9), 838 – 865. Nitm, C. G., Lindop, S., and Thomas, D. A. (2013). “Corporate governance and risk reporting in South Africa: a study of corporate risk disclosures in the pre- and post-2007/2008 global financial crisis period”. International Review of Financial Analysis, 30: 363-383. OECD (2012), “The Role of MENA Stock Exchanges in Corporate Governance”. OECD Publishing, Paris, France. O’sullivan, N. (2000). “The impact of board composition and ownership on audit quality: evidence from large UK companies”. The British Accounting Review,32(4), 397-414. Oliveira, J., Rodrigues, L. L., and Craig, R. (2011). “Risk-related disclosures by non-finance companies Portuguese practices and disclosure characteristics”. Managerial Auditing Journal, 26(9), 817-839. Petra, S. T. (2007). “The effects of corporate governance on the informativeness of earnings”. Economics of Governance, 8(2), 129-152. Piotroski, J. D., Roulstone D. T. (2004), “The Influence of Analysts, Institutional Investors, and Insiders on the Incorporation of Market, Industry, and Firm-Specific Information into Stock Prices”, The Accounting Review, 79, 1119–51. Rose, C. (2007). “Does female board representation influence firm performance? The Danish evidence.” Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15, 404‐413. Saidi, N. (2011). “Corporate governance in the GCC: What has been done and what remains”. Qatar Business Review, 11-13. Sánchez-Ballesta, J. P. García-Meca, E. (2007), “Ownership Structure, Discretionary Accruals and the Informativeness of Earnings”. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15: 677–691. Sarikhani, M., Ebrahimi, M. (2011). “Corporate Governance and Earnings Informativeness: Evidence from Iran”. International Research Journal of Finance & Economics; 65, 43-50. Schleicher T., Hussainey K., Walker M. (2007) “Loss firms’ annual report narratives and share price anticipation of earnings”. The British Accounting Review, 39,153 – 171 Shleifer, A., Vishny, R. W. (1997). “A survey of corporate governance”. The journal of finance, 52(2), 737-783. Singh, M., Mathur, I. and Gleason, K. (2004), “Governance and performance implications of diversification strategies: evidence from large US firms”. Financial Review, 39, 489-526. Slovin, M. B., Sushka M. E. (1993). Ownership concentration, corporate control activity, and firm value: Evidence from the death of inside block holders. Journal of Finance, 48: 1293– 1321.

42

Solomon, J., Solomon, A., Norton, S., Josef, N. (2000), “A conceptual framework for corporate risk disclosure emerging from the agenda for corporate governance reforms”, British Accounting Review, 32(4), 447-78. Taylor, G., Tower, G., Zahn, M.V.D., Neilson, J. (2008), “Corporate governance determinants on Australian resource companies’ financial instrument disclosure practices”, Asian Review of Accounting, 16(1), 56-73. Tihanyi, L., Johnson, R. A., Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A. (2003). ‘Institutional ownership differences and international diversification: the effects of boards of directors and technological opportunity’. Academy of Management Journal, 46, 195–211. Turki A., N. Ben Sedrine, (2012) “Ownership Structure, Board Characteristics and Corporate Performance in Tunisia”. International Journal of Business and Management, 7(4), 121-132. Useem, M. (1996) “Investor Capitalism: How Money Managers Are Changing the Face of Corporate America”. New York: Basic Books/HarperCollins. Vafeas, N. (2000). “Board structure and the informativeness of earnings”. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 19(2), 139-160. Vandemele, S., Vergauwen, P., Michiels, A. (2009), “Management risk reporting practices and their determinants: a study of Belgian listed firms”, Working paper available on internet at: https://doclib.uhasselt.be/dspace/handle/1942/9392. Velury, U., Jenkins, D. S. (2006). “Institutional ownership and the quality of earnings”. Journal of Business Research, 59(9), 1043-1051. Vishny R. Shleifer A. (1986) “Large Shareholders and Corporate Control”. Journal of Political Economy, 94(3), 461–88. Walsh, J. P., Seward, J. K. (1990). “On the efficiency of internal and external corporate control mechanisms”. Academy of Management Review, 15(3), 421-458. Wang, M., Hussainey, K. (2013) “Voluntary forward-looking statements driven by corporate governance and their value relevance”. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 32 (3), 2649. Warfield, T.D., Wild, J.J., Wild, K.L., (1995). “Managerial ownership, accounting choices, and informativeness of earnings”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 20, 61-91. Watts, R., Zimmerman J., (1986). “Positive Accounting Theory”. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Winship, C., Morgan, S. L. (1999). “The estimation of causal effects from observational data”. Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 659–706. Xu, X., Wang, Y. (1999). “Ownership structure and corporate governance in Chinese stock companies”. China economic review, 10(1), 75-98. Yeo, G. H., Tan, P., Ho, K. W., Chen, S. S. (2002). “Corporate ownership structure and the informativeness of earnings”. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 29(7-8), 10231046. Yu, J. (2011) “Stock Price Informativeness and Corporate Governance: An International Study”. International Review of Finance, 11 (4), 477–514 Zhang, X., Taylor, D., Qu, W., Judith, O. (2013). “Corporate risk disclosures: Influence of institutional shareholders and audit committee”. Corporate Ownership and Control, 10(4), 341-353.

43

APPENDIX A: Risk disclosure categories adopted from Linsley and Shrives (2006) Customer Satisfaction Operations Risk Product Development Efficiency And Performance Sourcing Stock Obsolescence And Shrinkage Product And Service Failure Environmental Health And Safety Brand Name Erosion Leadership And Management Empowerment Risk Outsourcing Performance Incentives Change Readiness Communications Information Processing And Technology Risk Integrity Access Availability Infrastructure Management And Employee Fraud Integrity Risk Ilegal Acts Reputation Environmental Scan Strategic Risk Industry Business Portfolio Competitors Pricing Valuation Planning Life Cycle Performance Measurement Regulatory

44

107 - Nejia Moumen.pdf

Page 1 of 44. 1. Corporate governance and the informativeness of risk disclosure: evidence from MENA emerging markets. Abstract: Our paper examines whether corporate governance characteristics influence firms' decision to. disclose informative risk information voluntarily. Our sample includes 320 listed firms in nine.

2MB Sizes 2 Downloads 83 Views

Recommend Documents

107.it.pdf
che permette di assemblare in modo diverso i rilevatori, e. nell'esecuzione di ... 3D-Computing, Inc. 900 Hideaway Pl, DeSoto, TX 75115 ([email protected]). 2.

ITU-T G.107
ensure that users will be satisfied with end-to-end transmission performance. The primary ...... Figure A.2 − Comparison of R versus STMR for the current and the previous .... (which was provided in Annex C of the 2005 version of this Recommendatio

107.pdf
the U.S since 1976, while PET, which was invented [2] half a .... South (NEWS) connections are implemented on IBM PC. boards or .... Displaying 107.pdf.

גליון 107.pdf
"פתאום קם אדם ומתחיל ללכת". ד"ר בת-אל הלמר. דואר תנועה. ד"ר יוסף דלין. רשימת מסמכי מדיניות והנחיות. מטעם המפקח הארצי על התעבורה. PPP - סיכום מחקר

107.pdf
C. Key innovation of the synergistic combination of A and B. 1. The 3D-FlowTM parallel-processing architecture allows the. execution of complex algorithms with ...

107.PDF
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. 107.PDF. 107.

GO Ms. No. 107 - balusapa
Apr 7, 2010 - According to Rule 51 of Andhra Pradesh Civil Services (Travelling. Allowance) Rules, 1996 "No journey is reckoned as a journey on tour that does not reach a point outside a radius of more than eight kilometers from headquarters. But a.

107-1393902545.pdf
The intensity of pain between these two groups were compared in the. latent phase (cervix dilated 3-4cm), active phase (cervix dilated 5-7cm) and transitional ...

GO Ms. No. 107 - balusapa
Apr 7, 2010 - in the Andhra Pradesh Gazette. Copy to the General Administration (Spl.B) Department. // FORWARDED :: BY ORDER //. SECTION OFFICER.

16-07-107. REGIONAL WRITESHOP ON CONTEXTUALIZATION ...
REGIONAL WRITESHOP ON CONTEXTUALIZATION AND LOCALIZA.pdf. 16-07-107. REGIONAL WRITESHOP ON CONTEXTUALIZATION AND LOCALIZA.pdf.

Emerald_SP-V008_4 81..107
news, conference talk and conversational narration) was annotated both for ...... typology of intonation units (1994: 63–64), we will call them regulatory units.

DEPARTMENT ORDER NO. 107 .pdf
standards and guidelines prescribed by the Civil Service. Commission; Provided that no official or employee in the. local government shall suffer any diminution ...

MINISTRY ORDER NO. 107 .pdf
Page 1 of 1. Republic of the Philippines. MINISTRY 'OF `FINANCE. Office of the Minister. Manila. OFFICE OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT FINANCE. MINISTRY ORDER NO. / A. October 14, 100. SUBJECT SUB-CLASSIFICATION OF MUNICIPALITIES IN THE PROVINCE OF. NEGROS OCCI

man-107\bengali-boudi-golpo.pdf
There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying... Download. Connect more apps... Try one of the apps below to open or edit this item. man-107\bengali-boudi-golpo.pdf. man-107\bengali-boudi-golpo.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main me

20 107 10 article final.pmd
grow them profitably as intercrop in coconut and get additional revenue from their coconut garden. ... as intercrop gave extra income in coconut groves.

man-107\moto-guzzi-california.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. Retrying... Whoops! There was a problem previewing this document. Retrying.

man-107\bengali-boudi-golpo.pdf
File name : bengali boudi golpo.pdf ... After knowing this extremely easy way to check out as well as get this ... Merely prepare few time as well as web links to.

Southern highbush blueberry plant named 'FL05-107'
Sep 8, 2009 - Notice: Subject to any disclaimer, the term of this. 'FLQS'IOT is a new 5911mm highbush blueberry Plant dis' patent is extended or adjusted ...

Boletim SBI 107-1.pdf
relações filogenéticas do grupo. O professor Naércio Aquino Menezes. Museu de Zoologia da Universidade de São Paulo. Page 3 of 23. Boletim SBI 107-1.pdf.

man-107\sxy-viaeo.pdf
LIST EBOOK RELATED TO SXY VIAEO PDF. Page 3 of 5. man-107\sxy-viaeo.pdf. man-107\sxy-viaeo.pdf. Open. Extract. Open with. Sign In. Main menu.

MINISTRY ORDER NO. 107 .pdf
... able for salaries and wages, representation allowances, admin- istrative aids ... Retrying... MINISTRY ORDER NO. 107 .pdf. MINISTRY ORDER NO. 107 .pdf.

DM-TFT35-107 Datasheet.pdf
Jun 13, 2014 - Flash Interface SPI (single). Flash size 32 Mega Bit (4 Mega Byte). Page 3 of 10. DM-TFT35-107 Datasheet.pdf. DM-TFT35-107 Datasheet.pdf.

Math 107 Course Syllabus
class and count for 5% of your grade. Additional Homework. These questions are ... 7.4 Arc Length and Surfaces of Revolution. 7, 13, 37. 3-7, 11 - 25, 31, 37 - 45.