Does In‡ation Adjust Faster to Aggregate Technology Shocks than to Monetary Policy Shocks? LUIGI PACIELLO* Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance, Rome September 2009 Abstract This paper studies U.S. in‡ation adjustment speed to aggregate technology shocks and to monetary policy shocks in a Bayesian VAR model with a large number of macroeconomic variables. According to the model estimated on the 1960-2007 sample, in‡ation adjusts much faster to aggregate technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. These results are robust to di¤erent identi…cation assumptions and measures of aggregate prices. However, by separately estimating the model over the pre- and post-1980 periods, this paper further shows that in‡ation adjusts much faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks in the post-1980 period, but not in the pre-1980 period. This evidence challenges existing models of sticky prices.

JEL Classi…cation: E31, E4, C11, C3 Keywords: Bayesian VAR, price responsiveness, monetary policy shocks, technology shocks

*

Email: [email protected]. Mailing address: EIEF, Via dei Due Macelli, 73, 00187

Roma. This paper is a revised version of Chapter I in my PhD dissertation at Northwestern University. I thank Martin Eichenbaum, Giorgio Primiceri and Mirko Wiederholt for invaluable comments and advice. I am also grateful to Francesco Lippi and Stefano Neri as well as seminar participants at Northwestern University, EIEF and MONCASCA workshop.

1

Introduction

This paper investigates whether U.S. in‡ation adjusts faster to aggregate technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. Assessing the speed of in‡ation adjustment to di¤erent types of shocks is an important task in macroeconomics, not only to establish the main sources of business cycle ‡uctuations, but also to understand the way di¤erent shocks transmit through the economy and to distinguish among available models. In fact, Altig, Christiano, Eichenbaum and Linde (2005) and Dupor, Han and Tsai (2009) have recently shown that DSGE models of sticky prices have a hard time jointly explaining in‡ation responses to technology and monetary policy shocks. Technology and monetary policy shocks are particularly important as these shocks account together for a large fraction of business cycle ‡uctuations.1 In this paper I document in‡ation adjustment to technology and monetary policy shocks, using a Bayesian VAR (BVAR) model with a large number of macroeconomic indicators and with standard Litterman priors, estimated on the U.S. economy from 1960 to 2007. This paper contributes to the existing literature on several dimensions. First, this paper shows that in‡ation adjusts much faster to aggregate technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks in the post-1980 period, i.e. the period associated to Volcker and Greenspan at the helm of the Federal Reserve, but not in the pre-1980 period. In fact, in the pre-Volcker period in‡ation adjusts faster to monetary policy shocks than to technology shocks. In particular, in‡ation adjustment speed has increased to both types of structural shocks in the Volcker-Greenspan period relatively to the pre-Volcker period, but it has increased much more to technology shocks. Second, on the methodological side, this paper estimates impulse responses to both technology and monetary policy shocks in a relatively larger VAR model than previous studies.2 Moreover, the paper shows results about in‡ation adjustment 1

See, for intance, Smets and Wouters (2007). Recently Banbura, Giannone and Reichlin (2007) have shown that BVAR models including a large number of variables achieve relatively accurate forecasts and improve the structural analysis to 2

1

speed are robust to several identi…cation assumptions of the structural shocks. This is important as identi…cation of monetary policy and technology shocks through shortand long-run restrictions as in Altig, et al. (2005) have recently been questioned by part of the macroeconomic literature.3 In addition, the paper takes a more systematic approach at measuring in‡ation adjustment speed to technology and monetary policy shocks than previous studies, by using a measure of in‡ation persistence proposed by Cogley, Primiceri and Sargent (2009). Third, I show that in‡ation adjustment speed to both technology and monetary policy shocks is faster when in‡ation is measured through the producer price index than through the GDP de‡ator and the consumer price index. This evidence is consistent with microeconomic studies showing that intermediate goods have a higher frequency of price adjustment than more …nished goods.4 However, wether in‡ation adjusts faster to technology or to monetary policy shocks is independent of the measure of aggregate prices. Finally, I evaluate the ability of the New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) to match in‡ation responses to the two shocks in the two subsamples. Conditional on impulse responses from the BVAR, I …nd that the NKPC has particularly hard time matching the fast response of in‡ation to technology shocks in the Volcker-Greenspan period. This is not the …rst paper studying in‡ation responses to technology and monetary policy shocks in the context of VARs. Altig et al. (2005), Edge, Laubach and Williams (2003) and Dupor, et al. (2009) have recently estimated a structural VAR of the U.S. economy in the post second World War period, and found that in‡ation responds much faster to aggregate technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. Moreover, these monetary policy shocks. The importance of conditioning on a large information set when identifying monetary policy shocks has also been shown in frameworks related to factor analysis by Bernanke, Boivin, and Eliasz (2005) and Giannone, Reichlin, and Sala (2004). 3 See the reference list in Erceg, et al. (2005) for most of the relevant references regarding identi…cation of technology shocks. See Faust (1998) and references therein regarding identi…cation of monetary policy shocks. 4 See Nakamura and Steinsson (2008).

2

authors have argued that standard DSGE models with nominal rigidities have a hard time matching in‡ation adjustment to both technology and monetary policy shocks. This paper contributes to this literature by investigating in‡ation adjustment speed in the pre- and post-1980 periods. This analysis provides useful guidance for future research trying to reconcile existing DSGE models with in‡ation dynamics predicted by the VARs. Moreover, this paper employes a larger VAR than previous studies, has a more systematic approach at measuring in‡ation adjustment speed, and assesses robustness of …ndings against di¤erent identi…cation assumptions. In a related literature, Gali, Lopez-Salido and Valles (2003) and Boivin and Giannoni (2006) have shown that, in the Volcker-Greenspan era, in‡ation responsiveness has decreased to technology and monetary policy respectively. These authors have argued that the di¤erent behavior of in‡ation in response to the two shocks is to be attributed to the improvement of the FED performance at stabilizing prices in the last decades. This paper contributes to this literature by estimating in‡ation responses to both technology and monetary policy shocks, in the pre-Volcker and in the Volcker-Greenspan periods. Results from this study allow to compare in‡ation dynamics both across time and across di¤erent structural shocks. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the BVAR model, the data, the prior and the identi…cation assumptions, and derives impulse responses to aggregate technology and monetary policy shocks in the whole sample. Section 3 assesses subsample stability of results. Section 4 assesses robustness of …ndings against the main assumptions behind the procedure adopted in the paper. Section 5 interprets results through a NKPC. Section 6 concludes.

3

2

The benchmark BVAR model

This section describes the baseline empirical model consisting of a SVAR for an ndimensional vector of variables, Yt . The SVAR model is given by A0 Y t =

+ A1 Y t

1

+ ::: + Ap Yt

p

where Yt = (y1;t y2;t :::yn;t )0 is the set of time-series at period t, a vector of constants, A0 ; A1 ;..Ap are n

(1)

+ et ; =(

1

2

:::

n)

is

n matrices of structural parameters, p is a

non-negative integer, and et is an n-dimensional Gaussian white noise with unitary covariance matrix, E fet e0t g = I; representing structural shocks. The reduced form VAR model associated to (1) is given by Yt = c + B1 Yt

1

+ B2 Yt

2

+ ::: + Bp Yt

p

(2)

+ ut ;

where c = A0 1 ; Bs = A0 1 As for s = 1; ::p; and ut = A0 1 et : It follows that 0

E fut u0t g = A0 1 A0 1 : Following Banbura, Giannone and Reichlin (2007), Yt includes a relatively large number of macroeconomic variables. Therefore model (2) is estimated using a Bayesian VAR approach to overcome the curse of dimensionality. This approach consists in imposing prior beliefs on the parameters of (2). These priors are set according to the standard practice which builds on Litterman (1986)’s suggestions, which are often referred to as Minnesota priors. According to these priors, Yt is assumed to evolve according to Yt = c + diag ( 1 ; ::::;

n ) Yt 1

(3)

+ ut ;

where the ith equation in (2) is centered around a random walk with drift if the ith element of Yt is highly persistent;

i

= 1; and around a white noise otherwise,

4

i

= 0.

In particular, prior beliefs are such that

E (Bs )ij

=

V (Bs )ij

=

8 <

i;

if i = j; s = 1

: 0; 2

s2

2 i ; 2 j

for i = 1; :::; n; j = 1; :::; n; s = 1; :::; p; and the matrix E ( ) = diag ( 21 ; ::::;

2 n) :

;

otherwise

The scale parameters

2 i

has prior expectation

are set equal to the variance of

the residual from a univariate autoregressive model of order p for the ith element of Yt : The hyper-parameter

governs the overall tightness of the prior distribution

around (3) : Next subsection describes choices of

and

the posterior distribution of B = (B1 ; ::::; Bp ; c)0 and

2.1

i:

Under these assumptions,

is Normal inverted-Wishart.5

Data and priors

Model (2) includes twenty-three U.S. macroeconomic indicators, among which there are four di¤erent indices of aggregate prices: GDP price de‡ator, consumer price index, producer price index and personal consumption expenditure de‡ator.6 This allows the study of the dynamics of di¤erent aggregate price indices within the same model. The time span is from January 1960 through June 2007. Model (2) is estimated on a quarterly frequency, and the number of lags p is set equal to 4. The model is speci…ed so that the vector Yt is stationary, ensuring that all the 5

See Appendix B for more details. The model includes: labor productivity (GDPQ/LBMNU), hours worked (LBMNU), the nominal interest rate (FYFF), the GDP price de‡ator (PGDP), the Standard and Poor’s stock price index (FSPCOM), the number of employees on non-farm payrolls (CES002), personal income (A0M051), real consumption (JQCR), real non-residential investments (IFNRER), real residential investments (JQIFRESR), industrial production (IPS10), capacity utilization (UTL11), unemployment rate (LHUR), housing starts (HSFR), the index of sensitive material prices (PSM99Q), the producer price index (PWFSA), the personal consumption expenditures price de‡ator (GDMC), the consumer price index (PUNEW), average hourly earnings (CES275), M1 monetary stock (FM1), M2 monetary stock (FM2), non-borrowed reserves (FMRRA) and total reserves (FMRNBA). 6

5

roots of the VAR polynomial lie outside the unit circle.7 In particular, all the highly persistent variables enter Yt in log-di¤erences with the exception of the federal funds rate.8 Given that persistent variables enter Yt in log-di¤erences, a white noise prior, i

= 0; is assumed for all variables but the federal funds rate. This choice of

( 1 ; :::;

n)

=

is consistent with Banbura, Giannone and Reichlin (2007) and Stock and

Watson (2005). Results of this paper are robust to di¤erent speci…cations of : Finally, the hyper-parameter

is chosen similarly to Banbura, Giannone and Reichlin (2007)

and set equal to 0:065:9

2.2

Identi…cation of the structural parameters

Identi…cation of (1) amounts to putting enough restrictions on the model to be able to recover A0 ; A1 ::; Ap and

given estimates of the reduced form parameters,

;

B1 ; :::; Bp and c: This is achieved, in the benchmark speci…cation of the model, by appealing to the combination of standard identi…cation assumptions for technology and monetary policy shocks. This choice has the advantage of making results easily comparable to the existing literature.10 First, it is assumed that only technology shocks may have a permanent e¤ect on the level of labor productivity, as originally proposed by Galí (1999). This restriction is satis…ed by a broad range of business cycle models under standard assumptions. In particular, let’s de…ne the matrix C

(I

B1

:::

Bp )

1

A0 1 ; and suppose that

labor-productivity growth is the ith element of vector Yt ; and that the technology shock is the j th element of vector et : It is assumed that all the elements of the ith row of C are zero but the one associated to the j th column. Second, similarly to Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999), it is assumed that 7

Stationarity of (2) is needed to implement the identi…cation scheme in the next sub-section. The twenty-three indicators are entered in Yt in levels, logarithms or log-di¤erences depending on the persistence of each indicator. See Appendix A for details on how each indicator is entered in Y. 9 The model includes a set of variables similar to Banbura, Giannone and Reichlin. Results are robust to di¤erent choices of : See Appendix C for more details on the choice of : 10 In section 4 I show that results are robust to di¤erent identi…cation assumptions. 8

6

monetary policy targets a policy instrument, St ; according to St = f (zt ) + !est ;

(4)

where zt is the information available to the central bank as of time t; ! is a constant and est is the monetary policy shock. Following the Bernanke-Blinder assumption, St is set equal to the 3-months average Federal Funds rate. Variables in Yt are divided in four subsets, Yt = (Xt ; St ; Zt ; Ft )0 : Similarly to the recursive assumption of Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999), it is assumed that variables in Xt ; mainly quantities and prices, may respond to monetary policy shocks, est ; with one period lag. It is also assumed that the FED targets the monetary policy instrument so that St is unresponsive to contemporaneous changes in Zt ; where Zt includes M1 and M2 monetary stocks as well as non-borrowed and total reserves.11 Ft is equal to the S&P stock price index and there is no short-run restriction on the relationship between Ft and the other variables in Yt .12 Finally, the column of A0 1 corresponding to the impact of monetary policy shocks on Yt is normalized so that monetary policy shocks are associated to a contemporaneous increase in the federal funds rate; the column of A0 1 corresponding to the impact of technology shocks is normalized so that such shocks are associated to a permanent increase in labor productivity.13 Under this set of assumptions the impulse responses of Yt to monetary policy and technology shocks are exactly identi…ed.14 11

Similarly to Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999), results are robust to using non-borrowed reserves, M1 or M2 as the monetary policy instrument, S: 12 This implies that the monetary policy instrument St is allowed to respond contemporaneously to Ft ; as well as Ft is allowed to respond contemporaneously to St : See Appendix D for details. 13 Results are robust to di¤erent normalization assumptions, and in particular to the likelihood preserving normalization proposed by Waggoner and Zha (2003). 14 See Appendix D for details.

7

2.3

Impulse responses

Impulse responses are generated according to the methodology proposed by Ramirez, Waggoner and Zha (2007). In particular, the model reduced-form parameters B1 ; :::; Bp and

are drawn from the estimated Normal inverted-Wishart posterior distribu-

tion. For each draw of B1 ; :::; Bp and

; the model structural-form parameters A0 ; :::;

Ap are computed according to the identi…cation assumptions above. Given the structural parameters, the impulse responses of Yt to a one standard deviation technology shock and to a one standard deviation monetary policy shock are computed for each draw.15 [Figures 1-4 about here] Figure 1 plots the median impulse responses to aggregate technology and monetary policy shocks, and the associated 68 and 90 percent con…dence intervals, of in‡ation computed from the GDP price de‡ator (PGDP), the consumer price index (PUNEW), the personal consumption expenditure de‡ator (PCEPI) and the producer price index (PWFSA). Figure 2 plots the impulse responses of some key variables such as the federal funds rate, GDP, PGDP-in‡ation and labor productivity. Figures 3 and 4 plot the impulse responses of the remaining macroeconomic indicators of the model. Given the focus on in‡ation adjustment, this paper only discusses results about price impulse responses. However, the estimated impulse responses of the other variables in Y are consistent with results obtained in previous studies.16 From the analysis of impulse responses we can draw the following conclusions. First, in‡ation is much more responsive to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. In particular, the median in‡ation response to a monetary policy shock has its peak about three years after the shock, and it is not statistically di¤erent from zero for the …rst two years. In contrast, in‡ation response to a technology shock has 15

Results are based on 5,000 draws and are robust to larger number of draws. See for instance Francis and Ramey (2005), Altig, Christiano, Eichenbaum and Linde (2005), Galì (1999). 16

8

its peak in the period of impact of the shock, and monotonically converges towards zero. Second, the shape and the dynamic of in‡ation responses do not change much across di¤erent measures of aggregate price. For a given shock, either to technology or monetary policy, the median responses of the consumer price index, the GDP de‡ator, the personal consumption expenditure de‡ator are very similar both in terms of magnitude and in terms of dynamics. However, producer price index in‡ation is relatively more responsive to both types of shocks than the other measures of prices. This evidence is consistent with microeconomic studies showing that intermediate goods have a higher frequency of price adjustment than …nished goods.17

2.4

Measuring in‡ation adjustment speed

In‡ation adjustment speed is measured according to the methodology proposed by Cogley, Primiceri and Sargent (2008). Relative to other measures of in‡ation persistence, such as half-lives, this measure has the advantage of not relying on the monotonicity of responses. Given that in‡ation response to monetary policy shocks is characterized by a hump-shape dynamic, this property is very appealing. In particular, in‡ation persistence to shock i, j periods after the shock, is measured as

rj;i

j X

2 j;i

s=0

1

1 X

:

(5)

2 j;i

s=0

According to this measure, in‡ation is weakly persistent when the e¤ects of shocks decay quickly, and it is strongly persistent when they decay slowly. When the e¤ects of shock i die quickly, rj;i is pushed close to zero for relatively small j. But when the e¤ects of shock i decay slowly, rj;i is pushed closer to one. Thus, for small or medium 17

See Nakamura and Steinsson (2008).

9

0, a small rj;i signi…es high adjustment speed, and a large rj;i low adjustment

j

speed. Figure 5 displays scatter plots for the values of rj;i obtained from the posterior draws of the structural parameters of the BVAR model; rj;i is evaluated at one year horizon of responses, i.e. j = 4.18 Each plot is associated to one of the four measures of prices. The vertical axis of each plot reports values of rj;i associated to the monetary policy shock, and the horizontal axis values of rj;i associated to the technology shock. By de…nition of rj;i ; draws above (below) the 45 degree line mean that in‡ation adjustment is faster (slower) to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. [Figure 5 about here] In Figure 5, the vast majority of draws is above the 45 degree line for all measures of prices. This means that the posterior probability that the price level adjusts faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks is relatively high across all four measures of aggregate price level. Tables 1 and 2 report the median, 16th and 84th percentiles of the posterior distribution of rj;i for the technology and the monetary policy shocks respectively, evaluated at j = 2; 4; 8; 12; 16.

[Tables 1-2 about here] From these tables we can draw the following conclusions. First, in‡ation adjustment speed to technology shocks is much faster than to monetary policy shocks, independently of the horizon of the response at which we measure rj;i ; and independently of the measure of aggregate prices. For instance, two years after the shock, GDP de‡ator in‡ation has accomplished at the median about 80 percent of total adjustment to the technology shock, but only 20 percent of total adjustment to the monetary policy 18

Results are qualitatively similar for other horizon j.

10

shock.19 Second, the fact that in‡ation adjusts faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks is statistically robust. In particular, the fraction of draws in which in‡ation adjustment measured at 1 year horizon is faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks ranges between 93 percent for the GDP de‡ator and 96 percent for the consumer price index. Therefore, the posterior probability of such event is very high. Third, the producer price index is more responsive to both types of shocks than the other measures of aggregate prices. For instance, two years after the shock, the producer price index in‡ation has accomplished at the median about 93 percent of total adjustment to the technology shock, and 42 percent of total adjustment to the monetary policy shock.

3

Robustness analysis

This section investigates to what extent results from the benchmark BVAR model are robust to several features of the identi…cation assumptions. While extensively adopted, identi…cation of monetary policy shocks through the recursive assumption of Christiano et al. (1999), and identi…cation of technology shocks through long-run restrictions as in Gali (1999) have been recently criticized by part of the macroeconomic literature. In fact, zero restrictions on the contemporaneous responses of economic variables to monetary policy shocks might be particularly restrictive when frequency of observations is quarterly.20 Furthermore, long-run restrictions on the response of economic variables to technology shocks might give biased results in a VAR with a …nite number of lags.21 In order to address both issues, in this section I identify the two structural shocks of interest through a di¤erent method relying on sign restrictions of impulse responses. 19 Notice that the fraction of in‡ation adjustment accomplished j quarters after the shock is measured by 1 rj;i : 20 See Faust (1998) and references therein regarding identi…cation of monetary policy shocks. 21 See the reference list in Erceg, et al. (2005) for most of the relevant references regarding identi…cation of technology shocks.

11

Furthermore, as additional robustness exercises, I estimate the BVAR model at the monthly frequency and I consider a di¤erent identi…cation assumption of technology shocks based on a Solow-residual measure of quarterly total factor productivity growth. The insights from these exercises reinforce the results obtained in the previous sections.22

3.1

Identi…cation through sign restrictions

This method has been originally proposed by Faust (1998) and then applied by Uhlig (2006) to the identi…cation of monetary policy shocks, and by Dedola and Neri (2007) to the identi…cation of technology shocks. These sign restrictions are robust in the sense that they are consistent with a wide range of DSGE models.23 From a Bayesian point of view, sign restrictions amount to attributing probability zero to reducedform parameters giving rise to impulse responses which contravene the restrictions. To the extent that these restrictions do not lead to over-identi…cation, they impose no constraint on the reduced form of the VAR. Apart from the di¤erent identi…cation assumptions, the rest of the estimation procedure is as in the benchmark speci…cation of the model. I adopt the algorithm proposed by Ramirez, Waggoner and Zha (2007) to compute the posterior distribution of impulse responses.24 Sign restrictions on the impulse responses to monetary policy shocks are similar to the ones adopted by Uhlig (2006), while sign restrictions on the impulse responses to technology shocks are similar to the ones adopted by Dedola and Neri (2006).25 Intuitively, this method distinguishes the two types of shocks on the basis of the facts 22

In what folloes I will report impulse responses of output, Federal Funds rate, in‡ation and labor productivity. The other variables are omitted to save on space. 23 Canova, Gambetti and Pappa (2007), Dedola and Neri (2006) provide detailed examples of standard DSGE models where these restrictions hold. Moreover, these restrictions are consistent with impulse responses estimated in a DSGE model by Smets and Wouters (2007). I refer to these authors for more details. 24 For more details see Ramirez, Waggoner and Zha (2007) pp. 38-40. 25 I refer to these authors for a discussion of the ability of these restrictions to distinguish technology from monetary policy shocks as well as from other shocks.

12

that: i) permanent technology shocks have a more persistent impact on quantities than monetary policy shocks; ii) quantities and prices move in opposite directions following a technology shock, but move in the same direction following a monetary policy shock; iii) monetary policy shocks are associated to changes in monetary aggregates and interest rates. Sign restrictions are reported in more details in Table 7.26 [Figure 6 about here] Figure 6 plots the impulse responses of output, Federal Funds rate, in‡ation and labor productivity. Although the identi…cation scheme is very di¤erent from the one adopted under the benchmark speci…cation, impulse responses to the two types of shocks are similar to the ones reported in section 2. In particular, in‡ation response is much faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks.

3.2

A Solow-residual based identi…cation for technology

As an additional robustness check on identi…cation of technology shocks, this subsection adopts a di¤erent identi…cation assumption for technology shocks, relying on a Solow-residual measure of quarterly total factor productivity (FTFP) growth estimated by Fernald (2007). Fernald’s quarterly measure explicitly accounts for variable capital utilization and labor hoarding.27 The FTFP series is added to Y and the posterior distribution of (B; ) is estimated as in section 2. Di¤erently from section 2, in this subsection the identifying assumption is that a technology shock is the only shock a¤ecting FTFP in the long-run, while the long-run response of labor productivity is unrestricted. Relative to the identi…cation assumptions of section 2, the advantage 26

Results are robust to di¤erent speci…cations of sign restrictions, and in particular to di¤erent assumptions about the number of periods they are expected to hold for. 27 The growth rate of FTFP is given by: ln(F T F P ) =

ln(GDP )

(

ln(K) +

ln(Z))

(1

) ( ln(QH) +

ln(E)) ;

where Z is capital utilization, K is capital input, E is labor e¤ort per (quality-adjusted) hour worked, Q is labor quality (i.e., a labor composition adjustment), and H is hours worked.

13

of this procedure is that, by explicitly assuming an aggregate production function, it directly estimates total factor productivity growth.28 As long as the assumption about the aggregate production function holds at low frequencies, the model provides unbiased estimates of technology shocks. The remaining assumptions required to jointly identify the monetary policy shock are unchanged from section 2. [Figure 7 about here] Figure 7 plots technology shocks between 1961:II and 2007:II, estimated according both to the benchmark identi…cation scheme of section 2 and to the identi…cation scheme of this subsection. The time series of estimated technology shocks are very similar across the two identi…cation assumptions, and have a high correlation equal to 0.96. In fact, impulse responses are almost identical to the benchmark speci…cation and are therefore omitted. Statistics about ri;j computed under the identi…cation assumptions of this subsection are, both quantitatively and qualitatively, very similar to the ones obtained under the benchmark identi…cation scheme, and are therefore omitted.

3.3

Monthly data

The empirical literature investigating the responses of macroeconomic variables to monetary policy shocks often makes use of monthly frequency data. The advantage of using monthly data over quarterly data is that the benchmark identi…cation scheme of section 2 requires economic variables in the sub-vector Xt not to respond to monetary policy shocks only for a month instead of a quarter. Therefore, identi…cation of monetary policy shocks is less restrictive. The disadvantage is that some economic 28

This procedure has been originally applied by Christiano, Eichenbaum and Vigfusson (2004), suggesting there could be high frequency cyclical measurement error in Solow-residual based measures of total factor productivity, that the long-run restriction might clean out.

14

variables are measured only at the quarterly frequency, as for instance GDP.29 This section estimates model (2) at a monthly frequency. Quarterly interpolated time-series equivalents are used anytime the monthly frequency observations are unavailable.30 The number of lags, p; is set to 13. Data is available from January 1964 to June 2006. Apart from the frequency of the data, the estimation and identi…cation method is identical to the benchmark version of the model. [Figure 8 about here] Figure 8 plots the impulse responses to monetary policy and technology shocks. Impulse responses resemble the ones obtained at the quarterly frequency. In‡ation adjustment is faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. Therefore, results from the benchmark speci…cation are not a¤ected by the frequency of the data.

4

In‡ation adjustment speed and subsample stability

Monetary policy plays a central role in shaping in‡ation adjustment to di¤erent structural shocks. Boivin and Giannoni (2006) have documented that the impact of monetary policy shocks on the U.S. economy has became less e¤ective in the VolckerGreenspan period compared to the pre-Volcker one. The smaller impact of monetary policy shocks is particularly pronounced on in‡ation. These authors argue that, by responding more strongly to in‡ation expectations, monetary policy has stabilized the economy more e¤ectively in the last decades. Similarly, Galí, López-Salido and Vallés (2003) have found that the e¤ects of technology shocks on in‡ation di¤er drastically 29

GDP is necessary to identify the technology shocks under the benchmark identi…cation scheme. It is needed to compute a measure of labor productivity. 30 Variables unavailable at the monthly frequency are: real GDP, real non-residential and residential investments and GDP price de‡ator. Sims and Zha’s (2007) interpolated series are used instead. These series are constructed through the Chow-Lin interpolation method.

15

between the two periods. They also argue that monetary policy stabilization of prices is the main cause of the reduction in in‡ation persistence to technology shocks. While the papers above document the change in in‡ation responses to each type of shock, there is no evidence on wether the di¤erence in in‡ation adjustment speed between the two shocks has increased or decreased in the Volcker-Greenspan period compared to the pre-Volcker one. Does in‡ation adjust faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks in both subsamples? Is the di¤erence in in‡ation adjustment speed quantitatively similar in the two subsamples? Motivated by these questions, this section evaluates and compares in‡ation adjustment speed to the two shocks in the periods before and after Volcker’s tenure, i.e. 1960:1-1979:3 and 1979:42007:3.

[Figures 9-11 about here] Figures 9 and 10 display in‡ation impulse responses to technology and monetary policy shocks in the pre- and post- 1980 periods respectively. In‡ation response is very persistent to technology shocks in the …rst subsample, but adjusts very fast to such shocks in the second subsample. Similarly, in‡ation is more persistent to monetary policy shocks in the …rst subsample than in the second one. However, the change in the pattern of in‡ation response to monetary policy shocks over the two periods appears less dramatic than to technology shocks. These results hold through the di¤erent measures of aggregate prices. Figure 11 displays scatter plots for the values of rj;i obtained from the posterior draws of the structural parameters of the BVAR model in the 1960:1-1979:3 and 1979:4-2007:3 periods respectively; rj;i is evaluated at one year horizon of responses. These …gures clearly show that the relationship between in‡ation adjustment speed to the two di¤erent shocks has changed over time. In fact, in the 1960:1-1979:3 subsample, the majority of draws is below the 45 degree line, indicating that in‡ation adjusts faster to monetary policy shocks than to technology shocks. In particular, 16

according to rj;i ; the posterior probability that in‡ation adjusts faster to monetary policy shocks than to technology shocks ranges between 67 and 87 percent, depending on the measure of aggregate prices. In contrast, in the 1979:4-2007:3 subsample, the majority of draws is well above the 45 degree line, indicating that in‡ation adjusts faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. In particular, according to rj;i ; the posterior probability that in‡ation adjusts faster to monetary policy shocks than to technology shocks ranges between 89 and 95 percent, depending on the measure of aggregate prices. To better quantify in‡ation adjustment speed in the two subsamples, Tables 3-4 report the median, 16th and 84th percentiles of the posterior distribution of rj;i in the …rst subsample for the technology and the monetary policy shocks respectively. [Tables 3-4 about here] According to rj;i ; in the …rst subsample, in‡ation adjustment is relatively slow to both types of shocks. For instance, two years after the shock, in‡ation has accomplished only about half of overall adjustment to technology shocks, with median values of rj;i between 45 and 55 percent, depending on the measure of aggregate prices; over the same horizon, this statistic to monetary policy shocks ranges between 37 and 55 percent, being lowest for the producer price index and highest for the GDP de‡ator. It takes four years before in‡ation response accomplishes more than 80 percent of overall adjustment to both shocks. Tables 5-6 report the median, 16th and 84th percentiles of the posterior distribution of rj;i in the post-1980 subsample for the technology and the monetary policy shocks respectively. [Tables 5-6 about here] Comparing statistics in Tables 5-6 with the corresponding ones in Tables 3-4, I obtain the following results. First, in‡ation adjusts faster to both types of shocks in the

17

second subsample than in the …rst one. This is true independently of the evaluation horizon, j; and of the price index. Second, the increase in in‡ation adjustment speed has been larger for the consumer price index and for the producer price index than for the other indexes. Third, the increase in in‡ation adjustment speed in the second subsample has been much larger conditional on technology shocks than conditional on monetary policy shocks. For instance, in the post-1980 subsample, one year after the shock, the GDP de‡ator in‡ation has accomplished, at the median, 94 and 38 percent of overall adjustment to technology and monetary policy shocks respectively; in the pre-1980 subsample, these statistics are 15 and 30 percent respectively. According to the producer price index, one year after the shock, median in‡ation response has accomplished 98 and 77 percent of overall adjustment to technology and monetary policy shocks respectively in the second subsample; in the pre-1980 subsample, these statistics are 19 and 44 percent respectively.

5

Discussion of results

In‡ation responses to technology and monetary policy shocks display substantially di¤erent dynamics. Dupor, Han and Tsai (2009) have shown that standard DSGE models have a very hard time explaining the di¤erent dynamics of in‡ation to the two shocks. In addition, in‡ation responses have changed dramatically in the pre- and postVolcker periods. The latter is not a surprise as several authors have documented changes in the structure of the US economy in the last decades, and attributed at least partially these changes to shifts in monetary policy.31 This paper has …rst documented the fact that in‡ation adjusts much faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks in the post- Volcker period, while adjusts slightly faster to monetary policy shocks than to technology shocks in the pre31

In the speci…c case of in‡ation responses, see Galí, López-Salido and Vallés (2003) and Boivin and Giannoni (2006).

18

Volcker period. In this section, I illustrate the ability of the NKPC to account for the di¤erent in‡ation persistence to the two shocks and over the two periods, conditional on the path of other economic variables from the VAR. This study provides valuable information on what aspect of these models can be improved to match the behavior of in‡ation in response to technology and monetary policy shocks. Therefore, I consider the NKPC derived by Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (2005), where in‡ation dynamics,

t

=

t 1

t;

are given by

+ Et

t+1 (1

where xt is marginal cost of production, 1 1

is the frequency of price adjustment, and

t )(1

+ xt ; )

;

(6)

< 1 is the discount rate,

2 [0; 1] is price indexation to past

in‡ation. Model (6) de…nes the dynamics of

t

conditional on the path of marginal cost.

Similarly to Sbordone(2002, 2005) and Cogley and Sbordone (2008), dynamics of marginal cost are obtained from the VAR model, rather than modelling them within a DSGE framework. Therefore, responses of marginal cost st are obtained from a linear combination of responses of unit labor cost, st ; and Federal Funds rate, rt ; to the two shocks, xt = st + (1

) rt ;

where, relatively to Sbordone (2002), I also allow for marginal cost to depend on the interest rate in order to encompass models of limited participation as in Christiano et al. (2005).32 This methodology has the advantage that it doesn’t involve other maintained hypotheses about the structure of the economy, (for example, about household preferences or about wage- setting) in addition to the assumed model of pricing and supply behavior by …rms and identi…cation assumptions of the VAR. In addition, 32

See Sbordone (2002) for a derivation of the relationship between marginal cost and unit labor cost.

19

this approach allows to focus more on those aspects of existing price setting models that should be improved to match impulse responses predicted by the BVAR model. Given the focus of this section is evaluating the ability of the NKPC to explain in‡ation responses to the two shocks conditional on the path of the other variables, the methodology is appropriate. However, estimating a full ‡edged DSGE model would be more appropriate if one wanted to have more information on the interaction of the NKPC, and its structural parameters, with other equations of the DSGE, as in Dupor, et al. (2009). While this is interesting, it is outside the scope of this paper.

5.1

In‡ation responses in the NKPC

In order to obtain impulse responses from model (6) ; I have to choose the structural parameters

( ; ;

; ) : I set the discount factor to

the remaining parameters,

= 0:993, while I choose

; ; and ; so to minimize the weighted mean-square

distance of median in‡ation responses between the BVAR and the NKPC. I match impulse responses separately in the 1960:1-1979:3 and 1979:4:2007:3 samples. In each subsample, I …nd the set of parameters that …t impulse responses conditional on each type of shock, and compare responses to the ones obtained when I …t impulse :33

responses to both shocks under the same

[Figure 12 about here] Figure 12 plots in‡ation responses to the two shocks predicted by the NKPC, in the two subsamples. In the pre-Volcker sample, the NKPC fails to fully account for the hump-shape in in‡ation response to monetary policy shocks. This is also true when is set to …t exclusively such responses. Over the same period, the NKPC understates in‡ation response to technology shocks, which is more evident when

is set to …t

responses to both shocks contemporaneously. In the Volcker-Greenspan sample, the 33

This is similar to Altig et al. (2005) and Dupor et al. (2009). See appendix E for more details.

20

NKPC does a fairly good job at explaining in‡ation response to monetary policy shocks. In contrast, the model substantially fails at matching the fast response of in‡ation to technology shocks. These results suggest that, conditional on the path of variables estimated by the BVAR, the NKPC does a fairly good job at approximating in‡ation responses to monetary policy shocks, in particular in the Volcker-Greenspan period. However, in the post-Volcker period, the NKPC does much better at explaining in‡ation response to monetary policy shocks than to technology shocks. This implies that more e¤ort is required at improving such a model so to explain the di¤erent behavior of in‡ation to the two shocks, and in particular to technology shocks, in the last subsample. The fact that in‡ation responses to the two shocks have changed so much in the pre-Volcker and Volcker-Greenspan periods also suggests that monetary policy has in‡uenced price setting behavior in response to technology and monetary policy shocks. In the author view, exploring more in detail the link between price stabilization in monetary policy and price adjustment to di¤erent structural shocks is a promising avenue for future research.34 Moreover, these results are obtained conditional on the path of economic variables predicted by the BVAR. It would be interesting to evaluate the ability of the NKPC to explain in‡ation responses within a DSGE model over the two sub samples. Dupor et al. (2009) have done this exercise for the whole sample, but this paper suggests that in‡ation dynamics di¤er substantially in the pre- and post- 80 periods.

6

Concluding remarks

This paper answers the question of whether, by how much and how likely it is that U.S. in‡ation adjusts faster to aggregate technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. According to a BVAR model for the 1960-2007 sample, this paper …nds that U.S. 34

Paciello (2009) investigates the relationship between price responsiveness to di¤erent shocks and monetary policy.

21

in‡ation adjusts much faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. This paper also …nds that this result is robust to di¤erent identi…cation assumptions. However, when investigating more in detail over subsamples, this paper …nds that in‡ation adjusts faster to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks in the Volcker-Greenspan period, but the opposite is true in the pre-Volcker subsample. This result is due to the fact that in‡ation adjustment speed in the later subsample has increased much more to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. Gali, Lopez-Salido and Valles (2003) and Boivin and Giannoni (2006) have argued that the faster adjustment of in‡ation in response to technology and monetary policy shocks respectively is to be attributed to the improvement of the FED performance at stabilizing prices in the last decades. It remains to be shown wether existing DSGE models can also account for the fact that a more aggressive monetary policy on prices has a¤ected in‡ation adjustment speed to technology shocks more than to monetary policy shocks. Conditional on the path of variables predicted by the BVAR, the NKPC has a hard time explaining in‡ation response to technology shocks in the Volcker-Greenspan period. In a companion paper, Paciello (2009), I show that a model of price setting under imperfect information and endogenous attention allocation can provide an explanation for the di¤erent response of in‡ation to the two shocks under more aggressive monetary policy on price stability.

References [1] Altig, David, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde, (2005): ”Firm-Speci…c Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle,” NBER Working Paper No. 11034. [2] Banbura, M., D. Giannone and L. Reichlin (2007): ”Bayesian VARs with Large Panels,”CEPR DP6326.

22

[3] Bernanke, B., and Alan S. Blinder. (1992): ”The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary Transmission”. The American Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 4, pp. 901-921. [4] Bernanke, B., J. Boivin, and P. Eliasz (2005): ”Measuring Monetary Policy: A Factor Augmented Autoregressive (FAVAR) Approach,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 387-422. [5] Boivin, J. and Marc Giannoni (2006): ”Has Monetary Policy Become More Effective?”The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(3). [6] Boivin, J., Marc Giannoni and Ilian Mihov (2008): ”Sticky Prices and Monetary Policy: Evidence from Disaggregated U.S. Data,” Forthcoming American Economic Review. [7] Canova, F., Luca Gambetti and Evi Pappa. 2007."The Structural Dynamics of Output Growth and In‡ation: "Some International Evidence." The Economic Journal, 117 (March), C167–C191. [8] Chari, V.V. , P. J. Kehoe and E. R. McGrattan (2008): ”Are structural VARs with long-run restrictions useful in developing business cycle theory?”Forthcoming Journal of Monetary Economics. [9] Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans (1999): ”Monetary policy shocks: What have we learned and to what end?,” in Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. by J. B. Taylor, and M. Woodford, vol. 1, chap. 2, pp. 65-148. Elsevier. [10] Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans (2005): ”Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic E¤ects of a Shock to Monetary Policy”. Journal of Political Economy, 2005, vol. 113, no. 1.

23

[11] Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and R.Vigfusson (2004): ”What Happens After A Technology Shock?,”NBER Working Paper No. W9819. [12] Cogley, TimothyW., Giorgio Primiceri, and Thomas J. Sargent (2009): “In‡ation-Gap Persistence in the U.S.,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, forthcoming. [13] Dedola, L. and Stefano Neri. 2006. "What does a technology shock do? A VAR analysis with model-based sign restriction." Journal of Monetary Economics, 54 (2007) 512–549. [14] Del Negro, M. and Frank Schorfheide (2008): ”Forming Priors for DSGE Models (and How it A¤ects the Assessment of Nominal Rigidities)”, Forthcoming Journal of Monetary Economics. [15] Doan, T., R. Litterman, and C. A. Sims (1984): ”Forecasting and Conditional Projection Using Realistic Prior Distributions,”Econometric Reviews, 3, 1-100. [16] Dupor, Bill, Jing Han and Yi Chan Tsai (2007): ”What Do Technology Shocks Tells Us about the New Keynesian Paradigm?”. Forthcoming Journal of Monetary Economics. [17] Edge, Rochelle M., Laubach, Thomas and John C. Williams (2003): "The responses of wages and prices to technology shocks." Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2003-65. [18] Erceg, C., Guerrieri, L. and C. Gust, ”Can Long-Run Restrictions Identify Technology Shocks”Journal of the European Economic Association, vol. 3 (December 2005), pp. 1237-1278. [19] Faust, Jon (1998): ”The robustness of identi…ed VAR conclusions about money”. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy Volume 49, Pages 207244. 24

[20] Francis, Neville and Valerie A. Ramey (2005): ”Is the technology-driven real business cycle hypothesis dead? Shocks and aggregate ‡uctuations revisited.” Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 52(8), pages 1379-1399, November. [21] Galí, Jordi, (1999): ”Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?,” American Economic Review, 89(1), 249-271. [22] Galí, Jordi and Mark Gertler (1999): ”In‡ation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis”. Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 195-222. [23] Galí J., J. D. Lopez-Salido and J. Valles, (2003): ”Technology shocks and monetary policy: assessing the Feds performance,” Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 723743. [24] Ireland, Peter N. 2007. "Changes in the Federal Reserve’s In‡ation Target: Causes and Consequences," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Blackwell Publishing, vol. 39(8), pages 1851-1882, December. [25] Litterman, R. (1986): ”Forecasting With Bayesian Vector Autoregressions - Five Years of Experience,”Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 4, 25-38. [26] Nakamura, Emi, and Jón Steinsson (2008): ”Five Facts about Prices: A Reevaluation of Menu Costs Models”. Quarterly Journal of Economics. [27] Paciello, Luigi (2009): “Monetary Policy Activism and Price Responsiveness to Aggregate shocks under Rational Inattention.”EIEF discussion paper. [28] Ramirez, J. R., Daniel F. Waggoner and Tao Zha (2007): ”Markov-Switching Structural Vector Autoregressions: Theory and Application.” FRB of Atlanta Working Paper No. 2005-27.

25

[29] Sims, Christopher A. (1992): ”Interpreting the Macroeconomic Time Series Facts: the E¤ects of Monetary Policy”. European Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 36(5), pages 975-1000. [30] Smets, F. and Rafael Wouters. 2007. "Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach." American Economic Review, vol. 97(3), pages 586-606. [31] Stock, J. and Marc Watson (2002): ”Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why?” NBER Working Paper No. 9127. [32] Uhlig, Arald. 2006. "What are the e¤ects of monetary policy on output? Results from an agnostic identi…cation procedure." Journal of Monetary Economics, Volume 52, Issue 2, March 2005, Pages 381-419. [33] Waggoner D.F., and T. Zha (2003): ”Likelihood Preserving Normalization in Multiple Equation Models”. Journal of Econometrics, 114, 329-347.

26

Appendices A Data Mnemon

Series

Y=(X,S,Z,F)

GDPQ/LBMNU

Labor productivity

X

log

LBMNU

Index total hours worked

X

log

FYFF

INTEREST RATE: FEDERAL FUNDS

S

Level

PGDP

GDP price de‡ator

X

log

FSPCOM

Standard and Poor’s stock price index

F

log

CES002

Number of employees on non-farm payrolls

X

log

A0M051

Personal income (AR, BIL. CHAIN 2000 $)

X

log

JQCR

Real Personal Consumption Expenditures

X

log

IFNRER

Real non-residential investments

X

log

JQIFRESR

Real residential investments

X

log

IPS10

Industrial production

X

log

UTL11

Capacity utilization

X

Level

LHUR

Unemployment rate

X

Level

HSFR

Housing starts (NONFARM)

X

log

PCOM

Index of sensitive material prices

X

log

PWFSA

Producer price index

X

log

PCPEPI

Personal consumption expenditures price de‡ator

X

log

PUNEW

Consumer price index

X

log

CES275

Average hourly earnings

X

log

FM1

M1 monetary stock

Z

log

FM2

M2 monetary stock

Z

log

FMRRA

Non-borrowed reserves

Z

log

FMRNBA

Total reserves

Z

log

FTFP

Fernald’s (2007) TFP estimate

X

log

27

Units

The source of most of the data is the DRI Basic Economics Database, available on-line at Northwestern University. Output, GDP de‡ator, residential and nonresidential investments were obtained from the BEA website. Most data is available at a monthly frequency. Output, GDP de‡ator, residential and non-residential investments are not. When I estimate the model at the monthly frequency, I use Sims and Zha (2007) interpolated monthly series for these four time series. LBMNU is also not available at the monthly frequency. In the monthly frequency analysis, the latter is replaced by the BLS index for average weekly hours worked.

B Minnesota prior Let’s rewrite model (2) as a system of multivariate regressions: Y = X B + U ;

T n

T k k n

T n

where Y = (y1 ; :::yT )0 , X = (X1 ; ::::; XT )0 and with Xt = Yt0 1 ; :::; Yt0 p ; 1 ; U = (u1 ; :::; uT )0 ; B = (B1 ; ::::; Bp ; c)0 ; and k = np + 1: The prior beliefs are such that B and

have a Normal inverted Wishart distribution, according to which v iW (S0 ;

The prior parameters S0 ;

0 ; B0

and Bj

0)

and

0

v N (B0 ;

0) :

are chosen so that the coe¢ cients in B1 ; B2 ;..,

Bp ; denoted by (Bs )ij ; s = 1; ::p; i = 1; 2::; n; j = 1; 2; ::n; have prior expectations and variances given by

E (Bs )ij

=

V (Bs )ij

=

8 <

: 0; 2

and the matrix

i;

s2

if i = j; s = 1

;

otherwise

2 i ; 2 j

has prior expectation E ( ) = diag ( 21 ; ::::; 28

2 n) :

For details see

Kadiyala and Karlsson (1997). The scale parameters

2 i

are set equal to the variance

of the residual from a univariate autoregressive model of order p for the variable yi : The prior is implemented by adding T0 dummy observations, Y0 and X0 ; to Y and X respectively. It can be shown that this is equivalent to imposing a normal inverted1

Wishart prior with B0 = (X00 X0 ) and

0

= T0

k

X00 Y0 ;

= (X00 X0 )

0

1

X0 B0 )0 (Y0

; S0 = (Y0

X0 B0 )

1: It follows that the dummy-augmented VAR model is:

n

Y

= X

T

n

T

B + U ;

k k n

T

n

where T = T + T0 ; X = (X 0 ; X00 ) ; Y = (Y 0 ; Y00 )0 and U = (U 0 ; U00 )0 : To insure the existence of the prior expectation of ~j j

(n+3)=2

: The posterior distribution of (B; ) is a Normal inverted-Wishart: jY v iW (S ;

where B = (X 0 X ) =T

it is necessary to add an improper prior

1

and Bj ; Y v N (B ;

)

= (X 0 X )

X0 Y ;

1

; S = (Y

); X B )0 (Y

X B ) and

k + 2: See Banbura, Giannone and Reichlin (2007) for more details.

C Parameterization of Consider an n1

dimensional subset of Y . De…ne the in-sample mean squared

forecast error (MSFE) of the 1-step-ahead mean squared forecast as: ( ;m) M SF Ei

=

T

1 p

T X

1 t=p+1

( ;m)

y^i;t

2

yi;t

;

where i = 1; ::::; n1 indices the variable the MSFE is computed for, T is the length ( ;m)

of the sample, y^i;t

is the one-step-ahead forecast computed in model m with prior

parameterization equal to : This analysis studies three types of models, depending on the number of variables included in the analysis and the value of . The …rst model, m = 1; includes n1 variables and is estimated with a ‡at prior, 29

= 1: The

n1 variables considered are: labor-productivity, hours worked, GDP price de‡ator, Federal Funds rate, M2 money stock, commodity price index, capacity utilization and average hourly earnings of production workers. This set of variables is similar to the one adopted by other authors in the study of the response of the U.S. economy to monetary policy and aggregate technology shocks35 . The second model, m = 2; is the benchmark model. It includes all the n macroeconomic indicators and is estimated with the Minnesota prior described in the main text and depending on : The third model, m = 3; includes all the n variables and is estimated imposing the prior exactly, = 0: Following Banbura, Reichlin and Giannone (2007), I choose

in model m = 2

so to minimize the di¤erence in …t from model m = 1: = arg min z

where z =

1 n1

Pn1

n1 ( ;1) 1 X M SF Ei ; n1 i=1 M SF Ei(0;3)

(1;1)

M SF Ei i=1 M SF E (0;3) i

= 0:35 is the measure of relative …t associated to the

reference model. From this procedure

is equal to 0:065.

D Identi…cation Let’s order the variables in the model as Yt = (Xt ; St ; Zt ; Ft )0 ; where the …rst element of Xt and Yt is log-labor productivity: Variables are entered in the VAR according to Appendix A. Following Ramirez, Waggoner and Zha (2007) let’s express the set of linear restrictions onto the structural parameters of A0 as 2

H (A0 ) = 4

A0 (I

1

B (1))

1

A0 1

3 5

D

where B (1) = B1 + ::: + Bp and B1 ; :::; Bp are the estimates of the reduced form autoregressive matrices. D is a 2n

n matrix of restrictions imposed on the impact

and long-run responses to structural shocks. Let’s de…ne nx and nz as the number of 35

See for instance Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (1999) and Altig, Christiano, Eichenbaum and Linde (2005).

30

variables in X and Z respectively. Let’s order the technology and monetary policy shock as the nth and nth z elements of the vector of structural shocks et respectively. The identifying restrictions are zero restrictions on the matrix D given by 2

6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 D =6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 4 where Tz and Tx are nz

nz and nx

0

0 Tx x

0

x

x

x

Tz x

x

x

x

x

x

x

0

0

0

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

3

7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7; 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 5

(7)

nx matrices respectively, and have the form of

upper triangular matrices with an inverted order of columns: 2

6 6 6 Ti = 6 6 6 4

0

0

0 0

x2;ni .. .

xni ;1

xni ;ni

x1;ni 1

1

x2;ni .. . xni ;ni

3

7 7 7 7; 7 7 5

where i = z; x: The zero restrictions on D satisfy both the necessary and su¢ cient (rank) conditions for exact identi…cation derived by Ramirez, Waggoner and Zha (2007). In order to recover A0 from the system of linear equations, H (A0 ) = D and A0 1 A0 10 = (2007). Let

; I recur to an algorithm proposed by Ramirez, Waggoner and Zha 1

= SD 2 be the n n lower diagonal Cholesky matrix of the covariance of

the residuals of the reduced form VAR, that is SDS0 = E[ut u0t ] =

31

and D = diag( ):

Let’s compute H ( ) and de…ne matrices P1 and P2 as:

P1

P2 where Is

s

2

0 6 1 6 6 In 4 0n

1

01

n 1

n

0n

1

0n

n 1

n

0n

1

n

In

3

1 n 1

[in ; in 1 ; ::::; i1 ] ;

7 7 ,7 5

(8)

(9)

is the s-dimensional identity matrix and is is an n-dimensional column

vector of zeros with the sth element equal to 1. Proposition 1 For given estimates of B and ated to

; let

be the Cholesky factor associ-

; and let H ( ) ; P1 and P2 be de…ned as in (8)

(9) : Let P3 be the Q factor

associated with the QR decomposition of the matrix P1 H ( ) and de…ne P = P3 P20 . Let also A0 satisfy the restriction H (A0 ) = D where D is de…ned as in (7) : It 1

follows that A0 =

P.

For a proof see Ramirez, Waggoner and Zha (2007). These restrictions satisfy both the necessary and the rank conditions for exact identi…cation. The structural shocks et are obtained from et = A0 1 ut : Finally, the order of the variables in X and Z can be arbitrarily changed without any e¤ect on the identi…cations of the columns for technology and monetary policy shocks. To see these, consider the matrix A0 : These assumptions impose the following zero restrictions on the matrix A0 ; 2

a11 6 6 6 (nx nx ) 6 6 6 a21 6 6 6 (1 nx ) A0 = 6 6 6 a31 6 6 6 (nz nx ) 6 6 6 a41 4 (1 nx )

0 nx

0 1

(nx

a22 (1

1)

(1

nz ) a33

1)

(nz

a42 (1

nz ) 0

a32 (nz

a14

nz ) a43

1) 32

(1

nz )

3

7 7 nx 1 7 7 7 7 a24 7 7 (1 1) 7 7: 7 7 a34 7 7 (nz 1) 7 7 7 7 a44 5 (1 1)

Then consider the n

n orthonormal matrix 2

6 6 6 W =6 6 6 4 where W11 and W33 are nx

W11 0

0

0

1

0

0 W33

0

0

nx and nz

0

0

0

3

7 7 0 7 7; 7 0 7 5 1

nz orthonormal matrices respectively. If A0

satis…es H (A0 ) = D ; any matrix A~0 = W A0 also satis…es H A~0 = D :

Appendix E: Matching the NKPC to the BVAR impulse responses The value of

that reduces the weighted mean-square distance in median in‡ation

responses is given by = arg min Ia ~ a

0

~ a ( ) Wa ~ a

where ~ j and ~ j ( ) are (T

~ a ( ) + Ir ~ r

0

~ r ( ) Wr ~ r

~r( )

1) column vectors of in‡ation impulse responses to the

two shocks, j = T ECH and j = M P; evaluated over the …rst T periods; ~ j refers to the median impulse response from the BVAR, ~ j ( ) refers to the impulse response in the NKPC evaluated at

: Ia and Ir are scalar equal to 1 or 0 depending on whether

I am …tting in‡ation responses to technology and/or monetary policy shocks. In order to compute impulse responses predicted by the NKPC conditional on the path of the other variables, I use the median responses predicted by the BVAR model for those variables. Wj is a diagonal matrix set equal to the inverse of the diagonal of the posterior variance-covariance matrix of in‡ation impulse response vector from the BVAR.

33

;

Table 1 : Benchmark BVAR, 1960:1-2007:3. Median inflation adjustment speed to technology shocks. 1 Half-year

1 year

2 years PGDP 0.21

3 years

4 years

0.68

0.50

0.07

0.02

0.61;0.78

0.43;0.63

0.16;0.34

0.04;0.15

0.01;0.06

0.61

0.42

PUNEW 0.16

0.05

0.02

0.51;0.74

0.33;0.56

0.10;0.28

0.02;0.12

0.00;0.05

0.46

0.28

PWSFA 0.07

0.02

0.00

0.35;0.62

0.20;0.44

0.04;0.18

0.00;0.07

0.00;0.02

0.58

0.42

PCEPI 0.18

0.06

0.02

0.51;0.71

0.35;0.56

0.13;0.30

0.04;0.14

0.01;0.06

Table 2 : Benchmark BVAR, 1960:1-2007:3. Median inflation adjustment speed to monetary policy shocks Half-year

1 year

0.99

0.96

2 years PGDP 0.81

0.46

0.14

0.93;1.00

0.83;0.99

0.62;0.91

0.29;0.62

0.06;0.24

0.93

0.89

PUNEW 0.69

0.32

0.07

0.81;0.98

0.71;0.95

0.50;0.80

0.18;0.46

0.02;0.15

0.95

0.88

PWSFA 0.58

0.21

0.04

0.83;0.99

0.71;0.95

0.40;0.72

0.11;0.35

0.01;0.10

0.98

0.92

PCEPI 0.74

0.37

0.09

0.88;1.00

0.75;0.97

0.52;0.85

0.20;0.52

0.03;0.18

1

3 years

4 years

Inflation adjustment speed is measured by rij over different horizons, and for different price indices. Number in smaller characters are the 16th and 84th percentiles. PGDP: GDP deflator; PUNEW: CPI; PWSFA: PPI; PCEPI: personal consumption deflator.

34

Table 3 : Benchmark BVAR, 1960:1-1979:3, Median inflation adjustment speed to technology shocks. Half-year

1 year

0.96

0.85

2 years PGDP 0.55

3 years

4 years

0.28

0.13

0.93;0.98

0.80;0.91

0.46;0.67

0.20;0.40

0.08;0.21

0.89

0.77

PUNEW 0.45

0.24

0.13

0.84;0.94

0.69;0.86

0.35;0.59

0.16;0.37

0.07;0.21

0.92

0.81

PWSFA 0.47

0.27

0.16

0.86;0.96

0.72;0.89

0.36;0.61

0.18;0.40

0.10;0.24

0.91

0.80

PCEPI 0.50

0.28

0.14

0.85;0.96

0.72;0.88

0.40;0.63

0.19;0.40

0.09:0.22

Table 4 : Benchmark BVAR, 1960:1-1979:3, Median inflation adjustment speed to monetary policy shocks. Half-year

1 year

0.88

0.70

2 years PGDP 0.55

0.24

0.12

0.75;0.97

0.52;0.88

0.28;0.75

0.13;0.36

0.04;0.25

0.89

0.74

PUNEW 0.54

0.23

0.18

0.76;0.98

0.50;0.90

0.32;0.67

0.13;0.37

0.06;0.30

0.72

0.56

PWSFA 0.37

0.21

0.16

0.53;0.92

0.38;0.74

0.21;0.53

0.09;0.36

0.06;0.27

0.80

0.68

PCEPI 0.50

0.24

0.19

0.64;0.95

0.48;0.86

0.27;0.67

0.12;0.39

0.06;0.33

35

3 years

4 years

Table 5 : Benchmark BVAR, 1979:4-2007:3, Median inflation adjustment speed to technology shocks. Half-year

1 year

0.20

0.06

2 years PGDP 0.01

3 years

4 years

0.01

0.00

0.13;0.40

0.03;0.20

0.00;0.08

0.00;0.05

0.00;0.02

0.11

0.04

PUNEW 0.02

0.01

0.01

0.06;0.30

0.01;0.14

0.01;0.07

0.00;0.04

0.00;0.02

0.08

0.02

PWSFA 0.01

0.01

0.00

0.04;0.23

0.01;0.09

0.00;0.04

0.00;0.02

0.00;0.01

0.13

0.05

PCEPI 0.02

0.01

0.00

0.07;0.31

0.02;0.17

0.00;0.08

0.00;0.04

0.00;0.02

Table 6 : Benchmark BVAR, 1979:4-2007:3, Median inflation adjustment speed to monetary policy shocks. Half-year

1 year

2 years PGDP 0.34

3 years

4 years

0.96

0.62

0.17

0.07

0.83;1.00

0.43;0.75

0.19;0.48

0.08;0.27

0.03;0.13

0.48

0.29

PUNEW 0.10

0.05

0.03

0.27;0.84

0.14;0.52

0.04;0.22

0.02;0.13

0.01;0.07

0.54

0.23

PWSFA 0.08

0.03

0.01

0.24;0.93

0.09;0.54

0.02;0.25

0.01;0.12

0.00;0.05

0.88

0.68

PCEPI 0.36

0.18

0.08

0.68;0.98

0.47;0.82

0.19;0.50

0.08;0.28

0.03;0.13

36

MP # of Quarters PGDP M2 FYFF IFNRER JQCR GDPQ/ LBMNU LBMNU GDPQ CES275/PGDP

2 2 2 2 2 -

SignRestriction 70 70 :0 70 70 -

2 2 -

70 70 -

TECH # of Quarters 20 10 5 20

SignRestriction 70 :0 :0 :0

10 5

:0 :0

Table 7: Sign- Restrictions. The second and fourth columns contain the least number of quarters it is assumed to hold for. The third and fifth columns contain the sign restrictions. Remaining variables are unrestricted. IFNRER: Real non-residential investments; JQCR: Real Personal Consumption Expenditures; LBMNU: Index total hours worked; CES275: Average hourly earnings.

37

TECH shock

0.2

PGDP

0.1

0

0 -0.02

-0.1

PUNEW

-0.2

PWFSA

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.04

20

0.1

0.02

0.05

0.01

0

0

-0.05

-0.01

-0.1

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.02

20

0.05

0.04

0

0.02

-0.05

0

-0.1

-0.02

-0.15

PCEPI

MP shock

0.02

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.04

20

0

0.01

-0.02

0.005

-0.04

0

-0.06

-0.005

-0.08

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.01

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

Figure 1 : Benchmark BVAR. Median, 5, 16, 84 and 95th percentiles inflation impulse responses of different measures of inflation to one standard deviation shock. COLUMNS: Responses to Tech and MP shocks respectively. ROWS: PGDP: GDP deflator; PWFSA: producer price index; PCEPI: consumption expenditure deflator; PUNEW: CPI. Units are in basis points. Horizontal Axis: quarters. TECH shock

GDPQ

1

FFR

0.2

0.5

0 0 -0.5

-0.2 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.4

20

0.2

0.6

0

0.4

-0.2

0.2

-0.4

0

-0.6

-0.2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.2

PGDP

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.02

0.1

0

0 -0.02

-0.1 -0.2

GDPQ/H

MP shock

0.4

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.04

20

0.8

0.3

0.6

0.2

0.4

0.1

0.2 0

0 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.1

20

Figure 2 : Benchmark BVAR, Median, 5, 16, 84 and 95th percentiles impulse responses to one standard deviation shock. COLUMNS: Responses to Tech and MP shocks respectively. ROWS: GDPQ: real GDP; FFR: annual FedFunds rate; dPGDP: GDP deflator inflation; GDPQ/H: labor productivity.

38

Figure 3 : Benchmark BVAR. Impulse response to one standard deviation technology shock of the remaining variables in the BVAR. MP shock

0

0

5

10

15

0 -50

20

0

5

10

15

5

10

15

FSPCOM

CES275

0

5

10

15

20

2

15

0

0

5

10

15

20

10

15

20

0

5

10

15

20

0

5

10

15

20

0

5

10

15

20

0

5

10

15

20

PCOM

1

0

5

10

15

0 -1

20

0.5

0

5

10

15

20

0 -0.5 1

0 -2

5

0 -20

20

2 FixInvRes

FixInvNRes

10

0 -1

0

5

10

15

20

0

5

10

15

20

0 -1

0.5 FM2

0.5 FM1

5

1

0

0 -0.5

0

0 -0.2

20

0

20

LBMNU

HSFR

CES002 0

0.2

-2

0 -0.5

20

0.2

0

-0.2

15

0 -0.2

20

2

-2

10

LHUR

0 -0.1

5

0.2 A0M051

JQCR

0.1

0

FMRRA

-1

0.5 IPS10

50 UTL11

FMRNBA

1

0

5

10

15

20

0 -0.5

Figure 4 : Benchmark BVAR. Impulse response to one standard deviation monetary policy shock of the remaining variables in the BVAR. .

39

Inflation Adjustment Speed: 1 year horizon PGDP

1

PUNEW

1

0.6

0.6

MP

0.8

MP

0.8

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

0

1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

TFP

PWSFA

1

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

TFP

PCEPI

1

0.6

MP

0.8

0.6

MP

0.8

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

0

1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

TFP

0.5

TFP

Figure 5 : Benchmark BVAR, draws of inflation adjustment speed to TFP (horizontal axis) and MP (vertical axis) shocks, evaluated at 1 year horizon, and for the four measures of prices (4 plots).

0.05

-0.05

0

-0.1 2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.4

0.2

0.2

0

0

-0.2

-0.2

-0.4 0

-0.4 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.01

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

0 0

20

0.2

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

0 0

1

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

TFP

-0.04 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

PCEPI

1

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

20

0.1 0.05

0.05

PWSFA

1

MP

0.1 GDPQ/H

0.4

TFP

-0.02

-0.02

0.4

0.4

0 0.2

-0.05 0 0

0.6

0.2

-0.01

-0.03 0

0.6

0.4

2

PUNEW

1 0.8

0.02

0 DPGDP

-0.15 0

0.4

1 0.8

MP

FFR

-0.05 0

PGDP

MP

GDPQ

0

Inflation Adjustment Speed: 1 year horizon

MPshock

0.05

0.1

MP

TECHshock

0.15

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.1 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

0 0

20

0.2

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

TFP

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0 0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

TFP

Figure 6 : Robustness: Sign-restrictions identification. Median, 5, 16, 84 and 95th percentiles impulse responses. Five hundreds draws of inflation adjustment speed to TFP (horizontal axis) and MP (vertical axis) shocks, evaluated at 1 year horizon.

40

Figure 7: Estimates of technology shocks. The solid-blue line is the benchmark identification scheme, the dashed-red line is the estimate obtained by imposing long-run restrictions on the FTFP series in the BVAR model.

-0.1

0

-0.2 10

20

30

40

50

60

0.6

0.2

0.4

0

0.2

-0.2 -0.4 0

20

30

40

50

60

-0.2 0

0.05

0 -0.005

GDPQ/H

30

40

50

60

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.2

10

20

30

40

50

0 0

60

0.2

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

0 0

1

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

TFP

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

TFP

0.005

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

-0.01 0

0.4

0.1

0.3

0.05

0.2

0

0.1

-0.05

0 0

20

0.01

-0.05 -0.1 0

10

0 10

0.1

DPGDP

-0.3 0

0.4

PUNEW

1 0.8

10

20

30

40

50

60

-0.1 0

PWSFA

1

10

20

30

40

50

0.8

0.6

0.6

60

0.4

0.4

0.2

10

20

30

40

50

PCEPI

1

0.8

MP

FFR

-0.2 0

1 0.8

MP

0.2

PGDP

MP

GDPQ

0

InflationAdjustment Speed: 1year horizon

MP shock

0.1

0.4

MP

TECH shock

0.6

60

0 0

0.2

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

TFP

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0 0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

TFP

Figure 8 : Robustness: BVAR estimated on Monthly frequency. Median, 5, 16, 84 and 95th percentiles inflation impulse responses. Five hundreds draws of inflation adjustment speed to TFP (horizontal axis) and MP (vertical axis) shocks, evaluated at 1 year horizon.

41

Sub-sample 1960:I-1979:III TECH shock

0.05

0.04

0 -0.02 4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

0.02

-0.02

0.01

-0.04

0

-0.06 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.1

PWFSA

-0.01 0

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.02 0

0

0.02

-0.02

0.01

-0.04

0

-0.06 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.01 0

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.01 0

0.02

15

0

10

-0.02

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

5 0

-0.06 0

-5 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.02

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

0.01

-0.05 0

-0.1 -0.15 0

20

x 10

-0.04

0.05

0

2

0 2

-3

0.02

-0.1 0

0.01

-0.1 0

20

0 -0.05

0.02

-0.05 2

0.04

0.05

PCEPI

-0.04 0

PWFSA

PUNEW

2

PUNEW

-0.1 -0.15 0

0.03

0.05 PGDP

-0.05

MP shock

TECH shock

0.1

0.02

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.01 0 -3

0.02

10

0 PCEPI

PGDP

0

Sub-sample 1979:IV-2007:III

MP shock

5

-0.02 0

-0.04 2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

x 10

-0.06 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-5 0

20

Figure 9: Subsamples abalysis. Median, 5, 16, 84 and 95th percentiles impulse responses of different measures of inflation to one standard deviation shock. Sub-sample 1960:I-1979:III TECH shock

0.1 0

0.5

-0.1

0

-0.2

-0.5 0

-0.3 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

0.1

0.4

0

0.2

-0.1

0 0

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.2 0

20

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.3

0

0.2

FFR

0.6

0 -0.2

0.2

-0.4

0

-0.2

-0.6 0

-0.2 0

-0.4 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

0 0

20

0.1

0.03

0

0.02

0.05

0.02

dPGDP

0.04

0

-0.1

-0.02 2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.01 0

1.5

0.3

0.8 0.6

0.1

0.4

0.05

1

0.2

0.5

0.1

0

0

-0.5 0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

-0.1 0

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0.15

0.2

0

0 0

20

6

0

-0.1 0

20

4

0.01

-0.05

-0.04 0

2

0.1 2

0.05

-0.15 0

MP shock

0.2

0.6

0.2

-0.05

GDPQ/H

TECH shock

0.8

GDPQ

1

GDPQ/H

dPGDP

FFR

GDPQ

1.5

Sub-sample 1979:IV-2007:III

MPshock

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.05 0

Figure 10: Median, 5, 16, 84 and 95th percentiles impulse responses to one standard deviation shock. Sub-sample 1960:I-1979:III

Sub-sample 1979:IV-2007:III

Inflation Adjustment Speed: 1 year horizon PGDP

1

Inflation Adjustment Speed: 1 year horizon PUNEW

1

PGDP

1

0.6

0.6

0.6

MP

0.6

MP

0.8

MP

0.8

MP

0.8

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0

0

0

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

TFP

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0.4

0.2

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

TFP

PW SFA

1

0.5

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

0

1

PW SFA

1

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.2

0

0

0

0.3

0.4

0.5

TFP

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.3

0.4

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

TFP

0.5

PCEPI

MP

0.6

MP

0.6

MP

0.8

MP

0.8

0.2

0.2

1

0.8

0.1

0.1

TFP

0.8

0

0

TFP

PCEPI

1

PUNEW

1

0.8

0.4 0.2

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

TFP

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

TFP

Figure 11 : Five hundreds draws of inflation adjustment speed to TFP (horizontal axis) and MP (vertical axis) shocks, evaluated at 1 year horizon, and for the four measures of prices.

42

Pre-Volcker sample Pre-Volcker Sample Inflation response to TECH shock

Inflation response to MP shock 0.015

-0.005 NKPC-both NKPC-tech BVAR

NKPC-both NKPC-mp BVAR

-0.01 0.01

Both Tech MP 0.49 0.4 0.49 0.0026 0.0034 0.0026 0.00 0.00 0.00

-0.015

0.005

-0.02

-0.025 0

-0.03

-0.005

-0.035

-0.04

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-0.01

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

Volcker-Greenspan sample Volcker-Greenspan Sample Inflation response to TECH shock

Inflation response to MP shock

-3

0.01

12

0

10

x 10

NKPC-both NKPC-mp BVAR

-0.01

8

-0.02

6

-0.03

4

Both 0.99 0.0021 0.2

Tech 0.86 0.0064 0.00

2

-0.04

NKPC-both NKPC-tech

-0.05

0

BVAR

-0.06

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

Figure 12 : Median (black line), 5th and 95th quantiles (--) of inflation response to a one standard deviation shock to technology and monetary policy predicted by the BVARmodel; inflation response in the NKPC calibrated to jointly fit both responses (red line with circles) and to fit responses separately (green line with diamonds).

43

MP 0.99 0.0013 0.00

Does Inflation Adjust Faster to Aggregate Technology ... - Acrobat Planet

$-ais the frequency of price adjustment, and ρ ' 3(,)4 is price indexation to past inflation. Model %.& defines the dynamics of π*t conditional on the path of marginal cost. Similarly to Sbordone(2002, 2005) and Cogley and Sbordone (2008), dynamics of marginal cost are obtained from the VAR model, rather than modelling ...

2MB Sizes 1 Downloads 226 Views

Recommend Documents

Does Inflation Adjust Faster to Aggregate Technology ... - Acrobat Planet
$Email: [email protected]. Mailing address: ..... First, inflation is much more responsive to technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks. ... Tables 1 and 2 report the median, 16th and 84th percentiles of the posterior distrib& ution of rj

Does Inflation Adjust Faster to Aggregate Technology ...
establish the main sources of business cycle fluctuations, but also to understand the ... such as sign restrictions of Uhlig (2006) and Dedola and Neri (2006).

Does Inflation Adjust Faster to Aggregate Technology ...
are particularly important as these shocks account together for a large fraction of business cycle fluctuations.1 Assessing the speed of inflation adjustment to different types of .... where Ft is the information available to the central bank as of t

Does Inflation Adjusts Faster to Aggregate Technology ...
ing restrictions at two horizons (k30 and k31), since this choice accounts for both ..... where Ft is the information available to the central bank as of time t, ω is a ... Comparing these with the ones obtained under the Minnesota prior, we can see

Does Inflation Adjusts Faster to Aggregate Technology ...
This paper studies inflation adjustment speed to aggregate neutral ... information on the ability of existing models of price setting to match price dynamics.

Does the Price Level Adjust Faster to Aggregate ...
are robust to different identification assumptions, data definitions and measures of aggregate prices. JEL Classification: E31, E4, C11, C3. Keywords: Bayesian ...

Optimal Banking Sector Recapitalization - Acrobat Planet
banking capital stock, produces a disruption of credit and fall in output equivalent to those in ..... and the production function is Cobb Douglas: yt = B¯kαh1−α.

Switching to a Poor Business Activity: Optimal Capital ... - Acrobat Planet
Our results contrast with those obtained in models where the agency problem is reduced to a pure risk-shifting problem. We find larger agency costs and lower optimal leverages. We identify the bankruptcy trigger written in debt indenture, which maxim

Household Bargaining and Portfolio Choice - Acrobat Planet
We thank Anna Paulson, Robert Pollak, Silvia Prina, Mich`ele Tertilt and participants at the 2009 American Economic Association, Society of Labor Economists, and Midwest. Economic Association meetings for numerous helpful comments. All remaining erro

Household Bargaining and Portfolio Choice - Acrobat Planet
at the 2009 American Economic Association, Society of Labor Economists, and ... versity of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, 1301 W. Gregory Dr., 421 Mumford ...

Liquidity constraints in a monetary economy - Acrobat Planet
Sep 17, 2009 - +34-91-624-9619, Fax: +34-91624-9329. ... by Kiyotaki and Wright (1989) has been successful in providing a solid micro-foundation ..... The choice of money holdings m – and thus, through the budget constraint pc = (1−θ)m,.

Risk-sensitive Consumption and Savings under ... - Acrobat Planet
Jun 20, 2009 - Hong Kong, and the Chinese University of Hong Kong for helpful ... Research Fund (GRF, formerly CERG) in Hong Kong for financial support.

Liquidity Premia in Dynamic Bargaining Markets - Acrobat Planet
Sep 20, 2007 - buy or sell large quantities in a short time, at a similar price. .... borrow and save cash in some “bank account,” at the exogenously given interest rate ¯r .... In light of this discussion, the assets of our model are best viewe

Practical Uses of Virtual Machines for Protection of ... - Acrobat Planet
Terra [7] and NetTop [18,. 19] use VMM to separate compartments of differing levels of trustworthiness. For ex- ample, one VM may be used ..... [4] R. Cox, E. Grosse, R. Pike, D. L. Presotto, and S. Quinlan. Security in Plan 9. In Pro- ceedings of th

An estimated small open economy model with ... - Acrobat Planet
disconnect between the labor market and the rest of the economy. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 details the model. Section 3 presents.

Does Inflation Targeting Matter for Output Growth ...
Tel: +1-202-473-0360. Abstract: We examine in this paper the effects of inflation targeting (IT) on industrial and emerging economies' output growth over the ...

(Un)importance of Unemployment Fluctuations for ... - Acrobat Planet
We take up this finding and allow for two types of skills: good and bad. In the model it takes work experience to acquire good skills, and these skills are more likely to be lost when workers become unemployed. Importantly, in our modeling this skill

Inflation Dynamics in Egypt: Does Egypt's Trade ...
below market equilibrium exchange rate through indirect measures – although may temporarily .... targeting only in the case of shocks to world market prices.

Liquidity Premia in Dynamic Bargaining Markets - Acrobat Planet
Sep 20, 2007 - carry different exogenously specified trading costs. ... Wright, participants of seminar at Stanford, the Kellogg School of Management, the Séminaire CREST, ... determines investors' outside option when they trade with dealers.

Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy ... - Acrobat Planet
Nov 26, 2007 - At, the labor wedge 1−τl,t, the investment wedge 1/(1 +τx,t), and the government wedge gt. The household maximizes: max ct,kt+1,lt. E0. [. ∞. ∑.

Synchronising Deregulation in Product and Labour ... - Acrobat Planet
main reason why frictions remain in European labour markets, says Saint-Paul (2000), is that ..... optimal intervention into the market place, but a function of the legal culture and history of the country. EPL may ..... one possible equilibrium path

The Private Equity Premium Puzzle Revisited - Acrobat Planet
University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. This Version: July 23, 2009. Abstract. In this paper, I extend the results of ..... acquisitions adjustment, which is an important channel for movements in and out of private equity in