Journal of Economic Theory  ET2414 journal of economic theory 81, 5896 (1998) article no. ET982414

Indeterminacy and Sunspots with Constant Returns Jess Benhabib Department of Economics, New York University, 269 Mercer St., 7th Floor, New York City, New York 10003

and Kazuo Nishimura Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University, Yoshida-Honmachi, Sakyo-ku, Kyoto 606, Japan Received February 14, 1998

We show that indeterminacy can easily arise in multisector models that have constant variable returns to scale and very small market imperfections. This is in sharp contrast to models that require increasing returns to generate indeterminacy and which have been criticized on the basis of recent empirical estimates indicating that returns to scale are roughly constant and that market imperfections are small. We also show that we can calibrate our constant returns model with sunspots, using standard parametrizations to produce a close match to the moments of aggregate consumption, investment, output, and employment in US data. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: E00, E3, O40.  1998 Academic Press

1. INTRODUCTION Recently there has been a renewed interest in the possibility of indeterminacy and sunspots, or alternatively put, in the existence of a continuum of equilibria that arises in dynamic economies with some market imperfections. 1 Much of the research in this area has been concerned with the empirical plausibility of indeterminacy in markets with external effects or with monopolistic competition and which exhibit some degree of increasing returns. While the early results on indeterminacy relied on relatively large increasing returns and high markups, more recently Benhabib and Farmer [10] showed that indeterminacy can also occur in two-sector models with small 1 A long but incomplete list of the recent literature includes Beaudry and Deveruex [4], Benhabib and Farmer [6, 7, 9, 10], Boldrin and Rustichini [14], Chatterjee and Cooper [17], Christiano and Harrison [18], Farmer and Guo [19, 20], Gali [21], Perli [27], Rotemberg and Woodford [28], SchmittGrohe [29], Weder [31], and Xie [32].

58 0022-053198 25.00 Copyright  1998 by Academic Press All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

File: DISTL2 241401 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 4219 Signs: 2229 . Length: 50 pic 3 pts, 212 mm

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

59

sector-specific external effects and very mild increasing returns.2 Nevertheless, a number of empirical researchers, refining the earlier findings of Hall [23, 24] on disaggregated US data, have concluded that returns to scale seem to be roughly constant, if not decreasing. 3 While one can argue whether the degree of increasing returns required for indeterminacy in Benhabib and Farmer [10] falls within the standard errors of these recent empirical estimates, one may also ask whether increasing returns are at all needed for indeterminacy to arise in a plausible manner. The purpose of this paper is to give a negative answer to this question, and to show how indeterminacy can occur in a standard growth model with constant social returns, decreasing private returns, small or negligible external effects, and standard parameter values that are typically used in the literature on business cycles. Furthermore we will show that it is possible to realistically calibrate such a model and to obtain a reasonably good match to the moments of aggregate US data. Indeterminacy or multiple equilibria emerges in dynamic models with small market distortions as a type of coordination problem. Roughly speaking, what is needed for indeterminacy is a mechanism such that, starting from an arbitrary equilibrium, if all agents were to simultaneously increase their investment in an asset, the rate of return on the asset would tend to increase, and in turn set off relative price changes that would drive the economy back towards a stationary equilibrium. One such simple mechanism in one-sector models is increasing returns, typically sustained in a market context via external effects or monopolistic competition. In a multisector model, however, the rates of return and marginal products depend not only on stocks of assets, but also on the composition of output across sectors. Increasing the production and the stock of a capital asset, say due to an increase in its price, may well increase its rate of return. It is possible therefore to have constant aggregate returns in all sectors at the social level, and to still obtain indeterminacy if there are minor or even negligible external effects in some of the sectors. A more detailed intuition for indeterminacy is given at the end of Section 2 in the case of a simple two-sector model. Constant social returns coupled with small external effects implies that some sectors must have a small degree of decreasing returns at the private level. This is in contrast to models of indeterminacy with social, increasing but private, constant returns to scale. An implication of decreasing private returns is of course positive profits. In the parameterized examples given in the sections below, these profits will be quite small because the size of 2 Since Benhabib and Farmer [10] postulate constant returns at the private level, we can measure increasing returns as the sum of all CobbDouglas coefficients minus one. Indeterminacy then, for standard parametrizations, requires increasing returns of about 0.07. 3 See for example Basu and Fernald [1, 2], Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebello [15], or Burnside [16], among others.

File: DISTL2 241402 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3797 Signs: 3207 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

60

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

external effects, and therefore the degree of decreasing returns needed for indeterminacy will also be small. Nevertheless positive profits would invite entry, and unless the number of firms are fixed, a fixed cost of entry must be assumed to determine the number of firms along the equilibrium. Such a market structure would then exhibit increasing private marginal costs but constant social marginal costs, which is in line with current empirical work on this subject (see footnote 3, above). It seems therefore that models of indeterminacy based on market imperfections which drive a wedge between private and social returns must have some form of increasing returns, no matter how small, either in variable costs (as in some of the earlier models of indeterminacy), or through a type of fixed cost that prevents entry in the face of positive profits. (See also Gali [21] and Gali and Zilliboti [22].) The point is that while some small wedge between private and social returns is necessary for indeterminacy, this in no way requires decreasing marginal costs or increasing marginal returns in production. For reasons also given at the end of Section 2, indeterminacy can arise in a constant returns two-sector economy only if the utility of consumption is close to linear. In order to calibrate the model with standard parameters for production and preferences we need a three sector model. Section 3 presents such a model in a continuous time framework. In Section 3.2 we show that this model easily gives rise to indeterminacy with standard parametrizations for utility functions, labor supply elasticities, discount and depreciation rates, and factor shares. Much of the derivations are relegated to Appendix I. In Section 4 we present the stochastic, discrete-time version of our model and we calibrate it. We construct some simple sunspot equilibria and show that we can easily find standard parametrizations of our CobbDouglas technology and preferences to reasonably match the various moments of US data. The full derivations for this case are given in Appendix II.

2. THE TWO-SECTOR MODEL 2.1. Basic Structure We model an economy having an infinitely-lived representative agent with instantaneous utility given by U(c)=(1&_) &1 c (1&_) &(1+v) &1 L (1+v)

_, v0

where c is consumption, L is labor supply, v &1 is the labor supply elasticity and _ is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption. For simplicity of exposition we will start with a two-sector rather than an n-sector

File: DISTL2 241403 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3013 Signs: 2508 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

61

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

CobbDouglas production technology with consumption goods c, and investment goods, x. The agent's optimization problem will be given by Max

|



0

(U(q c L :c0 K :c 1 L ac0 K ac1 )&(1+v) &1 L (1+v) ) e &(r& g) t dt

(1)

with respect to K c , L c , K x , L x and subject to x=q x L ;x0 K ;x1 L bx0 K bx1 ,

(2)

c=q c L :c0 K :c1 L ac 0 K ac 1 , (3)

dk =x&gk, dt K x +K c =k,

L x +L c =L,

(4)

with initial stock of k given. The components of the production functions, L bc0 K bx1 for x, and L ac 0 K ac 1 for c, represent output effects that are external, and are viewed as functions of time by the agent. We can write the Hamiltonian as follows: H=U(q c L :c0 K :c 1 L ac 0 K ac1 )&(1+v) &1 L (1+v) + p(q x L ;x0 K ;x1 L bx0 K bx1 & gk)+w 0(L&L x &L c )+w(k&K x &K c ). Here p, w 0 , and w are the Lagrange multipliers which will represent the utility price of the capital good x, the rental rates of capital goods, and the wage rate of labor, all in terms of the price of the consumption good c. The first-order conditions with respect to K c , L c , K x , L x yield the following w 0 =U$: 0 q c L :c 0 +a0 &1 K :c 1 +a1 = p; 0 q x L ;x0 +b0 &1 K ;x1 +b1, w =U$: 1 q c L :c 0 +a0 K :c 1 +a1 &1 = p; 1 q x L ;x0 +b0 K ;x1 +b1 &1 . If we define w 0 =U$w 0 ,

w =U$w,

p =U$p,

then the first-order conditions become w 0 =: 0 q c L :c 0 +a0 &1 K :c 1 +a1 = p; 0 q x L ;x0 +b0 &1 K ;x1 +b1, w=: 1 q c L

:0 +a0 c

K

:1 +a1 &1 c

= p; 1 q x L

;0 +b0 x

K

;1 +b1 &1 x

.

(5) (6)

The first-order conditions with respect to L, after combining with the others, give the labor market equilibrium condition: v c (1&_): 0 L &1 c =L .

File: DISTL2 241404 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 4095 Signs: 1390 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

(7)

62

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

If we assume constant returns at the social level, we have a 0 +: 1 +a 0 +a 1 =; 0 +; 1 +b 0 +b 1 =1. The equations of motion for the system are given by dk

\ dt + =x& gk, d(U$p) \ dt + =U$(c)(rp&w),

(8) (9)

Then Eq. (9) can be written as

dp =rp&w( p, k)&p dt U"(c) = 1+p U$(c)

U"(c)

dc dp

c dk

_p dt +k dt & U$(c)

&1

c p

_

U"(c)

c dk

_k dt &

&

_ \ +\ +& rp&w( p, k)&p U$(c) p c p c = 1&_ } rp&w( p, k)+_ _ \c+\p+& _ \c+\k+ (x( p, k)& gk)& , &1

(10)

where _=(&U"(c)cU$(c)). With logarithmic utility of consumption, we have, of course, _=1. The first-order conditions given by Eqs. (5)(7), and the equations of motion given by (8) and (10) completely describe the system. 2.2. Two-Sector Dynamics The Jacobian matrix [J ] for the differential equations (8) and (10) is given by

[J]=

_

_E

&1

x &g k p c x &g c k k

\ +\ +\

x p

+

E

&1

_\

w p & +r +_ p c

c k

x p

+ \ +\ +\ +&

&

,

(11)

where E=[1&_( pc)(cp)]. Note that E can be written as one minus the product of two elasticities: E=(1&_= cp )

File: DISTL2 241405 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2192 Signs: 902 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

(12)

63

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

where = cp #

c^ p c = . p^ c p

\+ \ +

If we multiply the first row of [J ] by &_E &1p and add it to the second, we get a matrix with an unchanged determinant. We have DET [J ]=

\

x &g k

+\

&

w +r [1&_= cp ] &1. p

+

If the utility of consumption is linear, then _=0, and it is easy to see that the roots of the matrix [J ] become ((xk)&g) and ((&wp)+r). In Appendix I we show, from Eq. (82), that

x

\ k+ =

L

_

\ \L +\ v ++

r: 0 1+

c

_

L

\ ; (1&a &a )&: (1&b &b )+; : \ v + L + L _ r: 1+ \ \ L +\ v ++ = . _ L \ ; : &: ; +; : \ v + L + 1

0

1

1

0

1

1

0

c

0

c

1

0

1

0

1

0

c

If _=0, we have r: 0

x

\k& g+ = (; : &: ; ) & g. 1

0

1

0

Similarly, from Eq. (59) in Appendix I, we have : 0 +a 0

w

\& p +r+ =r \&: +a &; &b +1+ r( ; +b ) = \; +b &: &a + r(; +b ) = \(: +a )(; +b )&(: +a )(; +b )+ . 0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

1

1

0

0

0

0

0

1

1

The last step above follows from multiplying (: 0 +a 0 ) in the denominator by ( ; 0 +; 1 +b 0 +b 1 ), which under constant returns equals one, similarly multiplying (; 0 +b 0 ) by (: 0 +: 1 +a 1 +a 0 ), and cancelling to simplify the denominator. It is easily shown that comparing the ratios of CobbDouglas

File: DISTL2 241406 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2164 Signs: 970 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

64

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

exponents of the production function amounts to comparing factor intensities, since the ratios of exponents determine input ratios. These ratios can be defined either with or without the external effects entering the exponents. We may therefore say that the capital good is labor intensive from the private perspective if (; 1 : 0 &: 1 ; 0 <0), but that it is capital intensive from the social perspective if ((: 1 +a 1 )(; 0 +b 0 )&(: 0 +a 0 )(; 1 +b 1 )<0). The expressions above allow us to state the following simple result: Proposition 1. In the two-sector model with _=0, if the capital good is labor intensive from the private perspective, but capital intensive from the social perspective, that is if ( ; 1 : 0 &: 1 ; 0 <0) but (: 1 +a 1 )(; 0 +b 0 )& (: 0 +a 0 )( ; 1 +b 1 )<0, then the steady state is indeterminate. A simple example illustrates the possibility of indeterminacy in the twosector model, for _=0, any r >0, g0, and only a small externality of the capital good in the production of the consumption good. Let ; 0 =0.34;

b 0 =0.00;

; 1 =0.66;

b 1 =0.0;

: 0 =0.30;

a 0 =0.05;

: 1 =0.65;

a 1 =0.0.

Then we have ; 1 : 0 &: 1 ; 0 <0, (: 1 +a 1 )( ; 0 +b 0 )&(: 0 +a 0 )(; 1 +b 1 )<0, and therefore both roots of [J ] are negative. Note also that without some external effects both of the above conditions cannot hold simultaneously. It is clear nevertheless that examples satisfying the above conditions for indeterminacy can be constructed with arbitrarily small external effects. To establish the intuition behind this result we note the following. Without external effects, the sign of (wp) depends on the sign of (: 0 ; 1 &: 1 ; 0 ), which represents the factor intensity difference between the two goods. This dependence on factor intensities is in fact nothing but an expression of the Stolper Samuelson theorem. Similarly, without external effects, the sign of term (xk) also depends on the sign of (: 0 ; 1 &: 1 ; 0 ), and reflects the Rybczynski theorem. We note from the Rybczynski theorem that this effect of stocks on outputs will, at constant prices, be more than proportional, and since at a steady state x= gk, it will be strong enough to overwhelm the term g. 4 It should be clear then that without external effects we have (wp)=(xk), so that the roots of [J] will be of opposite sign. The example of indeterminacy 4 In the same way, the StolperSamuelson theorem implies that &(w x p) will overwhelm r, since at a steady state wx =rp, but the expression above for ((&w x p)+r) already incorporates the steady-state relationship.

File: DISTL2 241407 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3523 Signs: 2465 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

65

works above precisely because, through external effects, it destroys the duality between the StolperSamuelson and Rybczynski effects. Since input coefficients are determined by factor prices, a change in aggregate inputs with prices fixed requires an adjustment of output levels to maintain full employment. The adjustment must reflect the structure of the input coefficient matrix, as implied by the Rybczynski Theorem. When there are no externalities the same is true, via Shepard's Lemma, for the effect of input prices on outputs, and this reflects the StolperSamuelson Theorem. However, with market distortions, true costs are not being minimized, and Shepard's Lemma no longer holds, breaking the reciprocal relation between the Rybczynski and StolperSamuelson effects. 5 We will make use of this point to provide a heuristic explanation of our indeterminacy result. To understand the intuition for this indeterminacy result consider first a simple one-sector model. Starting from an arbitrary equilibrium, consider another one with a higher rate of investment. A higher investment rate results in higher stocks and, if there are no increasing returns, in a lower marginal return to capital. The only way that this can be an equilibrium is if the other component of the return, the price (or shadow price) appreciation of capital, offsets the decline in the marginal product and justifies the increased holding of such stocks. This appreciating relative price induces a higher production of the capital good, that is a higher rate of investment. The result is a further decline in the marginal product of capital, which then requires an even higher price appreciation to justify the holding of the higher stocks. Transversality conditions rule out such an equilibrium. If there are increasing returns, however, incorporated into the model through some market imperfections, the higher stock levels increase rather than decrease the marginal product of capital, and this higher return justifies the holding of the higher stocks without requiring explosive price appreciations and violating transversality conditions. Such increasing returns to capital are generally introduced indirectly. In Benhabib and Farmer [6] increasing returns to capital are the result of changes induced in labor supply due to the reallocation of production in favor of investment and capital accumulation. In Gali [21], Rotemberg and Woodford [28], or SchmittGrohe [29], increasing returns are the result of countercyclical markups. In a two-sector model another mechanism leading to indeterminacy becomes operational. The return to capital now depends on the composition of output as well as the level of the stock. Let us first consider the case without external effects. Take the case where the capital good is capital intensive, and, again starting from an equilibrium, consider an increase in the rate of investment above the level of its initial equilibrium, induced 5 We should note that other distortions which interfere with true cost minimization are also likely to give rise to similar results.

File: DISTL2 241408 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3700 Signs: 3130 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

66

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

by an instantaneous increase in the relative price of the investment good. An increase in the stock of capital at constant prices would, from the Rybczynski theorem, lead to a more than proportional rise in its output. From the StolperSamuelson theorem, the initial price rise leads to an increase in rate of return of capital given by w, and to maintain the equality of the overall return to capital and the discount rate, the price of the investment good must decline. However this is not enough to check the Rycbzynski effect: The increasing capital stock leads to further expansions of investment output despite the retreat of prices towards the steady state levels, and investment output becomes explosive. 6 To get indeterminacy without relying on increasing returns, there must be a mechanism to nullify the duality between the Rybczynski and Stolper Samuelson theorems. This is precisely what happens in the two-sector model above in the presence of external effects, and is illustrated by Proposition 1. When the investment good is labor intensive from the private perspective, an increase in the capital stock decreases its output at constant prices through the Rybczynski effect. This checks the output side. The StolperSamuelson theorem, however, operates through the ``social'' factor intensities, and the investment good is capital intensive from the social perspective. The initial rise in its price causes an increase in one of the components of its return, w, and requires a price decline to maintain the overall return to capital equal to the discount rate. This offsets the initial rise in the relative price of the investment good and prices also reverse direction toward the steady state. Therefore, in the two-sector model, indeterminacy requires the destruction of the duality between the Rybczynski and StolperSamuelson effects through the introduction of market imperfections. 7 Why then do we have to resort to a three-sector model to generate examples of indeterminacy that are empirically plausible? The problem in the two-sector model arises because, when we consider constructing an alternative equilibrium with a higher investment rate, we must initially curtail consumption. If there is some curvature on the utility function, the desire to smooth consumption over time can overwhelm the effects described above. (A formal demonstration of this, in terms of the roots of [J], is tedious, but is available from the authors on request.) When a third nonconsumption good is introduced however, indeterminacy can arise from compositional 6

The argument for the case in which the capital good is labor intensive is similarly based on the Rybczynski and StolperSamuelson theorems,but in this case departing from the initial equilibrium trajectory leads to explosive prices instead of outputs. 7 A generalization of the results to a multisector framework will follow from the roots of (xk) and (wp), which now are matrices, and which are equal to each other if there are no external effects. It can be shown that only (wp) depends on external effects. Given any r>g, it is then possible to construct robust families of CobbDouglas technologies giving rise to indeterminacy for arbitrarily small external effects.

File: DISTL2 241409 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3967 Signs: 3257 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

67

changes in outputs, without severely affecting the output of the consumption. Therefore, with a third sector it becomes possible to construct examples of indeterminacy with _1, whereas in the two-sector model indeterminacy seems to hold for values of _ in a narrow range above 0. 8 Therefore, for a realistic parametrization and calibration of indeterminacy, we must turn to a three-sector model. Before focusing on the three-sector model, it may be useful to briefly compare our results to the other two-sector models in the literature. The model of Benhabib and Farmer [10] uses a two-sector model with sector specific externalities, but the production functions in the two sectors are identical so that compositional changes in production can affect returns only because of increasing returns in the form of sector specific external effects. The model of Gali [21] combines a setup of monopolistic competition with variable markups. Output is divided into a consumption and an investment good, and the composition of this division affects average markups and profits because the monopolistic competitors face demand curves that have different slopes for the consumption and the investment goods. The magnitude of average markups required, however, is large (see SchmittGrohe [29]). Gali's model is related to a model of Rotemberg and Woodford [28], which is also analyzed by SchmittGrohe [29]. The RotemberWoodford model has a variable markup that depends on aggregate economic activity, rather than a composition effect as in Gali [21].

3. THE THREE-SECTOR MODEL 3.1. The Basic Structure We again model an economy having an infinitely-lived representative agent with instantaneous utility given by U(c)=(1&_) &1 c (1&_) &(1+v) &1 L (1+v)

_, v0

where c is consumption, L is labor supply, v &1 is the labor supply elasticity and _ is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption. For simplicity of exposition we construct a three-sector rather than an n-sector 8 With nonlinear utility we will have indeterminacy in the two-sector model if the trace of [J ] is negative and its determinant is positive. It can in fact be shown that the trace will be negative under the assumptions of the proposition above because (ck)(xp) will be positive. For a positive determinant we must also assume that the term E in (12) is positive. However = cp appearing in E is endogenous. It can be computed as a function of parameters, and it is possible to produce examples of indeterminate steady states for positive but small values of _.

File: DISTL2 241410 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3267 Signs: 2562 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

68

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

CobbDouglas production technology with a consumption good c, and two investment goods, x and y. The agent's optimization problem is given by Max

|



0

(U(q c L :c0 K :xc1 K :yc2 L ac 0 K axc1 K ayc2 )&(1+v) &1 L (1+v) ) e &(r& g) t dt (13)

with respect to K xc , K yc , L c , L y , K xy , K xx , K yx , K yy , and subject to x=q x L ;x0 K ;xx1 K ;yx2 L bx0 K bxx1 K byx2 ,

(14)

y=q y L #y0 K #xy1 K #yy2 L cy0 K cxy1 K cyy2 ,

(15)

:0 c

:1 xc

:2 yc

a0 c

a1 xc

a2 yc

c=q c L K K L K K ,

(16)

dk x =x& gk x , dt dk y = y& gk y , dt K xx +K xy +K xc =k x ; K yx +K yy +K yc =k y ;

(17)

L x + L y +L c =L, with the initial stocks of k x and k y given. The components of the production functions, L bx0 K bxx1 K byx2 for x, L cy0 K cxy1 K cyy2 for y, and L ac0 K axc1 K ayc2 for c, represent output effects that are external and are viewed as functions of time by the agent. We can write the Hamiltonian as follows: H=U(q c L :c 0 K :xc1 K :yc2 L ac0 K axc1 K ayc2 )&(1+v) &1 L (1+v) + p x (q x L ;x0 K ;xx1 K ;yx2 L bx0 K bxx1 K byx2 & gk x ) + p y(q y L #y0 K #xy1 K #yy2 L cy0 K cxy1 K cyy2 & gk y ) +w 0(L&L x & L y &L c )+w x (k x &K xx &K xy &K xc ) +w y(k y &K yx &K yy &K yc ). Here p x , p y , w 0 , w x , and w y are the Lagrange multipliers which will represent the utility prices of the capital goods x and y, the rental rates of capital goods, and the wage rate of labor, all in terms of the price of the consumption good c. The first-order conditions, with respect to the inputs, are

File: DISTL2 241411 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 4038 Signs: 1256 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

69

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

w 0 =U$: 0 q c L :c 0 +a0 &1 K :xc1 +a1 K :yc2 +a2 =p x ; 0 q x L ;x0 +b0 &1 K ;xx1 +b1 K ;yx2 +b2 =p y # 0 q y L #y0 +c0 &1 K #xy1 +c1 K #yy2 +c2, w x =U$: 1 q c L :c 0 +a0 K :xc1 +a1 &1 K :yc2 +a2 ;1 +b1 &1 =p x ; 1 q x L ;x0 +b0 K xx K ;yx2 +b2

=p y # 1 q y L #y0 +c0 K #xy1 +c1 &1 K #yy2 +c2 , w y =U$: 2 q c L :c 0 +a0 K :xc1 +a1 K :yc2 +a2 &1 =p x ; 2 q x L ;x0 +b0 K ;xx1 +b1 K ;yx2 +b2 &1 =p y # 2 q y L #y0 +c0 K #xy1 +c1 K #yy2 +c2 &1 . If we define w 0 =U$w 0 ,

w x =U$w x ,

w y =U$w y ,

p x =U$p x ,

p y =U$p y ,

then the first-order conditions become: w 0 =: 0 q c L :c 0 +a0 &1 K :xc1 +a1 K :yc2 +a2 =p x ; 0 q x L ;x0 +b0 &1 K ;xx1 +b1 K ;yx2 +b2 =p y # 0 q y L #y0 +c0 &1 K #xy1 +c1 K #yy2 +c2,

(18)

w x =: 1 q c L :c 0 +a0 K :xc1 +a1 &1 K :yc2 +a2 ;1 +b1 &1 =p x ; 1 q x L ;x0 +b0 K xx K ;yx2 +b2

=p y # 1 q y L #y0 +c0 K #xy1 +c1 &1 K #yy2 +c2 ,

(19)

w y =: 2 q c L :c 0 +a0 K :xc1 +a1 K :yc2 +a2 &1 =p x ; 2 q x L ;x0 +b0 K ;xx1 +b1 K ;yx2 +b2 &1 =p y # 2 q y L #y0 +c0 K #xy1 +c1 K #yy2 +c2 &1 .

(20)

The first-order conditions with respect to L, after combining with the others, give the labor market equilibrium condition: v c (1&_): 0 L &1 c =L .

If we assume constant returns at the social level, we have a 0 +: 1 +: 2 +a 0 +a 1 +a 2 =; 0 +; 1 +; 2 +b 0 +b 1 +b 2 =# 0 +# 1 +# 2 +c 0 +c 1 +c 2 =1.

File: DISTL2 241412 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 4557 Signs: 997 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

(21)

70

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

The four equations of motion for the system are given by dk x dt x k = &g x ky dk y y dt

\+ \ +

\+ \ +

(22)

d(U$p x ) dt px wx =rU$(c) &U$(c) . py wy d(U$p y ) dt

\ +

\ +

(23)

To simplify Eq. (23), we define the following two matrices: c c p x = p c p x

c p y c p y

_ &

_ &

c c k x = k c k x

_ &

,

c k y . c k y

_ &

Evaluated at the steady state, where quantities and prices are stationary, Eq. (23) can be written as dp x dt p w U"(c) c =r x & x & py wy U$(c) dp y dt

\+

px c

0

0

py c

_ & \_ & \ + _ & \ ++ _ _ & _ && \ \ + \ + _ & _ &\ ++ \ + \ + \

_

} r

dp x dt c + k dp y dt

c p

= I&_

+

dk x dt dk y dt

&1

px c

0

0

py c

c p

px wx & +_ py wy

px c

0

0

py c

c k

(x&gk x ) ( y&gk y )

File: DISTL2 241413 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2556 Signs: 553 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

,

(24)

71

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

where _=(&U"(c) cU$(c)).With logarithmic utility of consumption, we have, of course, _=1. The first- order conditions given by Eqs. (18)(21), and the equations of motion given by (22) and (24), completely describe the system. 3.2. Three-Sector Dynamics We now linearize the dynamical system given by Eqs. (22) and (24), and we evaluate the associated Jacobian [JN] at the steady state. Let

[JN]=

_

k4

k4

_k& _ p& p* p* _k& _p&

&

where k4 =[[YK]& gI], k

_ & k4 _p& =[YP],

p* =[D] &1 _ p

_ &

0

0

py c

_ & _ _ &_ &

p* =[D] &1 _ k

_ &

px c

c

_k& [[YK]&gI],

px c

0

0

py c

c [YP]+[rI&[WP]] k

&

,

and where px c

_ _& & _ & _ & _ _ & _ &&

[D]= I&_

0

[WP]=

w x p x w y p x

c

_p&

w x p y w y p y

,

,

File: DISTL2 241414 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2207 Signs: 658 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

(25)

(26)

72

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

x

_k & y _k & x _p & y _p &

x

_k & y _k & x _p & y _p &

_ & _ & _ & _ & _ & _ &

[YK]=

x

x

[YP]=

x

x

y

,

(27)

,

(28)

y

y

y

c c p x = p c p x

c p y , c p y

(29)

c c k x = k c k x

c k y . c k y

(30)

In the appendix we show how the elements of the matrices [WP], [YK ], [YP], [cp], and [ck] can be evaluated using the steady state output elasticities and the steady-state values of the prices and quantities, all of which can be expressed in terms of the parameters of the economy. It is therefore possible to evaluate the roots of the Jacobian [JN] at the steady state and check for indeterminacy, that is, to check for parameter values that yield more than two roots of [JN] with negative real parts. The production parameters given below easily generate indeterminacy for our three sector economy, where the discount rate is r=0.05, the population growth rate is g=0.01, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption is _=1 (which implies logarithmic utility in consumption), and the inverse labor supply elasticity is v=1. Parameters for the Consumption Good c and Investment Goods x and y. q c =1,

: 0 =0.66;

: 1 =0.24,

: 2 =0.1; a 0 =0.00; a 1 =0.00,

a 2 =0.00;

q x =1,

; 0 =0.64; ; 1 =0.20,

; 2 =0.1; b 0 =0.00; b 1 =0.06,

b 2 =0.00;

q y =1,

# 0 =0.61;

# 2 =0.1;

c 2 =0.06.

# 1 =0.23,

c 0 =0.00;

c 1 =0.00,

Roots of the Jacobian [JN]. &10.8767, &0.0599, &0.8579, 0.1138. Clearly, the parameters above are entirely standard, and the external effects, which are present only for the capital input x in the production of x,

File: DISTL2 241415 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2693 Signs: 1457 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

73

and for the capital input y in the production of y, both of which are set to 0.06, are extremely small. The production functions of the three goods differ only slightly, with the labor share in each one of them given by : 0 , ; 0 , and # 0 , all at roughly equal to 23 . There are constant returns to scale at the social level and at the private level the agents face very slight diminishing returns to scale in producing x and y. Let us emphasize that the degree of perceived private decreasing returns in x and y is indeed negligibly small, while from the social perspective the CobbDouglas exponents add up to 1 and from the private perspective they add up to 0.94 for both x and y. Furthermore, indeterminacy seems very robust: Small variations in _, v, r, g, or in the production parameters do not change the values of the roots by much, nor do they change their sign pattern. Eliminating the external effects completely, however, does eliminate indeterminacy, as expected, because the private and social optimum coincide in that case. 9

4. THE STOCHASTIC DISCRETE TIME MODEL AND CALIBRATION The discrete time problem can be defined as V(k x , k y , z)=Max

1 (z c q c L :c 0 K :xc1 K :yc2 L ac 0 K axc1 K ayc2 ) (1&_) 1&_

\ +

&(1+v) &1 L (1+v) +\EV((1& g x ) k x +x, (1& g y ) k y + y, z$), x=z x q x L ;x0 K ;xx1 K ;yx2 L bc 0 K bxx1 K byx2 ,

(31)

y=z y q y L #y0 K #xy1 K #yy2 L cy0 K cxy1 K cyy2 ,

(32)

where \=(1+(r& g)) &1 is the discount factor, g x , g y are depreciation rates, z=(z c , z x , z y ), z i is a technology shock for i=c, x, y, where ln zi =` i , and ` i, t+1 =* i ` i, t + =^ i, t+1 ,

0* i 1,

9

(33)

It is also easy to construct examples of systems without externalities generating closed orbits or cycles as optimal paths, as in Benhabib and Nishimura [5]. For example if we set r=0.05, g=0.01, v=1, _=0.001, : 1 =0.0017, : 2 =0.459, : 0 =1&: 1 &: 2 , ; 1 =0.0265, ;2 =0.0012, ; 0 =1&; 1 &; 2 , # 1 =0.5635, # 2 =0.423, # 0 =1&# 1 &# 2 , then at _r0.020386, the Jacobian [JN] has two complex roots with zero real parts which become negative for higher _, and positive for lower _, satisfying the conditions of the Hopf Bifurcation Theorem for existence of closed orbits. We note that the family of cycles as a function of _ in the example occur for low discount rates, but a for utility function of consumption that is close to linear.

File: DISTL2 241416 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3830 Signs: 2226 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

74

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

i=c, x, y, and =^ i, t+1 is iid, normally distributed, and has mean zero. z$ is the value attained by z in the subsequent period. Note that we can write the consumption output as c=z c q c } (L&L x &L y ) :0 +a0 (k x &K xx &K xy ) :1 +a1 (k y &K yx &K yy ) :2 +a2. The first-order conditions, after simple substitutions, are

\ =\E c \

c &_ p x, t =\E c &_ t t+1 p x, t+1 p y, t c &_ t

&_ t+1

p y, t+1

w x, t+1

\p w \p

x, t+1 y, t+1

++ , +(1& g ) , ++ +(1& g x )

(34) (35)

y

y, t+1

where wx =; 1 q x L ;x0 +b0 K ;xx1 +b1 &1 K ;yx2 +b2 , px

(36)

wy =# 2 q y L #y0 +c0 K #xy1 +c1 K #yy2 +c2 &1 , py

(37)

px= py=

:1 +a1 &1 : 1 q c L :c0 +a0 K xc K :yc2 +a2

,

(38)

.

(39)

; 1 q x L ;x0 +b0 K ;xx1 +b1 &1 K ;yx2 +b2 : 1 q c L :c 0 +a0 K :xc1 +a1 &1 K :yc2 +a2 # 1 q y L #y0 +c0 K #xy1 +c1 &1 K #yy2 +c2

The equations for accumulation are given by k x, t+1 =(1& g x ) k x, t +x t ,

(40)

k y, t+1 =(1& g y ) k y, t + y t .

(41)

The computations for the analysis and calibration of this model are presented in Appendix II. Here we proceed directly to study the local dynamics. The linearized dynamics of the model are k x, t+1 k y, t+1

k x, t k y, t p^ x, t

p^ x, t+1 p^ y, t+1 z^ c, t+1 z^ x, t+1 z^ y, t+1

0 0

=[Q] &1 [R]

p^ y, t z^ c, t z^ x, t z^ y, t

&s^ x, t+1 +[Q] &1

&s^ y, t+1 =^ c, t+1 =^ x, t+1 =^ y, t+1

File: DISTL2 241417 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3770 Signs: 1052 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

,

(42)

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

75

where s^ i, t , i=x, y, are idd sunspot shocks with zero mean, acting on the ``Euler'' equations for the two capital stocks. The matrices [R] and [Q] are defined in Appendix II. Their elements are functions of parameters of the system, and of steady state quantities which are also functions of the parameters. We can therefore evaluate the roots of [Q] &1 [R] to check for the possibility of indeterminacy. When externality parameters are set to zero, four of the roots of the Jacobian matrix come in pairs of (+, 1\+), and the other three roots are the autoregressive coefficients of the technology shocks.10 For very modest externalities however indeterminacy arises, as it does in the continuous time case. The four roots no longer split with half inside and half outside the unit circle. We find that indeterminacy can easily occur for a large set of parameter values. The example below illustrates this point. We calibrate the model along the lines of a standard RBC model. We set the quarterly discount factor to r=0.036 and the depreciation rate to g=0.025, so that quarterly net discount is (r& g)=0.011. The instantaneous utility of consumption is logarithmic, so that _=1. Labor supply is taken to be quite elastic, although not infinitely elastic as is often the case in the real business cycle literature: We set v=0.2, implying a labor supply elasticity of 5. The persistence parameters for the technology shocks, * c , * x , and * y are each set to 0.95. The production parameters and the resulting roots of the Jacobian [[Q] &1 [R]] are as follows: Parameters for the Consumption Good c and Investment Goods x and y. q c =1, : 0 = 0.58; : 1 =0.15, : 2 =0.20; a 0 =0.00; a 1 =0.07, a 2 =0.00; q x =1, ; 0 =0.50; ; 1 =0.22, ; 2 =0.21; b 0 =0.00; b 1 =0.07, b 2 =0.00; q y =1, # 0 = 0.51; # 1 = 0.26, # 2 = 0.15; c 0 =0.00; c 1 = 0.00, c 2 = 0.08. Roots of the Jacobian [[Q] &1 [R]]. (0.251, 1.057, 0.967, 0.425, 0.950, 0.950, 0.950). The last three roots are simply the persistence parameters * c , * x , and * y . Of the remaining four roots, three are within the unit circle, which implies indeterminacy since there are two capital stocks and two prices. 11 Many other parametrizations giving indeterminacy are also possible, but the one above is the parametrization that we use in the calibrations below. 10

Here again, since \<1, there is the possibility of too many roots crossing and falling outside the unit circle even without external effects, making the steady state unstable and creating cycles on invariant circles via a Hopf bifucation, or cycles via flip bifurcation. Our concern here however is with too many roots inside the unit circle, a situation that implies indeterminacy. 11 The same parameters in the deterministic version of the model in continous time would yield the four roots: &0.72, 0.06, &0.03, &1.47. The three negative roots imply indeterminacy.

File: DISTL2 241418 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3792 Signs: 2829 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

76

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

To calibrate the model we set the standard deviations of sunspot shock s^ x, t , and the innovations to technology shocks =^ i, t+1 , i=c, x, y, all of which we take to be normally distributed, to 0.0039. 12 They are also set to imply a standard deviation for GNP of 1.76 to match the US data. In the simulations we take the technology shocks to be perfectly correlated, and the sunspot shock to be independent. Experimenting with independent technology shocks or with technology shocks correlated with the sunspot does not change the simulation results by much. The results of our calibration exercise are given in the table below.

St. Dev.

GNP

Consumption

Investment

Labor

1.00

0.74 (0.73) 0.53 (0.82) 0.97 (0.84)

3.32 (3.20) 0.83 (0.90) 0.92 (0.76)

0.70 (1.16) 0.71 (0.86) 0.80 (0.90)

Corr. with GNP 1.00 AR1 Coeff.

0.93 (0.90)

Standard deviations of the variables in the table are relative to those of GNP, and the numbers in parentheses are the same ratios for Hodrick Prescott filtered US data. Investment corresponds to its aggregated value, evaluated at the current relative prices of x and y. GNP contains consumption, c, and investment, with the price of the consumption good normalized to unity each period. Individual components of GNP, or of investment, tend to be much more highly volatile than the aggregated series. We find however that this is the case for standard RBC calibrations, irrespective of whether the chosen parameter values generate determinate or indeterminate equilibria. 13 The data generated by the model match US data reasonably well. Consumption is more weakly correlated with output for the data generated by the model than it is for actual US data: This in part may be because positive technology shocks initially lead to strong expansions in investment 12

Of course both sunspot shocks cannot be independently chosen: There is a joint restriction on the properties of the sunspot shocks and the innovations to technology shocks that is needed to guarantee that the solution remains stationary, and that the effect of the root outside the unit modulus is nullified. We choose the sunspot shock s^ y, t as a linear combination of the innovations to technology shocks and the sunspot shock s^ x, t in order to satisfy this restriction. We note that, alternatively, we could have picked s^ y, t independently and s^ x, t to satisfy the restriction, or simply chosen them jointly. 13 In multisector RBC models, in order to reduce volatility at the sectoral level and to insure that all sectors are procylical, it may be necessary to introduce adjustment costs for the movement of factors across sectors. See Huffman and Wynne [25].

File: DISTL2 241419 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3553 Signs: 2639 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

FIG. 1.

77

Simulated data.

at the expense of consumption. (See Fig. 2 and the preceding discussion.) In addition, labor data from the model are less volatile and less correlated with output than they are for actual US data. One possible reason for this, as we pointed out earlier, is that we used a labor supply elasticity of 5, compared to the infinite labor supply elasticities used in much of the RBC literature. Figure 1 gives a typical simulation with indeterminate equilibria and sunspots, calibrated to the parameters given above, for GNP, investment, and consumption. Clearly, investment displays oscillations of the largest amplitude while consumption is fairly smooth and GNP is in the intermediate range. Figure 2 shows the impulse responses for consumption, investment, and GNP generated by an aggregate productivity shock impacting the three sectors simultaneously. The aggregative shock leads to a surge of investment, initially at the expense of consumption. Again we find that this feature, that is, the initial negative response of consumption to the aggregative technology shock, typically arises for standard RBC calibrations of multisector models that do not have any external effects and therefore exhibit determinate equilibria. 14 GNP also drops by a small amount when the shock hits, but rises immediately afterward as investment surges, and then subsides to generate the hump-shaped response found in the data. 14 The impulse response function of consumption to a technology shock also exhibits the same behavior in the multisector model of Weder in this issue.

File: 642J 241420 . By:SD . Date:18:06:98 . Time:11:46 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2235 Signs: 1608 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

78

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

FIG. 2.

Impulse response for GNP, C, and I.

While we have by no means performed an extensive search, the model with the above parameters that generates sunspot equilibria can provide a reasonable match to the various moments of actual data. There exist many other reasonable parameter combinations that give a good match, and yet there are still others that give a very poor match to the data. Furthermore, some of the moments generated by the model can be sensitive to parameter changes in certain regions of the parameter set. This is true whether we have external effects and indeterminacy, or whether we restrict ourselves to standard parametrizations of the model without externalities and indeterminacy. Another feature, shared with calibrated multisector models without external effects or market distortions that have determinate equilibria, is that prices and outputs of the individual investment goods tend to be more volatile than the aggregated value of investment, with some sectors even exhibiting counter-cyclical behavior (see for example Benhabib, Perli, and Plutarchos [12]). This counter-factual observation about calibrated multisector models in the context of a determinate economy has led Huffman and Wynne [25] to introduce adjustment costs for the sectoral reallocations of factors of production. It seems therefore that multisector RBC models, with or without indeterminacy and sunspots, raise some new issues for the RBC literature. 15 More information concerning the moments of individual output 15 For an exploration of these issues in a three-sector model without external effects, market distortions, or indeterminacies, see Benhabib, Perli, and Sakellaris [12].

File: 642J 241421 . By:SD . Date:18:06:98 . Time:11:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2347 Signs: 1710 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

79

series must be considered to identify the best parametrizations and to assess how good the match is between the data and the simulations. Further disaggregation may be necessary to identify the sectors of the model with the actual sectors of the economy for which data is available. On the other hand it also seems likely that increasing the number of sectors will expand the range of parameters yielding indeterminacy, much as going from one to two to three sectors does. We view the above calibration exercise only as suggestive of interesting possibilities that can expand the scope of the RBC literature.

5. APPENDIX I:

THE CONTINUOUS TIME CASE

In this appendix we will derive the expressions necessary to evaluate the steady-state Jacobian of the linearized dynamics of the three-sector model in continuous time.

5.1. The Static Structure From Eqs. (33), (34), and (35) we can write: | 12 =

w x : 1 K yc ; 1 K yx # 1 K yy = = = , w y : 2 K xc ; 2 K xx # 2 K xy

(43)

| 10 =

wx : 1 Lc ;1 L x #1 Ly = = = , w 0 : 0 K xc ; 0 K xx # 0 K xy

(44)

| 20 =

wy :2 Lc ; L # L = = 2 x= 2 y. w 0 : 0 K yc ; 0 K yx # 0 K yy

(45)

If we denote x^ =dxx, then logarithmic differentiation yields the following: |^ 12 =K yc &K xc =K yx &K xx =K yy &K xy ,

(46)

|^ 10 =L c &K xc =L x &K xx =L y &K xy ,

(47)

|^ 20 =L c &K yc =L x &K yx =L y &K yy

(48)

Note that (| ij )=(| ji ) &1 and that (| ij )(| jh )=(| ih ). Now, combining equations (19), (20), (43), (44), and (45), and noting that at a steady state w x =rp x ,

w y =rp y ,

File: 642J 241422 . By:CV . Date:29:06:98 . Time:10:41 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2484 Signs: 1393 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

(49)

80

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

we have ;0 +b0

;0 ;1

;2 +b2

;2 ;1

\ \ + \ + + (| ) # # w =p q # \ \# + \ # + + (| )

w x =p x q x ; 1

#0 +c0

0

y

y

y

10

#2 +c2

1

2

#0 +c0

10

2

;0 +b0

2

(| 12 ) ;2 +b2 =rp x ,

(50)

(| 12 )  &c1 � &c0 =rp y . (51)

The exponential term (&# 1 &c 1 &# 0 &c 0 ) appears in Eq. (51) because the factor price ratios | 21 and | 20 in the equation are replaced by (| 12 ) &1 and (| 10 )(| 12 ) &1. Taking logs in (50) and (51) we can write them as:

\

\ \

;0 ;1 #0 ln r&ln q y # 2 #1

;0 +b0

;2 ;1 #2 #1

;2 +b2

\ \ + \ + ++ \ \ + \ + ++

ln r&ln q x ;

#0 +c0

#2 +c2

+

=M

ln | 10

\ln | + ,

(52)

12

where [M]=

; 0 +b 0

_ # +c 0

; 2 +b 2 . &# 1 &c 1 &# 0 &c 0

&

0

(53)

Equation (52) determines the steady-state values of | 10 and | 12 . We now solve, using (19), for the prices p x and p y . We have :1 qc

K yc K xc

\ +

(:2 +a2 )

Lc K xc

\ +

(:0 +a0 )

K yx K xx

\ + K =p # q \K + =p x ; 1 q x

(#2 +c2 )

yy

y 1

( ;2 +b2 )

y

xy

Lx K xx

\ + L \K +

( ;0 +b0 )

(#0 +c0 )

y

.

xy

Substituting from Eqs. (43), (44), and (45), we obtain :1 qc

:2 | 12 :1

(:2 +a2 )

:0 | 10 :1

(:0 +a0 )

\\ + + \\ + + ; ; =p ; q | \\; + + \\ ; + | + # # =p # q \\# + | + \\# + | + ( ;2 +b2 )

2

x

1

x

0

12

10

1

1

(#2 +c2 )

2

y 1

y

(#0 +c0 )

0

12

1

( ;0 +b0 )

10

1

File: DISTL2 241423 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3145 Signs: 918 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

.

(54)

81

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

Taking logs we then have q c : 1 : 2 (:2 +a2 ) qx ;1 : 1 q c : 1 : 2 (:2 +a2 ) ln qy #1 :1

\\ +\ + \ + \\ +\ + ln | +[N] \ln | + ln p x = ln p y

\

: 0 (:0 +:0 ) :1 : 0 (:0 +a0 ) :1

;2 ;1 #2 #1

&( ;2 +b2 )

\ + \ + \ + \+

ln

&(#2 +c2 )

;0 ;1 #0 #1

\ + \+

&( ;0 +b0 )

&(#0 +c0 )

10

+ +

+

(55)

12

where [N]=

_

: 0 +a 0 &; 0 &b 0 : 2 +a 2 &; 2 &b 2 . : 0 +a 0 &# 0 &c 0 : 2 +a 2 &# 2 &c 2

&

(56)

Eq. (55) allows us to solve for p x and p y , in terms of | 10 and | 12 , and then, using (52) and (49), for the steady-state values of the prices p x and p y and capital rentals w x and w y ; we will need them to evaluate the Jacobian matrix describing the local dynamics around the steady state. Furthermore, using Eq. (55) we obtain |^ 10

p^ x

\|^ + =[N] \ p^ + . &1

(57)

y

12

Now, taking logarithmic derivatives of Eqs. (50) and (51), we get w^ x ; 0 +b 0 ; 2 +b 2 = w^ y # 0 +c 0 # 2 +c 2

|^ 10 p^ x + |^ 12 p^ y

\ + _ &\ + \ + ; +b ; +b p^ = \_ # +c # +c &1& [N] +I +\ p^ + p^ =[G] \ p^ + . 0

0

0

0

2

2

2

&1

2

x

x y

(58)

y

Note that Eq. (58) defines the matrix [G]. 5.1.1. The Static Structure for the Two-Sector Case In a two-sector economy without the capital good y, either as an input or an output, the above expression for the elasticity of w^ x with respect to p^ x can be simplified. The matrix [N ] becomes a scalar and, since at a steady state w x =rp x , we obtain w^ x : 0 +a 0 w x =r =r . p x p^ x : 0 +a 0 &; 0 &b 0 We use this expression in Section 2 above.

File: DISTL2 241424 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2976 Signs: 1233 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

(59)

82

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

5.2. Unit Input Coefficients Computing unit input coefficients is straightforward. Taking logs of the production function for capital good x and using (43), (44), and (45), we have

_

; 1 +b 1 ; 2 +b 2 ; 0 +b 0 &1 1 0 &1

0

ln K xx ln k yx

&_ & & ln L x

1

ln x&ln q x = ln w x &ln w y +ln ; 2 &ln ; 1 ln w x &ln w 0 +ln ; 0 &ln ; 1

_

.

Solving, we get

a 11

Lx 1 = x qx xx

x

a 21

;1 +b1

;0 wx ;1 w 0

;2 +b2

;0 wy ;2 w 0

\ +\ + \ + K 1 ; w ; w = = \q +\ ; w + \ ; w + x K 1 ; w ; w = = \ q +\ ; w + \ ; w + x

a 01 =

yx

x

1

0

0

x

2

0

0

y

;0 +b0

;0 +b0

1

y

2

x

2

x

1

y

,

(60)

;2 +b2

,

(61)

.

(62)

;1 +b1

Similarly, for the consumption and second capital good we obtain

a 10

Lc 1 = c qc xc

c

a 20

yc

c

a 02

y

y

a 12

xy

y

a 22

:1 +a1

:0 wx :1 w0

\ +\ + K 1 : w = = \q +\: w + x K 1 : w = = \q +\ : w + c L 1 # w = = y \ q +\ # w + K 1 # w = = \q +\# w + y K 1 # w = = \q +\ # w + y

a 00 =

yy

y

1

0

0

x

2

0

0

y

0

x

1

0

1

0

0

x

0

x

1

0

\ + : w \: w + : w \: w + # w \# w + # w \# w + # w \# w +

:0 +a0

:0 +a0

#1 +c1

:2 +a2

:0 wy :2 w0

#0 +c0

#1 +c1

1

y

2

x

2

x

1

y

0

y

2

0

,

(63)

:2 +a2

,

(64)

,

(65)

:1 +a1

#2 +c2

1

y

2

x

0

y

2

0

,

(66)

#2 +c2

,

(67)

.

(68)

#2 +c2

File: DISTL2 241425 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3125 Signs: 811 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

83

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

Note that the input coefficients are functions of the ratios of factor rentals and can be written in terms of | 10 and | 12 , remembering that (|ij )=(|ji ) &1 and that (| ih )=(| ij )(| jh ). 5.3. Steady-State Quantities At a steady state we have y= gk y .

x= gk x ;

(69)

Full employment then requires

_

a 00

a 01

a 02

a 10 a 11 a 20 a 21

a 12 a 22

c

L

&\ + \ +

gk x = k x . gk y ky

(70)

We can solve for k x and k y as kx a 11 = I& g ky a 21

\ + _

_

a 12 a 22

&1

a 10

&& \a + c.

(71)

20

Let &=(1v). Then using (21), (69), and (70), we can solve, for steady-state c,

\

_

a 00 + g(a 01 a 02 ) I& g

_

a 11 a 21

a 12 a 22

&1

a 10

&& \a ++ c=: c

& (1&_) & 0

L && c ,

20

or, since L c =(a 00 )c, c=

:0 a 00

(&&)

\\ + \

_

a 00 + g(a 01 a 02 ) I& g

_

a 11 a 21

a 12 a 22

&1

a 10 a 20

+

&& \ +++ ,

(72)

where +=(&1(_&+1)). Using Eqs. (72) and (71) we can solve for steadystate k x and k y . Since unit input coefficients are functions of | 10 and | 12 , whose steady-state values are given by Eq. (52), the steady-state stocks k x and k y can be computed in terms of the parameters of the model. The steady-state outputs then are given by Eqs. (69) and (72). We can express the steady-state factor inputs in the production function as L c =a 00 c;

K xc =a 10 c;

K yc =a 20 c;

Lx=a 01 x;

K xx =a 11 x;

K yx =a 21 x;

L y =a 02 y;

K xy =a 12 y;

K yy =a 22 y;

File: DISTL2 241426 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2665 Signs: 1152 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

84

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

where, by construction L=L c +L x +L y , k x =K xc +K xx +K xy , k y =K yc +K yx +K yy .

5.4. Output Elasticities First we compute the elasticities of inputs with respect to | 10 and | 12 . From the first-order condition for labor given by Eq. (21) we have L =x 0 L c +x 1 K xc +x 2 K yc ,

(73)

where x0=

(: 0 +a 0 )(1&_)&1 ; v

x1=

(: 1 +a 1 )(1&_) ; v

x2=

(: 2 +a 2 )(1&_) . v

Using Eqs. (46), (47), and (48), it follows that L =(x 0 +x 1 +x 2 ) K yc +x 0 |^ 20 &x 1 |^ 12 .

(74)

The following identity,

_

Lc L c L K xc K xc kx K yc K yc ky

\ + \ + \ +

Lx L x L K xx K xx kx K yx K yx ky

\ + \ + \ +

Ly L y L K xy K xy kx K yy K yy ky

\ + \ + \ +

&

1 L 1 = k x k y 1

\+ \ +

(75)

may now be rewritten, after some substitutions using Eqs. (74), (47), (46), and (48), as

File: DISTL2 241427 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2085 Signs: 638 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

85

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

_

Lc

_

Lx

Ly

\ L +v+ \ L + \ L + K K K \k + \k + \k + K K K \k + \k + \k + xc

xx

xy

x

x

x

yc

yx

yy

y

y

y

&

K yc K yx

\+ K yy

(|^ 12 &|^ 10 )(1&x 0 )&(|^ 12 ) x 1 |^ 12 +k x = . k y

\

+

(76)

In particular, to derive the first equation of (76) we use (|^ 20 )=(|^ 10 )&(|^ 12 ) and _ x0 +x 1 +x 2 =& . v The equations given by (76) allow us to express the steady-state elasticities of K yc , K yx , and K yy with respect to |10 , |12 , k x , and k y . From the production functions, on the other hand, we have c^ =(: 0 +a 0 )(K yc &|^ 12 +|^ 10 )+(: 1 +a 1 )(K yc &|^ 12 )+(: 2 +a 2 )(K yc ) =K yc +(: 0 +a 0 )( &|^ 12 +|^ 10 )&(: 1 +a 1 )(|^ 12 ),

(77)

x^ =K yx +(; 0 +b 0 )( &|^ 12 +|^ 10 )&( ; 1 +b 1 )(|^ 12 ),

(78)

y^ =K yy +(# 0 +c 0 )( &|^ 12 +|^ 10 )&(# 1 +c 1 )(|^ 12 ).

(79)

Now notice that since K yc , K yx , and K yy depend on |^ 10 , |^ 12 , k x , and k y , and |^ 10 , |^ 12 in turn depend on p^ x and p^ y , we can now express the output elasticities of c, x, and y with respect to p x , p y , k x , and k y . We define the elasticity function of an m-vector q with respect to an n-vector p as an m_n matrix as E(q : p). Let the matrix in Eq. (76) be defined as _

Lc

[F ]=

_

Lx

Ly

\ L + v+ \ L + \ L + K K K \k + \k + \k + K K K \k + \k + \k + xc

xx

xy

x

x

x

yc

yx

yy

y

y

y

&

.

File: DISTL2 241428 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2853 Signs: 1064 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

86

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

Then we have 0 [E KK ]#E((K yc , K yx , K yy ) : (k x , k y ))=[F ] &1 1

0 0 .

_ & 0

1

Now define [S]=[N] &1. The price elasticities are [E KP ]#E((K yc , K yx , K yy ) : ( p x , p y ))

=[F &1 ]

_

(&S 11 +S 21 )(1&x 0 )&x 1 S 21 S 21

(&S 12 +S 212 )(1&x 0 )&x 1 S 22 S 22

0

0

&

where the elements of the matrix [S] are denoted by S ij . We will denote the ij th element of [E KK ] and [E KP] by E KK (i, j) and E KP (i, j). Substituting the elements of the matrices [S], [E KK ], and [E KP] into the production equations (77), (78), and (79), we obtain the output elasticities: E(c : p x )=E KP (1, 1)+(: 0 +a 0 )((S 11 &S 21 ))&(: 1 +a 1 ) S 21 , E(c : p y )=E KP (2, 1)+(: 0 +a 0 )((S 12 &S 22 ))&(: 1 +a 1 ) S 22 , E(c : k x )=E KK (1, 1), E(c : k y )=E KK (2, 1), E(x : p x )=E KP (2, 1)+(; 0 +b 0 )((S 11 &S 21 ))&( ; 1 +b 1 ) S 21 , E(x : p y )=E KP (2, 2)+(; 0 +b 0 )((S 12 &S 22 ))&( ; 1 +b 1 ) S 22 , E(x : k x )=E KK (2, 1), E(x : k y )=E KK (2, 2), E( y: p x )=E KP (3, 1)+(# 0 +c 0 )((S 11 &S 21 ))&(# 1 +c 1 ) S 21 E( y : p y )=E KP (3, 2)+(# 0 +c 0 )((S 12 &S 22 ))&(# 1 +c 1 ) S 22 E( y : k x )=E KK (3, 1), E( y : k y )=E KK (3, 2).

File: DISTL2 241429 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2306 Signs: 884 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

87

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

5.4.1. Output Elasticities for the Two-Sector Case Simpler expressions can be obtained for the case of a two-sector model. We will derive an expression only for (xk x ) in the two-sector case, to be used in Section 2 above. 16 Setting |^ 10 and |^ 12 to zero and using (44) and (47), the matrix equation (76) can be modified and written as:

_

_

Lc

Lx

\ L + v + \ L + K = 0 . \K + \k + K K \k + \k + xc

xx

x

x

&

xc

xx

(80)

x

Solving for K xx , L x we have,

K xx =

kL

Lc

_

\ Q +\ L &\ v ++ k

x

where

Q=L c K x &L x K c +

_ K x L. v

\+

(81)

Since |^ 10 has been set to zero, from (47), we get

L x =K xx &| 10 =

kL Q

Lc _ & L v

\ +\ \ ++ k . x

Using the input coefficients given by (63), (64), (67), and (68), but modified for the two-sector model, we obtain

\

Kc Q Kx _ L = 1+ & Lc Lx Lx v Lc Lc

+ \ \ \+ + + =

16

| _ L ; 1(1&a 0 &a 1 )&: 1(1&b 0 &b 1 )+; 1 : 0 . :0 ;0 v Lc

\

\+ +

A full characterization of the two-sector case is available from the authors.

File: DISTL2 241430 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2184 Signs: 846 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

88

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

Now the growth of the output x will be x^ =(; 1 +b 1 ) K xx +(1&; 1 &b 1 ) L x kx L Q

Lc _ + L v

\ +\ \ ++ k k L : ; = \L L +\ | + =

x

c

_

0

x

0

x

\\

Lc _ + L v

\ \ ++ ; 1(1&a 0 &a 1 )&: 1(1&b 0 &b 1 )+; 1 : 0

_ L v Lc

\+ +

+

k x

and we have

xL

x

:0 ; 0

\k+=\L L +\ | + c

x

\\

Lc

_

\ L + \v ++ _ L v Lc

\+ +

; 1(1&a 0 &a 1 )&: 1(1&b 0 &b 1 )+;1 : 0

+

.

However, noting that at the steady state w=rp= p;q x

;0 ;1 |

\\ ++

( ;0 +b0 )

=p;q x

;1 | ;0

\\ ++

( ;1 +b1 )

;0

\; |+ 1

and x ;1 | =q x Lx ;0

\ + \ +

( ;1 +b1 )

=

r|

\; + , 0

we obtain

x L =r k Lc

\ + \ + =

\\

\\

:0

L

_

\L + \ v ++ c

; 1(1&a 0 &a 1 )&: 1(1&b 0 &b 1 )+; 1 : 0

_

L

\v+ L + c

L

_

\ \L +\ v ++

r: 0 1+

c

; 1(1&a 0 &a 1 )&: 1(1&b 0 &b 1 )+; 1 : 0

_ L v Lc

\+ +

We use the expression (xk) as in Section 2.

File: DISTL2 241431 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2338 Signs: 569 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

+

.

+ (82)

89

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

6. APPENDIX II: THE DISCRETE TIME CASE The discrete time problem can be defined as V(k x , k y , z)=Max

1

\1&_+ (z q L c

c

:0 c

K :xc1 K :yc2 L ac0 K axc1 K ayc2 ) (1&_)

&(1+v) &1 L (1+v) +\EV((1&g x ) k x +x, (1&g y ) k y +y, z$), x=z x q x L ;x0 K ;xx1 K ;yx2 L bc 0 K bxx1 K byx2 ,

(83)

y=z y q y L #y0 K #xy1 K #yy2 L cy0 K cxy1 K cyy2 ,

(84)

where the discount factor is \=(1+(r& g)) &1, g x , g y are depreciation rates, z=(z c , z x , z y ), z i is a technology shock where ln z i =` i , ` i, t+1 =* i ` i, t += i, t+1 ;

0* i 1,

(85)

i=c, x, y, and = i, t+1 is iid, normally distributed, and has mean zero. z$ is the value attained by z in the subsequent period. Note that we can write the consumption output as: c=z c q c(L&L x &L y ) :0 +a0 (k x &K xx &K xy ) :1 +a1 (k y &K yx &K yy ) :2 +a2. The first-order conditions, after simple substitutions, are

\ =\E c \

p x, t =\E c &_ c &_ t t+1 p x, t+1 c &_ p y, t t

&_ t+1

p y, t+1

w x, t+1

\p w \p

x, t+1 y, t+1

y, t+1

++ , +(1& g ) , ++ +(1& g x )

y

(86) (87)

and the equations for accumulation are given by k x, t+1 =(1& g x ) k x, t +x t ,

(88)

k y, t+1 =(1& g y ) k y, t + y t .

(89)

Before analyzing the dynamics it is easy to show that the steady state of the dynamic system, (86(88), and (89), (85), with the random variables z c , z x , z y set to their long-run means, is identical to the steady state of the deterministic continuous time system if gx = g y = g. To see this set \=(1+(r& g)) &1 and note that at a steady state this implies 1+r& g=

w wx +(1& g)= y +(1& g). px py

File: DISTL2 241432 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3286 Signs: 1318 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

90

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

We can define q i =q i z i where z i is the long run mean of z i for i=c, x, y. The steady-state values of variables computed in the previous sections therefore remain as before. Quantity and price variables will now depend on the realizations of shocks as well, so to study the dynamics around the steady state we now have to compute the elasticities of input coefficients and of outputs that will incorporate the effects of the stochastic shocks. First we note that Eqs. (43)(45) as well as (76) remain unchanged. Equation (57) has to be slightly modified: |^ 10

p^ x +z^ x &z^ c

\|^ + =[N] \ p^ +z^ &z^ + . &1

y

12

y

(90)

c

In terms of elasticities, this implies that E(| 10 , | 12 : z x , z y )=E(| 10 , | 12 : p x , p y ), E(| 10 : z^ c )=&E(| 10 : p x ), E(| 12 : z^ c )=&E(| 12 : p y ). It follows therefore that E(c, x, y : z x , z y )=

0 1 0 +E(c, x, y : p x , p y ), 0 1

_0

&

(91)

E(c, x, y : z c )=(1 0 0)&E(c, x, y : p x )&E(c, x, y : p y ).

(92)

Note that the elasticities of (w x p x )and (w y p y ) 0 can be obtained from (58) after a slight rearrangement to incorporate the technology shock. Let r x =(w x p x ) and r y =(w y p y ). Then r^ x

; 0 +b 0

\r^ + =\_ # +c y

0

0

; 2 +b 2 [N] &1 # 2 +c 2 &1

&

p^ x +z^ x &z^ c

z^ x

+\ p^ +z^ &z^ + + \ z^ + . y

y

c

y

In terms of elasticities, this implies that E(r x , r y : z x , z y )=I+E(r x , r y : p x , p y ),

(93)

E(r x , r y : z c )=&E(r x , r y : p x )&E(r x , r y : p y ).

(94)

Note that E(r x , r y : p x , p y ) is simply given by the elements of the matrix ; 0 +b 0

\_ # +c 0

0

; 2 +b 2 [N] &1 . # 2 +c 2 &1

&

+

File: DISTL2 241433 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2660 Signs: 1333 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

91

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

Now we have all the elements to evaluate the Jacobian corresponding to the linear system evaluated at the steady-state. The relevant partial derivatives can be computed from the associated elasticities using steady-state values. To compute the appropriate Jacobian we note first that at the steady-state, \((w y, t+1 )( p y, t+1 )+(1& g y ))=1. A similar equation holds for the linearization of (87). We can express the linearized dynamics as percentage deviations from the steady state with the help of the following matrices:

[R 11 ]=

[R 12 ]=

[R 21 ]=

[R 22 ]=

R 13 =

R 23 =

_ _ _ _ _ _

\

k x((xk x )+1&g) x+(1& g) k x k x(yk x ) y+(1&g) k y

k y(xk y )

+ \x+(1&g) k + , k ((yk )+1&g) \ + \ y+(1&g) k + p (xp ) p ((xp )) \zx+(1& g) k + \zx+(1&g) k + , p (yp ) p (yp ) \ y+(1&g) k + \y+(1&g) k + k c k c &_ &_ \ c +\k + \ c +\k + , k c k c &_ &_ \ c +\k + \ c +\k + p c p c &_ \ c +\p + +1 &_ \ c +\p + , p c p c &_ \ c +\p + &_ \ c +\p + +1 z (xz ) z (xz ) z ((xz )) \x+(1&g) k + \x+(1& g)k + \x+(1& g) k + z (yz ) z (yz ) z (yz ) \ y+(1&g) k + \ y+(1&g) k + \ y+(1& g) k + z c z c z c &_ \ c +\z + &_ \ c +\z + &_ \ c +\ z + , z c z c z c & \ c +\z + &_ \ c +\ z + &_ \ c +\z + x

x

y

y

y

x

y

y

x

x

x

x

y

y

y

y

x

y

x

y

x

y

x

y

x

&

&

y

x

y

x

c

c

y

x

x

x

c

c

x

c

x

c

x

y

y

y

y

x

x

c

y

y

x

c

y

x

y

0 [R 31 ]=[R 32 ]= 0 0

&

y

x

&

y

y

x

y

0 0 , 0

_ &

File: DISTL2 241434 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2869 Signs: 1129 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

&

&

,

92

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

*c 0 [R 33 ]= 0 * x

_ _

0

0 0 *y

0

_ 0 1& ,

[Q 12 ]=

0 0 , 0 0

_ &

[Q 13 ]=

_0

[Q 23 ]=

R 32 ]

[R 13 ] [R 23 ] , [R 33 ]

&

1 0

[Q 11 ]=

[Q 22 ]=

,

[R 12 ] [R 22 ]

[R 11 ] [R]= [R 21 ] [R 31 ]

[Q 21 ]=

&

0 0 0

_ _ _

0 , 0

&

&_k x c &_k x c

\ \

c k x c k x

+\ + \ +\ + \

&_k y c &_k y c

_p x

r x

c k y c k y

+\ + +\ +

c

\p + & \ c +\p + +1 r _p c \p \p + & \ c +\p +

\p x

x

x

y

x

x

x

r x _z c & z c c r y _z c \z c & z c c

\z c

x

c z c c z c

\ + \ +\ + \ + \ +\ +

&

,

_p y

r x

c

\p + & \ c +\p + r _p c \p \p + & \ c +\p + +1 \p y

y

y

y

y

y

y

y

r x _z x & z z c r y _z x & z x c

&

,

c z x c z x

\ + \ +\ + \z \ + \ +\ +

\z x

x

r x

_z y

c

\z + & \ c +\z + r _z c \z \z + & \ c +\z +

\z y

y

y

y

y

y

y

[Q 31 ]=[Q 32 ]=[R 31 ],

File: DISTL2 241435 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2096 Signs: 492 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

y

&

,

93

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

1 0 [Q 33 ]= 0 1

0 0

0 0

1

[Q]=

_ & _

,

[Q 11 ] [Q 21 ]

[Q 12 [Q 22 ]

[Q 13 ] [Q 23 ]

[Q 31 ]

[Q 32 ]

[Q 33 ]

&

.

The linearized dynamics are then: k x, t+1 k y, t+1 p^ x, t+1 p^ y, t+1

k x, t k y, t =[Q] &1 [R]

p^ x, t p^ y, t

0 0 +[Q] &1

&s^ x, t+1 &s^ y, t+1

z^ c, t+1 z^ x, t+1

z^ c, t z^ x, t

=^ c, t+1 =^ x, t+1

z^ y, t+1

z^ y, t

=^ y, t+1

(95)

where s^ i, t , i=x, y is an iid sunspot shock with zero mean, acting on the ``Euler'' equations for the two capital stocks. Note that the elements of the matrices [R] and [Q] are functions of the parameters of the system, and also of the steady-state quantities which are functions of the parameters as well. We can therefore evaluate the roots of [Q] &1 [R] to check for the possibility of indeterminacy. When externality parameters are set to zero, as is well-known, the four of the roots of the Jacobian matrix come in pairs of (+, 1\+), and the other three are the autoregressive coefficients of the technology shocks. For modest externalities, however, it is easy to find large parameter regions for which there exist indeterminate equilibria, as the calibrated example in Section 4 illustrates.

6.1. The Calibration Equation (95) can easily be used to simulate or assess the stochastic properties of our dynamic system. In order to then obtain series for outputs c, x, and y, as well as their inputs, we must first express them as functions of ( p x , p y , k x , k y ). Using (43)(45), and (73), we can set up the matrix equation

File: DISTL2 241436 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 2978 Signs: 1397 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

94

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

|^ 10

[N] &1

|^ 12 |^ 10 |^ 12

y

[N] &1

x y

|^ 10 |^ 12 k x k y

=

[N] &1

x y

k x k y 0

0

=

p^ x

\ p^ + p^ \ p^ + p^ \ p^ +

0 1

0 0

0 0

&1 &1

0 0

0 0

1 0

0 0

0 0

K yc K yx

0 0 0

0 1 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

&1 &1 0

0 0 &1

0 0 0

1 0 0

0 0 1

K yy K xc K xx

0

0

1

0

K xy

0

&1 K xy kx

0

0

0 K xx kx

0

0

0 K xc kx

0

0

0

L c

K yc ky

K yx ky

K yy ky

0

0

0

0

0

0

L x

&x 2

0

0

&x 1

0

0

Lc Lx &x 0 L L

Ly L

L y

,

(96) where x 0 , x 1 , x 2 are as in Eq. (73). Equation (96), after inverting, will solve for K xc and K yc in terms of ( p^ x , p^ y , k x , k y ), so that we can obtain the associated elasticities. We now have all the elements of the Jacobian and we can analytically compute the variancecovariance matrix of the variables in Eq. (95), for contemporaneous as well as lagged values. Furthermore, using these we can easily compute a larger variancecovariance matrix that includes linear functions of the original variables, like the outputs of the three goods, and the aggregate value of investment or GNP.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We thank Jordi Gali, Stephanie SchmittGrohe, Sharon Harrison, Takashi Kamihigashi, Levent Kockesen, and Roberto Perli for very useful discussions and comments. Technical support from the C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics at New York University is gratefully acknowledged.

File: DISTL2 241437 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3057 Signs: 1147 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

INDETERMINACY AND CONSTANT RETURNS

95

REFERENCES 1. S. Basu and J. G. Fernald, ``Are Apparent Productive Spillovers a Figment of Specification Error?'' International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 463, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1994a. 2. S. Basu and J. G. Fernald, ``Constant Returns and Small Markups in U.S. Manufacturing,'' International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 483, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1994b. 3. M. Baxter and R. King, ``Productive Externalities and Business Cycles,'' Discussion Paper *53, Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, November 1991. 4. P. Beaudry and M. Devereux, ``Monopolistic Competition, Price Setting and the Effects of Real and Monetary Shocks,'' mimeo. 5. J. Benhabib and K. Nishimura, The Hopf bifurcation and the existence and stability of closed orbits in multisector models of optimal economic growth, J. Econ. Theory 21 (1979), 421444. 6. J. Benhabib and R. Farmer, Indeterminacy and Growth, J. Econ. Theory 63 (1994), 1941. 7. J. Benhabib and R. Perli, Uniqueness and indeterminacy: Transitional dynamics in a model of endogenous growth, J. Econ. Theory 63 (1994), 113142. 8. J. Benhabib and A. Rustichini, Introduction to the symposium on growth, fluctuations and sunspots, J. Econ. Theory 63 (1994), 119. 9. J. Benhabib, R. Perli, and D. Xie, Monopolistic competition, indeterminacy and growth, Ricerche Econ. 48 (1994), 279298. 10. J. Benhabib and R. E. Farmer, Indeterminacy and sector specific externalities, J. Monet. Econ. 37 (1996), 397419. 11. J. Benhabib and R. E. Farmer, ``The Monetary Transmission Mechanism,'' C. V. Starr Center of Applied Economics, Working Paper 96-13, New York University, 1996. 12. J. Benhabib, R. Perli, and P. Sakellaris, ``Persistence of Business Cycles in Multisector RBC Models,'' C. V. Starr Working Paper 97-19, New York University, 1997. 13. F. Black, Uniqueness of the price level in a monetary growth model with rational expectations, J. Econ. Theory 7 (1974), 5365. 14. M. Boldrin and A. Rustichini, Indeterminacy of equilibria in models with infinitely-lived agents and external effects, Econometrica 62 (1994), 323342. 15. C. Burnside, M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo, Capacity utilization and returns to scale, NBER Macroecon. Ann. 10 (1995), 67110. 16. C. Burnside, Production function regressions, returns to scale, and externalities, J. Monet. Econ. 37 (1996), 177201. 17. S. Chatterjee and R. Cooper, Multiplicity of equilibria and fluctuations in dynamic imperfectly competitive economies, Amer. Eco. ev. Papers Proc. 79 (1989), 353357. 18. L. J. Christiano and S. G. Harrison, ``Chaos, Sunspots and Automatic Stabilizers,'' NBER Working Paper 5703, 1996. 19. R. E. A. Farmer and J. T. Guo, Real business cycles and the animal spirits hypothesis, J. Econ. Theory 63 (1994), 4273. 20. R. E. A. Farmer and J.-T. Guo, The econometrics of indeterminacy: An applied study, CarnegieRochester Ser. Public Policy 43 (1995), 225272. 21. J. Gali, Monopolistic competition, business cycles, and the composition of aggregate demand, J. Econ. Theory 63 (1994a), 7396. 22. J. Gali, and F. Zilibotti, Endogenous growth and poverty traps in a Cournotian model, Ann. Econ. Statist. 37 38 (1995), 197213. 23. R. E. Hall, The relation between price and marginal cost in U.S. industry, J. Polit. Econ. 96 (1988), 921948.

File: DISTL2 241438 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 9459 Signs: 3355 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm

96

BENHABIB AND NISHIMURA

24. R. E. Hall, Invariance properties of Solow's productivity residual, in ``Growth, Productivity, Unemployment'' (P. Diamond, Ed.), pp. 71112, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1990. 25. G. W. Huffman and M. A. Wynne, ``The Role of Intertemporal Adjustment Costs in a Multi-Sector Economy,'' Working Paper, Southern Methodist University, 1996. 26. F. E. Kydland and E. C. Prescott, Business cycles: real facts and a monetary myth, Fed. Res. Bank inn. Quart. Rev., Spring (1990), 318. 27. R. Perli, ``Indeterminacy, Home Production and the Business Cycle: A Calibration Analysis,'' New York University Working Paper, 1994. 28. J. J. Rotemberg and M. Woodford, Oligopolistic pricing and the effects of aggregate demand on economic activity, J. Polit. Econ. 100 (1992a), 11531207. 29. S. SchmittGrohe, Comparing four models of aggregate fluctuations due to self-fulfilling expectations, J. Econ. Theory 72 (1997), 96146. 30. S. SchmittGrohe and M. Uribe, ``Balanced Budget Rules, Distortionary Taxes, and Aggregate Instability,'' Working Paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, 1996. 31. M. Weder, ``Indeterminacy, Business Cycles and Modest Increasing Returns,'' Humbolt University Working Paper, 1996. 32. Dangyang Xie, Divergence in economic performance: transitional dynamics with multiple equilibria, J. Econ. Theory 63 (1994), 97112.

















File: DISTL2 241439 . By:CV . Date:26:06:98 . Time:12:47 LOP8M. V8.B. Page 01:01 Codes: 3822 Signs: 1392 . Length: 45 pic 0 pts, 190 mm





Indeterminacy and Sunspots with Constant Returns

roughly constant, if not decreasing.3 While one can argue whether the degree of increasing returns required for indeterminacy in Benhabib and. Farmer [10] falls ...

2MB Sizes 1 Downloads 219 Views

Recommend Documents

Indeterminacy Under Constant Returns to Scale ... - Wiley Online Library
INTRODUCTION. RECENTLY THERE HAS BEEN a renewed interest in indeterminacy, or alternatively put, in the existence of a continuum of equilibria in dynamic economies that exhibit some market imperfections.2 One of the primary concerns of this literatur

indeterminacy and sunspots in macroeconomics
data. This chapter surveys this literature and places it in the context of other recent ..... the assumptions of the real business cycle model lead to big departures from its ... in advance and yet all markets may clear at all dates and agents may ha

Indeterminacy and Increasing Returns
We investigate properties of the one-sector growth model with increasing returns under two organizational structures ... We thank the C.V. Starr Center at NYU and the Risk Project of the Department of. Applied Economics at ... finding is that there e

Belief and Indeterminacy
A solution to this puzzle should tell us which of (a)-(c) to reject. A Putative Solution: Reject (c). This requires ... we have: I¬BT(b). • By (7) we have: BI¬BT(b). 3 ...

Embossing With Markers - Constant Contact
Layer 2: 5 1/8” x 3 7/8” Tangerine Tango Card. Stock. Layer 3: 5 x 3 ¾” Very Vanilla Card Stock. Inside Layer: 5 x 3 ¾”, stamped with crumb cake. “road grime” stamp. Instructions: Step 1: Using the road grime stamp, stamp the image mult

Belief and Indeterminacy
indeterminacy operator, I. Using the latter we can characterize the status of those ...... TрbЮ is a theorem, and that it is believed by Alpha on excel- ...... nicity of the function mapping extensions of T to formulas having semantic value 1 given

Linear Differential Equations With Constant Coefficients_Exercise 5.4 ...
devsamajcollege.blogspot.in Sanjay Gupta, Dev Samaj College For Women, Ferozepur City. Page 3 of 20. Linear Differential Equations With Constant Coefficients_Exercise 5.4.pdf. Linear Differential Equations With Constant Coefficients_Exercise 5.4.pdf.

Linear Differential Equations With Constant Coefficients_Exercise 5.5 ...
devsamajcollege.blogspot.in Sanjay Gupta, Dev Samaj College For Women, Ferozepur City. Page 3 of 17. Linear Differential Equations With Constant Coefficients_Exercise 5.5.pdf. Linear Differential Equations With Constant Coefficients_Exercise 5.5.pdf.

Trading on Sunspots
Nov 26, 2014 - in sunspot-contingent assets, this information would weigh down both the ..... The rich will take the other side of each s-security trade, and.

Introduction to Sunspots in Macroeconomics
sunspots can easily occur in standard real business cycle models or in models of ... petition or of technologies that exhibit external effects and are modelled in.

Enumerating indeterminacy - UNCG.edu
performer(s) with 25 pages of music played in any order and either rightside-up or upside-down.6 Enumerating all possible realizations is very similar to the. Queneau .... a number nearly as large as the number of atoms in our galaxy. General ...

Monopolistic competition, indeterminacy and growth
call 7' the amount of time devoted to the production of skills ..... Technical assistance from the C. V.. Starr Center for Applied Economics at New York University is.

Dealing with indeterminacy in spatial descriptions
Their data tend to show that ..... deal with indeterminate spatial descriptions in situations other than ..... there might not be enough room to insert the name of the.

Ramanujan's Constant
Jan 14, 2005 - important result is that j(q) is an algebraic number of degree n, where n is the class number of d. ... number 2, so j(q) would be an algebraic integer of degree 2, or a root of a quadratic. And so on for ...... Verlag, 2 nd. Ed., 1989

Fluctuations, and Sunspots: Confronting the Data
In recent years a relatively large body of research has explored and established the ... lived representative agents with cash-in-advance constraints or with money ..... simplicity of the model, we can give a global analysis of the equilibrium.

Anisotropic Bianchi type-I models with constant deceleration ...
Hubble's parameter, exact solutions of Einstein's field equations are ... of pressure, energy density and some other cosmological parameters are obtained for two different physical models. ..... We have presented an alternative and straight-.

On growth and indeterminacy: theory and evidence ...
A common theme in all the models with multiple equilibria that we con- ..... were to add an externality term 8(k), so all the (qualitative) results derived above for ...

PowerSchool and Constant Contact Information.pdf
Sign in. Loading… Page 1. Whoops! There was a problem loading more pages. PowerSchool and Constant Contact Information.pdf. PowerSchool and Constant ...

Bifurcation and sunspots in the continuous time ... - Wiley Online Library
We show that positive externalities can yield multiple steady states, a one-parameter family of homoclinic orbits, and a two-parameter family of periodic solutions. It is also shown that there exists a sunspot equilibrium in this model. Key words bif