Online Appendix to International Portfolios: A Comparison of Solution Methods Katrin Rabitsch∗

Serhiy Stepanchuk†

Viktor Tsyrennikov‡

August 31, 2015

1

Additional material to model specification 1

1.1 1.1.1

The role of the endogenous discount factor (EDF) and the tightness of the borrowing limit in shaping ergodic moments The role of the EDF, asymmetric version of model specification 1, section 4.2

0.015

global, η=10−3 global BL 0.01

local, η=10−3

frequency

global, η=10−4 local, η=10−4 global, η=10−5 local, η=10−5 global, η=0

0.005

0

−8

−6

−4

−2 0 2 NFA of country H

4

6

8

Figure A1: Ergodic distribution of NFA holdings in the asymmetric setting with σY i = 2σY i , f h for i = k, l, model specification 1. Labels ’global’ and ’local’ refer, respectively, to the global and DS solutions when the endogenous discount factor is present. Label ’global BL’ refers to the global solution when a borrowing limit is present.

To provide a deeper understanding of the role of the EDF in shaping ergodic moments, figure A1 plots the ergodic distribution of NFA for the three cases of table 4 (global and local solution with EDF and η = 10−3 , and ’global BL’), together with ergodic distributions for several parameter values of η. For a value of η = 10−4 the ergodic distributions reflect much more the underlying economic asymmetries of our parameterization, the means of the ∗

Vienna University of Economics and Business. E-mail: [email protected]. Ecole Polytechnique F´ed´erale de Lausanne. E-mail: [email protected] ‡ International Monetary Fund. E-mail: [email protected] †´

1

NFA distributions in this case (−1.397 for ’global η = 10−4 ’, and −1.740 for ’local η = 10−4 ’) are much closer to the model without EDF (’global BL’). However, it is also the case that the differences between local and global solutions become more pronounced in this case, ergodic mean consumption shares, domestic holdings of home and foreign equity are 0.456, 0.064 , 0.6311 for the ’global η = 10−4 ’, but 0.463, 0.163 , 0.652 for ’local η = 10−4 ’. For a value of η of 10−5 , the influence of the EDF on the ergodic distribution starts to vanish: the ergodic distribution of ’global η = 10−5 ’ is close to the one it converges to when η = 0, while the ergodic distribution of NFA when solved with the local method no longer produces a reasonable distribution of NFA holdings, it produces a very flat, near nonstationary distribution with a mean of −17.711. 1.1.2

The role of the EDF, asymmetric version of model specification 1, sensitivity analysis section 4.2.1

0.02 0.018 0.016

global, η=10−3 global BL

frequency

0.014

−3

local, η=10

global, η=10−4

0.012

local, η=10−4 0.01

global, η=10−5 global, η=0

0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 0

−8

−6

−4

−2 0 NFA of country H

2

4

6

Figure A2: Ergodic distribution of NFA holdings in the asymmetric setting with σY i = 2σY i , h f for i = k, l, model specification 1, sensitivity analysis with σY k = σY k = 0.03 and risk aversion h h coefficient of 15. Labels ’global’ and ’local’ refer, respectively, to the global and DS solutions when the endogenous discount factor is present. Label ’global BL’ refers to the global solution when a borrowing limit is present.

Figure A2 repeats the figure on ergodic distributions of NFA holdings for our sensitivity experiment. It shows ergodic distributions of NFA for the baseline parameter value of η = 10−3 (which corresponds to the simulation results in table 5), and also reports distributions for a lower value of η = 10−4 . For the global solution already η = 10−4 is a low enough value not to assert too strong an influence on the shape of the ergodic distribution and is close to the distributions implied by ’global η = 10−5 ’ or ’global η = 0’. On the other hand, at η = 10−4 the local method no longer produces a distribution within reasonable ranges of NFA holdings, its mean being at −40.697. 1.1.3

The role of the tightness of the borrowing limit

Figure A3 plots ergodic distributions of NFA under the global solution without endogenous discount factor but with exogeneous borrowing limits (BL), for both symmetric (left subplot)

2

and asymmetric (right subplot) settings of model specification 1. Ergodic distributions were computed from samples of 100 million simulated observations. 0.02

0.02

0.018

0.018 global, BL=0 global, BL=−1 global, BL=−2 global, BL=−3 global, BL=−5 global, BL=−7

frequency

0.014 0.012

0.014

0.01 0.008

0.012 0.01 0.008

0.006

0.006

0.004

0.004

0.002

0.002

0

−8

−6

−4

global, BL=0 global, BL=−1 global, BL=−2 global, BL=−3 global, BL=−5 global, BL=−7

0.016

frequency

0.016

−2 0 2 NFA of country H

4

6

0

8

−8

−6

−4 −2 NFA of country H

0

2

4

Figure A3: Stationary distributions of NFA under the global solution method with borrowing limit, for various values of borrowing limits, symmetric and asymmetric setting, model specification 1.

1.2

The role of the approximation point, section 4.2.2

In the analysis covered in the main text of the article, we have followed the convention to use the deterministic steady state as the approximation point in deriving the DS solution.1 It should be noted that the deterministic steady state in our model was only well defined because of the presence of the endogenous discount factor, which served as a remedy to the above mentioned problem of indeterminacy of the NFA at the deterministic steady state. In a stochastic world, the steady state distribution of NFA in our asymmetric country setting is influenced by all the factors that determine the (relative) strength of precautionary motives (such as the distribution of country specific risk faced by home and foreign households, or the menu of assets available for risk sharing), yet when looking at the deterministic steady state, we shut down exactly these forces. Instead, in the deterministic setting without stationarity inducing device there exists a whole continuum of steady state NFA position, as any Wh is consistent with the model’s system of equilibrium conditions at the deterministic steady state. It should be noted that this problem is not specific to portfolio choice problems, it arises even when only one asset is traded and an explicit portfolio choice problem is absent, for any incomplete markets models.2 But it is potentially more consequential in a setting with non-trivial portfolio choice, since under the DS method the solution for portfolio positions 1

This is also typically the route followed in most of the literature that has used the DS solution method. Consider a one-good two-country economy. Financial markets trade only a risk-free bond. Each period countries receive a deterministic endowment and decide how much to consume and save. The equilibrium conditions of this model: 2

qbt = βucht+1 /ucht , qbt = βucf t+1 /ucf t , qbt bh,t+1 + cht = bht + yht , cht + cf t = yh + yf ,

3

obtained depends directly on the steady-state value of Wh . While the endogenous discount factor pins down Wh uniquely and thus formally solves the problem of indeterminacy, it does so in a very exogenous way: the value Wh obtained is not based on the risk characteristics that determine the (mean of the) steady state distribution in a stochastic world. Instead it depends solely on the precise functional form of the endogenous discount factor. The value of Wh implied by our assumed endogenous discount factors (β(c) = βc−η for the home country, β(c∗ ) = βc∗−η for the foreign country), even in the asymmetric setting, still equals zero.3 This issue is inconsequential for models with symmetric countries where Wh = 0 is a ’natural’ candidate for a steady-state. But it may pose problems in models with asymmetric countries when the ergodic distribution of Wht is not centered around zero. It can be argued that this approach is not more satisfactory than simply postulating the desired level of Wh . While approximating around a well defined (unique) deterministic steady state is (because of the EDF) feasible, it is thus less clear that this value constitutes a ’good’ approximation point in the sense that most of the probability mass in a stochastic world will be centered around this point in an asymmetric setting. The concept of the risky steady state thus appears as an ideal concept to be employed as a better approximation point, in particular for the asymmetric setting of section 4.2, when we expect that an approximation point of Wh < 0 to more accurately capture features of the true ergodic distribution of NFA. Unfortunately, the DS solution method cannot be directly amended for use at the risky steady state in an asymmetric country setting. The ready-toapply closed-form portfolio solution formulas – the reason the DS method has become popular in the literature – rely on having equal rates of return at the point of approximation. This is true both for the formula for obtaining the zero-order, steady state, portfolio (the formula given by equation (43) of Devereux and Sutherland (2011))), as well as for the formula for obtaining first-order portfolio dynamics (the formula given by equation (48) of Devereux and Sutherland (2010)). Rates of return are equal, however, only if the deterministic steady state is used as an approximation point, or, at the risky steady state for the very special case with symmetric countries and assets with similar risk properties.4 In the setting where the determine the time paths of cht , cf t , bht , qbt , for a given bh0 . In a deterministic steady state, all equilibrium variables are constant: cht = c¯h , cf t = c¯f , bht = ¯bh , qbt = q¯b , ∀t. But at the constant values the two Euler equations reduce to the same qbt = β. As a result, one is left with two independent equations for three variables (¯ ch , c¯f , ¯bh ) leaving us with a continuum of solutions, one corresponding to each initial bond position ¯ bh0 = bh . 3 It should be noted, that it is indeed feasible to tie down a deterministic steady state position that is different from zero. This is true, e.g., for endogenous discount factor functions β(c) = βc−η for the home country, β(c∗ ) = β ∗ c∗−η for the foreign country, with β 6= β ∗ . The parameters β and β ∗ make it possible to capture structural differences in savings propensities across the two countries. For example, one could calibrate β and β ∗ to reach a certain desired Wh to match long-term averages of NFA positions in the data. Nevertheless, from a theoretical perspective, it remains unsatisfactory to base the approximation of a model around an exogenously determined steady state level of NFA, and this may lead to inaccuracies compared to the true solution. 4 This point is also noted by Julliard (2011), who looks at a portfolio choice model approximated around the risky steady state, but considers only a symmetric setup. Let us formally illustrate this claim for the solution formula of steady state portfolio holdings. Solving for the steady state portfolio relies on a second order approximation to the portfolio (Euler) equations (see Devereux and Sutherland (2011)), which for the 2 equity model (assuming CRRA preferences) is given by n o −γh Et cht+1 (rht+1 − rf t+1 ) = 0 Taking a second order approximation of the above expression in terms of variables in log deviations, x bt =

4

two countries display different shock volatilities, the return of the two countries’ equities will generally be different in the risky steady state. We explore two alternatives to the approximation around the value of Wh = 0 implied by the deterministic steady state (cum endogenous discount factor), in the following. Since we found the asymmetries/ differences between local and global method to be much more pronounced for the sensitivity setting of section 4.2.1, we do so for this setting directly. The two alternatives are as follows. One, we look at the ’stochastic steady state’ implied by the second-order approximative policy functions; in this, we follow an iterative procedure that looks for an ideal approximation point Wh , by continuously refining it using a heuristic procedure described in Devereux and Sutherland (2009). This procedure shares the principle idea with the risky steady state literature, in that the approximation point is found from the relative risk profiles of the two countries. It seems reasonable to approximate the model solution around the level of NFA that the economies tend to ’on average.’ Starting at some initial approximation point for the NFA (say Wh = 0), we derive the NFA position that results as a rest point of the economy when it is ’hit’ in every period by the mean values of the shock vector (that is, we compute the expected path of the NFA positions, as implied by the second order perturbation solution). The resulting NFA position can be used as a new approximation point and the whole procedure repeated.5 This procedure is not guaranteed to converge but it does in most cases. Applying this algorithm to the sensitivity case of our asymmetric setting of section 4.2.1, we find that the iterative procedure performs rather poorly: it converges to a net foreign asset position of Wh = −7.318, a point that is far off from the true mean of the ergodic NFA position (−2.526 in ’global’). Two, we consider the mean of the ergodic distribution of net foreign assets obtained from having solved the model with the global method, representing the closest match to the true ergodic distribution. In the general case, in which one wants to apply the DS method to a given DSGE model, the ’true’ ergodic distribution from the global solution is unknown, so this is not a feasible exercise in general. In our sensitivity asymmetric setting, the mean of the ergodic NFA distribution (for ’global’) is found to be equal to −2.526. Table A1 summarizes our findings. It presents the ergodic means and standard deviations generated using the global solution (with EDF and with BL) and the perturbation solution without (Wh = 0), with approximation point updating (Wh = −7.318), and with using the mean of the ergodic NFA distribution from the global method as an approximation point  ln Xt /X , doing the same for the foreign investor’s Euler equation and combining both, we get:   − (rh − rf ) [γ cht+1 − γf b cf t+1 ]    hb  + 12 (rh − rf ) γh2 b c2ht+1 − γf2 b c2f t+1 Et   − [γh b cht+1 − γf b cf t+1 ] (rh rbht+1 − rf rbf t+1 ) If and only if we have rh = rf , it follows that we get DS’ formula from which the closed-form expression for the steady state portfolio, α e, can be obtained. Whenever rh 6= rf , then solving for α e requires knowledge of second order solution, and the analytic formula for α e can no longer be applied. The logic for the formula for obtaining first order portfolio dynamics is similar. Unless rh = rf , higher order terms appear in the third-order approximation of the portfolio (Euler) equations that precludes application of the closed order formula for first-order portfolio dynamics, γ. 5 Importantly, this procedure only updates the NFA position to its ’stochastic steady state’, and leaves the approximation point for all other economic variables to be equal to their deterministic steady state values. This procedure is thus consistent with application of the DS (closed form) portfolio solution formulas. We thank Alan Sutherland for laying out the details of their routine to find the approximate stochastic steady state NFA position.

5

global

NFAh ch θhh θfh qh qf

µ(.) -2.526 0.434 -0.023 0.585 5.754 5.743

σ(.) 1.286 0.034 0.150 0.076 0.270 0.293

global BL

µ(.) -4.374 0.386 -0.232 0.474 5.760 5.749

σ(.) 1.116 0.029 0.125 0.075 0.274 0.297

local no updating Wh = 0 µ(.) σ(.) -4.132 1.737 0.403 0.037 -0.208 0.203 0.490 0.100 5.758 0.270 5.746 0.293

local with updating Wh = −7.318 µ(.) σ(.) -6.942 1.556 0.329 0.041 -0.540 0.176 0.335 0.088 5.755 0.270 5.744 0.293

local ergodic µ(N F A) Wh = −2.526 µ(.) σ(.) -5.099 1.627 0.375 0.037 -0.323 0.189 0.438 0.094 5.755 0.270 5.744 0.293

Table A1: Comparison of ergodic model moments in the asymmetric setting with σ f = 2σ h and η = 0.001, model specification 1, RA = 15. Columns ’global’ and ’local’ refer, respectively, to the global and DS solutions when the endogenous discount factor is present. Column ’global BL’ refers to the global solution when a borrowing limit is present.

(Wh = −2.526). Attempts at improving the performance of the DS method by searching for a more appropriate approximation point are unsuccessful.

2 2.1

Additional material to model specification 2 Varying the size of uncertainty

It is natural to expect the solution based on a local approximation method to perform worse as the size of shocks increases, since large shocks make it more likely that the model’s variables will depart further away from their values at the approximation point. In addition to this, as discussed in Rabitsch and Stepanchuk (2014), the DS method neglects a (direct) dependence of the portfolio solution on the size of uncertainty. Following Schmitt-Groh´e and Uribe (2004) and Jin and Judd (2002) we can think of the true policy function in a recursive economy as a function that depends on the model’s state variables, xt , and on a parameter that scales the variance-covariance matrix of the model’s exogenous shock processes, σ; that is, αt = α (xt , σ). A Taylor series to policy function αt , evaluated at approximation points xt = x and σ = 0, would then result in: 1 0 1 αt = α (x, 0) + αx (x, 0) x b αxx (x, 0) x bt + ασ (x, 0) σ + x bt + αxσ (x, 0) x bt σ + ασσ (x, 0) σ 2 + ... 2 t 2 (1) That is, in contrast to the Taylor series expansion in equation (1) the DS approximate portfolio solution only considers how variations in the model’s state variables affect the optimal portfolio solution, but ignores the effect of variations in the size of uncertainty. This can further compromise the performance of the perturbation-based method. To investigate this possibility, this section studies the behavior of global and DS solution as we change the size of uncertainty in the model. Figure A4 summarizes the results. For simplicity, to make changing the size of uncertainty easier, we assume in this section that all shocks have the same size, and are uncorrelated. This means that compared to table 6, we make 2 changes: (1) we set σY l = σY l = σY k = σY k = σ, and (2) set cor(Yhk , Yhl ) = cor(Yfk , Yfl ) = 0. We then h f h f change the size of uncertainty in the model by varying σ. h and bh , Panels A and B of figure A4 show the portfolio positions in equity and bond, θht t that correspond to an end-of-period net foreign asset position equal to 0 and exogenous shocks 6

equal to their unconditional means (Wht = 0,Yt = Et (Yt )), as predicted by the global (solid line) and local (dashed line) solutions. Reminiscent of our findings in a two-period model in Rabitsch and Stepanchuk (2014), we find that the portfolio positions obtained from the local (DS) method do not change with the size of uncertainty, σ. On the other hand, equity holdings under the global solution decrease, and bond holdings under the global method increase, as σ increases from 0.001 to 0.1. This is also consistent with the results in Rabitsch and Stepanchuk (2014) and Judd and Guu (2001)6 , who find that the true non-linear solution depends on the size of shocks, with higher-order moments of the distribution of the shocks such as skewness and kurtosis of the shocks (equal to the skewness and kurtosis of equity returns in that simple model) affecting the results. Panels G and I of figure A4 show the oneperiod-ahead skewness and kurtosis of equity returns at Wht = 0 and Yt = Et (Yt ). Skewness is positive, and both skewness and kurtosis of returns increase as σ increase. Rabitsch and Stepanchuk (2014) find that in a two-period setting with the foreign investor being more riskaverse than the domestic investor, and with positive skewness of equity returns, the first-order coefficient in an asymptotic Taylor approximation to the equity position obtained by Judd and Guu (2001) is positive, leading the domestic investor to take a larger equity position, while the second-order coefficient is negative, leading to the opposite result with the foreign investor taking a larger equity position. They also find that for a realistic calibration, using data from the United Kingdom, the second-order effect dominates.7 This is also what we get here, with the equity position of the domestic investor under the global solution decreasing as the size of the shocks, σ, goes up. Panels E and F of figure A4 show that at σ = 0.1, the equity premium in our model reaches a reasonable size of 2.8%. However, σ = 0.1 is quite higher than the size of shocks usually assumed in the dynamic macroeconomic models. Panel D of figure A4 shows that the DS solution underestimates the size of the equity return compared to the global solution. As a result, as shown in panel C, the NFA position in the last period (T=100) of our short simulations on average is higher according to the global solution. Note that, as pointed out above, panels A and B of figure A4 show the portfolio positions consistent with the endof-period net foreign assets equal to zero, Wht = 0. Figure 2.1 in the appendix shows the portfolio positions that correspond to beginning-of-period net foreign assets equal to zero, h (and bh ) were found to be constant with respect to Wht−1 = 0.8 While the DS solution of θht t changes in the size of uncertainty when plotted as a function of Wht = 0, documenting the lack of a direct dependence of the portfolio solution on σ, we observe it to decrease (increase) as σ increases when Wht−1 = 0. Similarly, while, under the global method, the equity position of the domestic investor in figure A4 decreases with σ, the one in figure 2.1 is in fact increasing with σ. The portfolio positions in figure 2.1 more closely correspond to the NFA(T) in figure A4, since we always start with the beginning-of-period net foreign assets, Wht−1 , equal to zero to obtain the simulated NFA(T). However, those portfolio positions also reflect the reaction of the consumption and savings decisions to the size of uncertainty in our model. Through the dependence of state variables on the size of uncertainty, portfolio solutions are affected 6 Judd and Guu (2001) develop a Taylor series approximation to the portfolio positions in a static two-period model, using a bifurcation method to solve for the approximation coefficients. Rabitsch and Stepanchuk (2014) compare this solution to the one obtained using the DS and global methods. 7 Note that compared to the 2-period model case, in this paper with long-lived equity the equity returns are endogenous. This means that we cannot change their skewness and kurtosis separately. 8 In our two-period model such distinction is not relevant and not applicable; the NFA position is always zero.

7

by variations in the scale of shocks indirectly. As a result, the DS portfolio solutions in that figure loose the ’invariance to the size of uncertainty’ property which we find in the static model in Rabitsch and Stepanchuk (2014). A. Equity position

B. Bond position

0.061

-0.3649 global local

0.0605

global local

-0.365 -0.3651

0.06

-0.3652

0.0595

-0.3653

0.059

-0.3654

0.0585

-0.3655

0.058

-0.3656 0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.1 size of shocks

0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.1 size of shocks

C. NFA(T)

D. Discrepancy in equity premium

0.25

0.00016 0.00014 0.00012 0.0001 8e-005 6e-005 4e-005 2e-005 0

global local

0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 size of shocks

0.1

RX(global)-RX(local)

0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.1 size of shocks

E. Mean equity returns 1.061 1.06 1.059 1.058 1.057 1.056 1.055 1.054 1.053 1.052

F. Mean bond returns 1.054 1.052 1.05 1.048 1.046 1.044 1.042 1.04 1.038 1.036 1.034 1.032

global local

0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 size of shocks

0.1

global local

0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 size of shocks

G. Equity return skewness 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0

H. Equity return kurtosis 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.3 4.2 4.1 4 3.9 3.8

global

0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09

0.1

0.1

global

0

size of shocks

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 size of shocks

Figure A4: Varying the size of uncertainty, σ, model specification 2. Labels ’global’ and ’local’ refer, respectively, to the global and DS solutions when the endogenous discount factor is present.

8

0.1

A. Equity position

B. Bond position

0.0613

-0.3605 global local

0.0612

global local

-0.361 -0.3615

0.0611

-0.362

0.061

-0.3625 0.0609 -0.363 0.0608 -0.3635 0.0607 -0.364 0.0606

-0.3645

0.0605

-0.365

0.0604

-0.3655

0.0603

-0.366 0

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.1

0

size of shocks

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.1 size of shocks

Figure A5: Portfolio solutions when varying the size of uncertainty and when beginning-ofperiod NFA, Wht−1 , equals zero, model specification 2.

Labels ’global’ and ’local’ refer, respectively, to the global and DS solutions when the endogenous discount factor is present.

9

References Devereux, M. B. and Sutherland, A. (2009). A portfolio model of capital flows to emerging markets. Journal of Development Economics, 89:181–193. Devereux, M. B. and Sutherland, A. (2010). Country portfolio dynamics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34:1325–1342. Devereux, M. B. and Sutherland, A. (2011). Country portfolios in open economy macro models. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(2):337–369. Jin, H.-H. and Judd, K. (2002). Perturbation methods for general dynamic stochastic models. Manuscript, Stanford University. Judd, K. and Guu, S. (2001). Asymptotic methods for asset market equilibrium analysis. Economic Theory, 18:127–157. Julliard, M. (2011). Local approximation of dsge models around the risky steady state. mimeo. Rabitsch, K. and Stepanchuk, S. (2014). A two period model with portfolio choice: Understanding results from different solution methods. Economics Letters, 124(2):239–242. Schmitt-Groh´e, S. and Uribe, M. (2004). Solving dynamic general equilibrium models using a second-order approximation to the policy function. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28:755–775.

10

Online Appendix to International Portfolios: A ...

Aug 31, 2015 - International Portfolios: A Comparison of Solution Methods. Katrin Rabitsch∗. Serhiy Stepanchuk† ... vanish: the ergodic distribution of 'global η = 10−5' is close to the one it converges to when η = 0, while the ergodic ..... A portfolio model of capital flows to emerging markets. Journal of Development ...

357KB Sizes 0 Downloads 125 Views

Recommend Documents

International Portfolios: A Comparison of Solution ...
Aug 31, 2015 - 2Because of their relative ease of implementation local solution methods are a default choice when it comes to solving medium- and .... Gourinchas and Rey (2013) document that advanced economies typically have a ..... In this case the

Online Appendix to
Online Appendix to. Zipf's Law for Chinese Cities: Rolling Sample ... Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, eds. V. Henderson, J.F. Thisse, 4:2341-78.

Online Appendix to
The model that controls the evolution of state z can be written as zt. = µz .... Members of survey A think of the signal θA as their own, but can observe both.

Online Appendix to
Sep 27, 2016 - data by applying the pruning procedure by Kim et al. .... “Risk Matters: The Real Effects of Volatility Shocks,” American ... accurate solutions of discrete time dynamic equilibrium models,” Journal of Economic Dynamics &.

Online Appendix to
Nov 3, 2016 - 0.03. 0.03. 0.03. 0.02. 0.04. 0.04. 0.04. 0.04. Note . Robust standard errors b et w een paren theses, r ob us t-standard-error-based. p-v alues b et w een brac k ets. ∆. Cr e d is the gro w th rate of real lending b y domestic banks

Online Appendix
Aug 13, 2013 - Online Appendix Figures 3a-4e present further evidence from the survey .... Control variables include age, gender, occupation, education, and ...

Online Appendix
Power Capital Variables adds up all ranking positions by terms (excluding the above top 4 positions). 2 ever held by native officials connected to a commune (in.

Online Appendix
Aug 13, 2013 - Online Appendix Figures 3a-4e present further evidence from the survey responses on the .... Notes: Data from a survey of 70 individuals in 9 villages. ...... You will stay in the assigned room for 20 minutes listening to a.

Online Appendix
Length of business registration in days. 2. Land access sub-score ..... Trends. Province trends. Cluster. Commune. Commune. Commune. Commune. Province.

Online Appendix
When γ = 1, Equation 3 becomes α(p – c) = 1 + exp(δ – αp). The left-hand ... We averaged daily five-year maturity credit default swap (CDS) spreads on GM debt.

Not-for-Publication Appendix to “An International Dynamic Term ...
data YT , calculate estimates for ft as E(ft|YT ,φ(n)). To this end, notice that the ... Thus, we can safely apply our inter-battery factor analysis to de- meaned data.

Technical Appendix to INTERNATIONAL TRENDS IN ...
We used Python to parse the XML files and extracted the necessary ... example, if yJP,11,1980 ј h, this means that considering the patents granted in 1980 for.

International Portfolios with Supply, Demand and ...
to the relative demand for home vs. foreign goods, and to the distribution of income .... that any investor can purchase any security without transaction costs. ...... discount factors, while ,0 is the vector of excess returns on the two stocks and t

Online Appendix to Exogenous Information ...
“Exogenous Information, Endogenous Information and Optimal Monetary Policy.” 1 ..... are standard values in the business cycle literature. Similar values ... In this online Appendix C there are no technology shocks because in Section 5 of the pap

Online Appendix to “Hard Times” - LSE
Aug 27, 2012 - of Business, University of Chicago, 5807 S. Woodlawn Ave., Chicago IL ... Polk: Department of Finance, London School of Economics, London.

Appendix A: Timing - Hand Cannon Online
If activating a unit, repeat steps 6 and 7 for all troopers, ... Compiled by brotherscott from Warmachine Prime MK II Pages 244 & 245 and Hordes Primal MK II, ...

A Online Appendix - University of Rochester
For the remaining models, the policy outcome depends on the identity of the majority party. I let. xD(s;α) denote the policy outcome if the Democratic Party controls the chamber and I let xR(s;α) denote the policy outcome if the Republican Party co

A Online Appendix - University of Rochester
correlation between ideal points estimated using the relative proximity model on cosponsorship data and conventional estimates is lower, suggesting that if cosponsorship and voting are governed by the same ideal points, the data are most consistent w

Online Appendix
War Draw. 0.006. 0.077. 0. 1. Civil War. 0.109. 0.312. 0. 1. Wealth (unlogged) ..... Sri Lanka. 1968. 2004. 0.405. 0.725. 3. 0.568. 0.835. 3. Sudan. 1968. 2004.

Online appendix
May 22, 2015 - Real estate and business services. Construction ... Wages to skilled (log). 0. 5. 10. 15. 20 year ... All unskilled workers (log). 2000. 2002. 2004.

Online Appendix
∗Department of Decision Sciences and IGIER, Bocconi University, email: [email protected]. †Department of Economics and IGIER, Bocconi University, email: [email protected]. 1 ...... S1.37.11: I believe the intermediary or online