Separate Appendix (Not for publication) to “The World Has More Than Two Countries: Implications of Multi-Country International Real Business Cycle Models” Hirokazu Ishise∗ February 18, 2014

Contents A Data

3

A.1 G7 business cycle moments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3

A.2 Size of G7 countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3

B Models



5

B.1 Computation and calibration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

5

B.2 Single-good models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

5

B.2.1 Households . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

5

B.2.2 The baseline production technology and the shock process . . . . . . . . . . .

6

B.2.3 Resource constraint . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

6

B.3 Modified versions of single-good models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

6

B.3.1 Time-to-build . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

7

B.3.2 Adjustment friction and variable utilization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

7

B.3.3 Resource constraints in case of a complete market and trade cost . . . . . . .

7

B.3.4 Resource constraints in a bond market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

8

B.4 One-good-per-country models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

8

B.4.1 Household problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

8

B.4.2 Complete market case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

8

B.4.3 Non-state contingent bond case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

9

B.4.4 A generalization of financial autarky . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

9

B.4.5 Final goods producer problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

9

B.4.6 Intermediate goods producer . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

10

B.4.7 Market clearing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

10

B.5 Derivation of single-good models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

10

B.5.1 Equilibrium conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

12

B.5.2 Transformed equilibrium conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

14

ISER, Osaka U. (Email: [email protected]) Data and programs are available on request.

1

B.5.3 Non-stochastic steady state . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

17

B.5.4 Log-linearized equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

18

B.6 Derivation of one-good-per-country models

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

20

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

20

B.6.2 Transformed economy equilibrium conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

23

B.6.3 Non-stochastic steady state . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

24

B.6.4 Log-linearized equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

28

B.6.1 Models

C Robustness Tables

32

D Impulse Response Functions and Intuition

42

2

A

Data

A.1

G7 business cycle moments

Table A1 shows key real business cycle moments. Intra-country moments are obtained from the median (mean) of the G7 countries: Canada, France, (West) Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States. The main data sources are quarterly national accounts on “SourceOECD.” If longer data is available through a country source or older SNA system, the main economic indicator data is extrapolated using the growth rates of additional data. All the variables are seasonally adjusted quarterly data. The real values in the data sets are used. Hours and employment are normalized by year 2000 values (average of four quarters in 2000), and then multiplied to obtain labor. Italian labor is calculated only using employment data, since the hours data is missing. Filtering is applied for the longest possible dataset, and then moments are calculated using a limited sample period (1970, 1st quarter to 2006, 4th quarter). The data for Germany and West Germany are combined after filtering. Excluding net exports, variables are taken from natural logs, after which filters are applied. Net exports are filtered after the figures have been divided by real GDP. Further details are explained in the dataset, which is available on request. Cross-country correlations are the medians (means) of the possible 21 (= 7 × 6/2) combinations of cross-country correlations. Table A1 includes U.S. statistics. U.S.-foreign cross-country correlations are the median of the possible six cross-country correlations. The last column shows model moments. The model is a straightforward extension of a textbook closed-economy business cycle model (King et al., 1988) to a two-country, connecting, complete set of state contingent claims, with standard parameterizations.

A.2

Size of G7 countries

In the models, each country has an equivalent steady state per capita output, because of the symmetry of the utility and technologies. The population weight captures both population size and economic size. The economic size is used for considering business cycle properties of developed countries. The data is from Penn World Table 6.2 (Heston et al., 2008). Country GDP is real GDP per capita chain (rgdpch) times total population (POP ). Calculations are the data for 1970, 1985 and 2000. The total world GDP is the sum of the GDPs of all the available countries. The ratios for the United States’s GDP to total world GDP are 26% in 1970, 24% in 1985 and 21% in 2000; for Japan’s are 8% in 1970, 9% in 1985 and 7% in 2000. Similarly, the ratios for Germany’s GDP to the total world GDP for the three years are: 8%, 6% and 5%; for the United Kingdom: 5%, 4% and 3%; for France: 5%, 4% and 3%; for Italy: 4%, 4% and 3%; and for Canada: 2%, 2% and 2%.

3

Table A1: G7 Business Cycle Moments Country

G7 Median Filter BP Standard deviation relative Consumption 0.91 Investment 2.60 Labor 1.04 Net exports 0.61 Correlation to output Consumption 0.77 Investment 0.75 Labor 0.74 Net exports −0.36 Autocorrelation Output 0.93 Consumption 0.94 Investment 0.93 Labor 0.93 Net exports 0.91 Cross-country correlation Output 0.37 Consumption 0.28 Investment 0.23 Labor 0.23 Net exports −0.02

G7 G7 G7 Mean S.D. Median BP BP HP to standard deviation of 0.92 0.12 0.92 2.63 0.35 2.67 1.30 0.53 1.67 0.52 0.21 0.65

USA Mean BP output 0.81 2.82 1.07 0.23

Model

0.76 0.80 0.63 −0.32

0.10 0.11 0.37 0.17

0.74 0.74 0.53 −0.29

0.88 0.96 0.93 −0.46

0.73 0.05 0.97 0.21

0.92 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.02 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.02

0.82 0.77 0.86 0.59 0.72

0.94 0.94 0.95 0.92 0.95

0.91 0.91 0.79 0.91 0.80

0.41 0.21 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.19 0.29 0.23 0.30 0.22

0.35 0.28 0.25 0.35 −0.01

0.45 0.38 0.30 0.51 −0.08

−0.72 0.64 −0.99 −0.96 −1.00

0.29 13.21 0.56 3.33

The author’s calculation is based mainly on “SourceOECD.” The sample period is 1970 Q1–2006 Q4. See Appendix A for details. Intra-country moments are medians (means) of the G7 countries. Cross-country correlations are medians (means) of 21 (= 7 × 6/2) statistics. Cross-country correlations of the U.S. column are medians of six pairwise correlations between the U.S. and other G7 countries. The S.D. column shows the standard deviations of seven intra-country moments and 21 cross-country correlations. The BP filter (Baxter and King, 1999) uses parameters BP12 (6, 32). The HP filter (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997) uses parameter λ = 1600. The model is the two-country baseline model (King et al. (1988), with a complete market and no shock diffusion).

4

B

Models

B.1

Computation and calibration

The computation procedure is also designed to compare to the prototypical two-country models. The economy is transformed into a detrended economy, and its non-stochastic steady state is calculated. Model moments are obtained from cyclical behavior around the steady state using the log-linear rational expectation system (Kydland and Prescott, 1982; King et al., 1988).1 The multi-country setting does not greatly inflate the state space of the model; state variables in the system of the baseline model are Ai,t , Ki,t for all i = 1, ..., N . In an N = 10 economy, for example, the total number of state variables is 20. The bond market assumption and the timeto-build technology require additional state variables, but the speed of an increment is a multiple of the number of countries and, hence, standard linear rational expectation solvers can handle the calculations.2 All the moments are calculated for each selection of production technology, shock process and market structure. To compare the implications of the number of countries per se, only the number of countries in the model is changed. The moments are obtained by 100,000-period simulations and filtered using an approximated band-path filter.3

B.2

Single-good models

Time is discrete and indexed by t. The world comprises N countries, indexed by i = 1, ..., N . The countries potentially vary in size, but are symmetric in other respects. The world population is a ∑ unit measure. Each country has a πi fraction of the population, where i πi = 1. The model is described as a social planner’s problem, since the equilibrium allocations are Pareto optimal. The Pareto weight is equivalent to a country’s population size. B.2.1

Households

Households enjoy consumption, Ci,t , and dislike working, Li,t . By normalizing total time endowment to be unity, 1 − Li,t stands for the leisure of a household in i at t. Li,t is used for the production in country i, i.e., labor is immobile across countries. The social planner maximizes the weighted sum of the utility of the stand-in households E0

N ∑ i=1

πi

∞ ∑

βt

ψ (Ci,t (1 − Li,t )1−ψ )1−γ

1−γ

t=0

.

(B1)

1 For example, the output is calculated by yˆi,t = log(Yi,t /Y ), where Y is the steady state output level. Net exports are calculated by:

n cxi,t = yˆi,t −

C C cˆi,t − ˆıi,t , Y Y

where C and I are steady state consumption and investment respectively. 2 The calculation employs AIM implementation of Anderson=Moore algorithm (Anderson, 2008). 3 The parameters are BPK (p, q) = BP12 (6, 32), following the recommendation in Baxter and King (1999). The results obtained using the HP filter (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997) are similar. If the number of countries is relatively small, the moments can be directly calculated from the system. As the number of countries increases, the computational burden prevents the use of a direct calculation method. Simulations give almost identical moments for cases with a small number (e.g., five) of countries.

5

subject to a technology, a shock process and a resource constraint. B.2.2

The baseline production technology and the shock process

The baseline model employs the standard neoclassical production function (King et al., 1988). The output, Yi,t , is produced using capital (Ki,t ) and labor (Li,t ). α 1−α Yi,t = Ai,t Ki,t Li,t

(B2)

Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ)Ki,t + Ii,t

(B3)

where Ai,t is the country-specific total factor productivity (TFP) and Ii,t is investment. TFP has a world common trend component (A¯t ) growing at rate g, and country specific stochastic components (A˜i,t ), such that Ai,t = A¯t A˜i,t = A0 (1 + g)t A˜i,t .

(B4)

˜ t be a vector of log A˜i,t and Moreover, let a ˜ t = Ω˜ a at−1 + εt ,

(B5)

where the diagonal element of Ω(i,i) is autocorrelation parameter ωii , and the off-diagonal element of Ω(i,h) is spillover parameter ωih . The vector of shock, εt , is jointly normal (εt ∼ N ), independently and identically distributed across t, E(εt ) = 0, V (εt )(i,i) = σii2 , and V (εt )(i,h) = σih . B.2.3

Resource constraint

The resource constraint of the baseline model is that the planner collects the entire global output and allocates both consumption and investment, which is identical to the complete market situation in the decentralized model. ∑

πi N Xi,t = 0.

(B6)

i

where N Xi,t is net exports and N Xi,t = Yi,t − Ci,t − Ii,t .

(B7)

Appendix B presents three alternative resource constraints, one including a complete market subject to trade costs, one restricting assets to non-state contingent bonds (risk-free bond market), and the other imposing period-by-period trade balance, which is a multi-country extension of “financial autarky” proposed by Heathcote and Perri (2002).

B.3

Modified versions of single-good models

Regardless of the production technologies or market assumptions, the models can be solved as constrained social planner’s problem.

6

B.3.1

Time-to-build

A simplified version employed in Backus et al. (1992) is expressed as follows: α 1−α Yi,t = Ai,t Ki,t Li,t ,

(B8)

Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ)Ki,t + Vi,t,1 ,

(B9)

Ii,t =

1 J

J ∑

Vi,t,j , and

(B10)

j=1

Vi,t+1,j = Vi,t,j+1

for j = 1, ..., J − 1,

(B11)

where Ii,t is the total investment in country i at t, and the investment is divided into J fractions of Vi,t,j . Each Vi,t,j becomes the working capital stock as j period passes. B.3.2

Adjustment friction and variable utilization

Some of the production functions are special cases of the following model. α 1−α Yi,t = Ai,t ζ(Zi,t )Ki,t Li,t

Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ(Zi,t ))Ki,t + ϕ

(

Ii,t Ki,t

(B12)

) Ki,t ,

(B13)

where Ii,t is the investment, Ki,t is the capital stock, Zi,t is the degree of capital utilization, and ϕ(.) is a function of the capital adjustment friction. The function ζ(.) represents the possibility of variable capital utilization. If ζ(Z) = Z α , the model is equivalent to Baxter and Farr (2005). If ζ(.) = 1 and δ(.) = δ, the capital utilization and depreciation rate are constant, which is reduced to the model of Baxter and Crucini (1993) specifications. Following Baxter and Farr (2005), a set of conditions is imposed on these functions, so that the non-stochastic steady state values are irrelevant with or without friction and/or adjustment assumptions.4 Then, only elasticity parameters are relevant for calculating log-linearized models. B.3.3

Resource constraints in case of a complete market and trade cost

Backus et al. (1992) specify a quadratic trade cost ∑

( ) πi N Xi,t − 0.1(N Xi,t )2 /Y = 0,

i

where Y is the steady state output.

4

The conditions are

) ( ) I I I = , ϕ′ =1 K K K δ(Z) = δ, Z = 1, (

ϕ

where variables without subscripts are non-stochastic steady state values derived in the separate appendix.

7

(B14)

B.3.4

Resource constraints in a bond market

Baxter and Crucini (1995) and Kollmann (1996) consider a model in which only risk-free bonds are available. It is expressed by N Xi,t + Bi,t = Ptb Bi,t+1 ∑ πi Bi,t = 0,

(B15) (B16)

i

where Bi,t is the bond holding of i country and Ptb is the subjective “price” of a bond that the planner faces. This price is the same as the competitive equilibrium price of the non-state-contingent bond.

B.4

One-good-per-country models

Backus et al. (1994), Arvanitis and Mikkola (1996), and Heathcote and Perri (2002) consider a onegood-per-country setting with various financial market arrangements. In this case, a decentralized problem is considered. B.4.1

Household problem

Each representative agent living in i solves

max E0

∞ ∑

βt

( )1−γ ψ Ci,t (1 − Li,t )1−ψ 1−γ

t=0

(B17)

subject to ( Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ)Ki,t + ϕ

Ii,t Ki,t

) Ki,t

(B18)

where ϕ is capital adjustment friction function as explained above. The capital adjustment friction is imposed only in Arvanitis and Mikkola (1996). The budget constraint is one of the following. B.4.2

Complete market case

Backus et al. (1994) consider the complete market model: Pi,t (Ci,t + Ii,t ) +



Ptb (st+1 )Bi,t+1 (st+1 )

st+1

= Bi,t + Pi,t (Wi,t Li,t + Ri,t Ki,t ) .

(B19)

where Pi,t is final good price, Wi,t is real wage, Ri,t is real rental rate, Bi,t+1 (st+1 ) is state contingent claim in i for rewarding a unit of currency, and Ptb (st+1 ) is the price of the claim (for each state at t + 1). Transversality conditions: 0 = E0 lim

t→∞

t ∑ ∏

Pkb (sk+1 )Bi,k+1 (sk+1 ).

k=0 sk+1

8

(B20)

B.4.3

Non-state contingent bond case

Arvanitis and Mikkola (1996) consider the only available asset in the world is non-state contingent period ahead risk free claim, household budget constraint is ηtb b b P (Bi,t )2 − Ti,t 2 t = Bi,t−1 + Pi,t (Wi,t Li,t + Ri,t Ki,t ) . Pi,t (Ci,t + Ii,t ) + Ptb Bi,t +

(B21)

where Ptb is world price of non-state contingent bond, Bi,t is amount of bond holdings, ηtb is bond holdings adjustment tax parameter (which is time-dependent for having stationarity in transformed b is lump-sum transfer financed by bond holding adjustment tax.5 Also, correeconomy) and Ti,t

sponding transversality condition is imposed: 0 = E0 lim

t→∞

B.4.4

t ∏

Pkb Bi,t .

(B22)

k=0

A generalization of financial autarky

Period-by-period trade balance assumption restricts possibility of asset trading that is balanced: Pi,t (Ci,t + Ii,t ) = Pi,t (Wi,t Li,t + Ri,t Ki,t ) .

(B23)

The period-by-period trade balance is a straightforward extension of “financial autarky” assumption proposed by Heathcote and Perri (2002). If there are only two countries, a country-by-country goods side balance automatically implies a period-by-period financial side balance. In the multi-country framework, however, the economies are still possible to trade asset. The asset trading may not hold country-by-country financial side balance, but a financial account of the economy is balanced in the aggregate, ensuring period-by-period financial side balance. B.4.5

Final goods producer problem

Final goods producer in i solves max Pi,t Xi,t −

N ∑

pj,i,t xj,i,t

(B24)

j=1

subject to

Xi,t

 1 θ N ∑ θ   = υj,i xj,i,t

(B25)

j=1

where pj,i,t is the price of an intermediate product xj,i,t in country j.

This type of tax and transfer is based on Ghironi and Melitz (2005). ηtb is adjusted so that it becomes stationary after removing trend, and detrended version of the parameter is parameterized to be a small number (0.0000125). 5

9

B.4.6

Intermediate goods producer max pi,t xi,t − Pi,t Wi,t Li,t − Pi,t Ri,t Ki,t

(B26)

α 1−α xi,t = Ai,t Ki,t Li,t

(B27)

subject to

B.4.7

Market clearing

Followings are market clearing conditions of the economy: N ∑

πj xi,j,t = πi xi,t

(B28)

j=1

Country’s resource constraint: Ci,t + Ii,t = Xi,t

(B29)

Market clearing of claims if there are state contingent claims: 0=

N ∑

πi Bi,t+1 .

(B30)

i=1

Non-state contingent bond case: 0=

N ∑

πi Bi,t .

(B31)

i=1

and lump-sum transfer is financed by bond holding adjustment tax: ηtb b b Pt (Bi,t )2 = Ti,t . 2

B.5

(B32)

Derivation of single-good models

Objective Function E0

N ∑ ∞ ∑

β t u(Ci,t , Li,t )

i=1 t=0

where u(Ci,t , Li,t ) =

ψ (Ci,t (1 − Li,t )1−ψ )1−γ

1−γ

subject to production technology and resource constraints.

10

.

(CD): Cobb=Douglas Production Function α 1−α Yi,t = Ai,t ζ(Zi,t )Ki,t Li,t

TFP process is defined Ai,t = A0 (1 + g)t A˜i,t = A¯t A˜i,t where ˜ t = Ω˜ a at−1 + εt where Ω(i,i) = ωii and Ω(i,h) = ωih where subscripts (i, h) stands for (i, h), non-diagonal, element of ˜ t is log A˜i,t . ith row of εt is εi,t , εt ∼ N jointly normal and i.i.d. across t, the matrix. ith row of a E(εt ) = 0, V (εt )(i,i) = σii2 and V (εt )(i,h) = σih . Adding to this, combinations of following components generate variations of models:

Choices of Investment Friction (NF): No Friction (Baseline) Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ(Zi,t ))Ki,t + Ii,t (AF): Adjustment Friction ( ) Ii,t Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ(Zi,t ))Ki,t + ϕ Ki,t Ki,t ( ) ( ) I I I ′ ϕ = , ϕ =1 K K K

(TB): Time-to-Build Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ(Zi,t ))Ki,t + Vi,t,1 Ii,t

J 1∑ = Vi,t,j J j=1

Vi,t+1,j = Vi,t,j+1

for j = 1, ..., J − 1.

Choices of Utilization (CU): Constant Utilization δ(Zi,t ) = δ

11

(VU): Variable Utilization δ(Z) = δ,

Z=1

Choice of Resource Constraint (CM): Complete Market ∑

πi [Yi,t − Ci,t − Ii,t ] = 0.

i

(TC): Complete Market with Trade Costs ∑

πi [Yi,t − Ci,t − Ii,t − τ (Yi,t − Ci,t − Ii,t )] = 0.

i ′ τ (0) = 0, τi,t > 0,

(BM): Bond Market Yi,t + Bi,t = Ci,t + Ii,t + Pt Bi,t+1 ∑ πi Bi,t = 0. i

B.5.1

Equilibrium conditions

Although the model is presented as a Social planner’s problem, the resulting system coincides with competitive equilibria. The equilibrium conditions can be expressed as the appropriate combinations of following blocks of equations. All the model uses marginal utility (MU) condition and the production function (CD) condition. In addition, the model is characterized by one of the investment friction conditions ((NF), (AF) or (TB)), one of the utilization conditions ((CU) or (VU)), and one of the resource constraints ((CM), (TC) or (BM)). Denote uc and ul first derivative of utility with respect to C and L. Λs are multipliers associate with various constraints.

(MU): Marginal Utility ψ(1−γ)−1

uc (i, t) = ψCi,t

(1 − Li,t )(1−ψ)(1−γ)

ψ(1−γ)

ul (i, t) = −(1 − ψ)Ci,t ΛYi,t = πi uc (i, t)

12

(1 − Li,t )(1−ψ)(1−γ)−1

(CD): Cobb-Douglas Production Function α α 1−α Yi,t = Ai,t Zi,t Ki,t Li,t Yi,t 1 − ψ Ci,t (1 − α) = Li,t ψ 1 − Li,t

(NF): No Friction Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ(Zi,t ))Ki,t + Ii,t [ ] Yi,t+1 uc (i, t) = Et βuc (i, t + 1) α + 1 − δ(Zi,t+1 ) Ki,t+1 ΛK i,t = uc (i, t) ϕ′ (i, t) = 1 (AF): Adjustment Friction Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ(Zi,t ))Ki,t + ϕ(i, t)Ki,t [ ( )] Yi,t+1 Ii,t+1 uc (i, t + 1) uc (i, t) ′ ′ = E β ϕ (i, t + 1)α + 1 − δ(Z ) + ϕ(i, t + 1) − ϕ (i, t + 1) t i,t+1 ϕ′ (i, t) ϕ′ (i, t + 1) Ki,t+1 Ki,t+1 ΛK i,t = uc (i, t) ϕ(i, t) = ϕ(Ii,t /Ki,t ) ϕ′ (i, t) = dϕ(i, t)/d(Ii,t /Ki,t ) (TB): Time-to-Build Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ(Zi,t ))Ki,t + Vi,t,1 Ii,t =

J 1∑ Vi,t,j J j=1

Vi,t+1,j = Vi,t,j+1 [ ] −1 Y K ΛK = E β Λ αY K + Λ (1 − δ(Z )) t i,t+1 i,t+1 i,t, i,t+1 i,t+1 i,t+1 1 Y 1 V Λi,t = ΛK Λ i,t − J G4 i,t−1,1 1 V 1 Y Λi,t = ΛVi,t,1 − Λ J G4 i,t−1,2 ... 1 Y 1 V Λi,t = ΛVi,t,J−2 − Λ J G4 i,t−1,J−1 1 Y Λ = ΛVi,t,J−1 J i,t ϕ′ (i, t) = 1

13

(CU): Constant Utilization Zi,t = 1 δ(Zi,t ) = δ (VU): Variable Utilization ϕ′ (i, t)ΛYi,t α

Yi,t ′ = ΛK i,t δ (Zi,t )Ki,t Zi,t

(CM): Complete Market ∑

πi (Yi,t − Ii,t − Ci,t ) = 0

i

uc (i, t) = uc (h, t) (TC): Complete Market with Trade Costs ∑

πi (Yi,t − Ii,t − Ci,t − τ (Yi,t − Ii,t − Ci,t )) = 0

i

uc (i, t) uc (h, t) ′ = 1 − τ′ 1 − τi,t h,t (BM): Bond Market ∑

πi Bi,t = 0

i

Yi,t + Bi,t = Ci,t + Ii,t + Pt Bi,t+1 uc (i, t + 1) Pt = βEt uc (i, t) B.5.2

Transformed equilibrium conditions

Denote variables with tilde as detrended values. The table summarizes various factors to detrend variables. Detrending factors detrend factor 1 1−α

A¯t

ψ(1−γ) 1−α

A¯t

ψ(1−γ)−1 1−α

variables Yi,t , Ci,t , Ii,t , Ki,t , Bi,t , Vi,t,j M ul (i, t), ΛL i,t , Λi,t

A¯t

V uc (i, t), ΛYi,t , ΛK i,t , Λi,t,j

none

Li,t , Zi,t

14

For notational convenience, denote G’s as growing factors, and define shortcut notation of adjustment friction functions Growing factors notation

value

G1

(1 + g)

G2

G11−α

G3

βG1 1−α

1

ψ(1−γ)

G4

ψ(1−γ)−1 1−α

βG1

(MU) ( )(1−ψ)(1−γ) e ψ(1−γ)−1 1 − L e i,t uec (i, t) = ψ C i,t )(1−ψ)(1−γ)−1 ( ψ(1−γ) e e 1 − Li,t uel (i, t) = −(1 − ψ)Ci,t e Yi,t = πi uec (i, t) Λ (CD) ei,t Z eα K e α e 1−α Yei,t = A i,t i,t Li,t (1 − α)

ei,t Yei,t 1−ψ C = e i,t e i,t ψ 1−L L

(NF) e i,t+1 = (1 − δ(Z ei,t ))K e i,t + Iei,t G2 K [ ( )] Yei,t+1 uec (i, t) = G4 Et uec (i, t + 1) α + 1 − δ(Zei,t+1 ) e i,t+1 K ϕ′ (i, t) = 1 (AF) e i,t+1 = (1 − δ(Z ei,t ))K e i,t + ϕ(i, t)K e i,t G2 K [ ( )] ei,t+1 ei,t+1 Y I uec (i, t) uec (i, t + 1) = G4 Et ϕ′ (i, t + 1)α + 1 − δ(Zei,t+1 ) + ϕ(i, t + 1) − ϕ′ (i, t + 1) e i,t+1 e i,t+1 ϕ′ (i, t) ϕ′ (i, t + 1) K K

15

(TB) e i,t+1 = (1 − δ(Z ei,t ))K e i,t + Vei,t,1 G2 K J 1∑e e Vi,t,j Ii,t = J j=1

G2 Vei,t+1,j = Vei,t,j+1 [ ] −1 Y K eK e e e e e Λ = E G Λ α Y K + Λ (1 − δ( Z )) t 4 i,t+1 i,t+1 i,t+1 i,t, i,t+1 i,t+1 1 eV 1 eY eK Λ =Λ Λ i,t − J i,t G4 i,t−1,1 1 eY eV eV − 1 Λ Λ =Λ i,t,1 J i,t G4 i,t−1,2 ... 1 eY e Vi,t,J−2 − 1 Λ eV Λi,t = Λ J G4 i,t−1,J−1 1 eY eV Λ =Λ i,t,J−1 J i,t ′ ϕ (i, t) = 1 (CU) ei,t = 1 Z ei,t ) = δ δ(Z (VU) e Yi,t α ϕ′ (i, t)Λ

Yei,t ′ e eK e =Λ i,t δ (Zi,t )Ki,t e Zi,t

(CM) ∑

[ ] ei,t = 0 πi Yei,t − Iei,t − C

i

uec (i, t) = uec (h, t) (TC) ∑

[ ] ei,t − τ (Yei,t − Iei,t − C ei,t ) = 0 πi Yei,t − Iei,t − C

i

uec (h, t) uec (i, t) = ′ ′ 1 − τi,t 1 − τh,t

16

(BM) ∑

ei,t = 0 πi B

i

ei,t = C ei,t + Iei,t + Pt G2 B ei,t+1 Yei,t + B uec (i, t + 1) Pt = βG4 Et uec (i, t) B.5.3

Non-stochastic steady state

At the non-stochastic steady state, market structure does not matter. Due to symmetric assumption, steady state values are the same across countries so that we drop country subscripts. Also, ad hoc capital adjustment friction and variable utilization do not affect by construction. Denote Ξ as the e i,t . The following system include cases with time-to-build (TB), adjustment steady state value of Ξ friction (AF), and variable utilization (VU). If time-to-build is not used, set J = 1. ) ( 1 1 r= −1+δ α G4 ( ( ))−1 1−ψ 1 1 1 − GJ2 −1 L= 1+ 1− (G2 − 1 + δ)r ψ 1−α J 1 − G2 1

K = r α−1 L V1 = (G2 − 1 + δ)K Vj+1 = G2 Vj I=

J 1∑ Vj J j=1

Y = rK C =Y −I Z=1 δ ′ = αr uc = ψC ψ(1−γ)−1 (1 − L)(1−ψ)(1−γ) ΛY = πuc 1 ΛVJ−1 = ΛY J ΛVJ−2 = (1 +

1 1 Y ) Λ G4 J

... ΛV1 = (1 + ... + ΛK = (1 +

1 GJ−2 4

1 GJ−1 4

1 ) ΛY J

1 ) ΛY J

B=0 P = βG4

17

B.5.4

Log-linearized equations

˜ i,t − log Ξ, deviation from the steady state, except for Let ξˆi,t = log Ξ nxi,t − nx ˆbi,t = bi,t − B , n cxi,t = . Y Y (MU) ubc (i, t) = (ψ(1 − γ) − 1)ˆ ci,t − (1 − ψ)(1 − γ)

L ˆ li,t 1−L

(CD) yˆi,t = a ˆi,t + αˆ zi,t + αkˆi,t + (1 − α)ˆli,t 1 ˆ yˆi,t = cˆi,t + li,t 1−L

(NF) ) 1 ′ 1 I ( kˆi,t+1 = kˆi,t − δ (Z)Z zˆi,t + ˆıi,t − kˆi,t G2 G2 K ( ) ubc (i, t) = E ubc (i, t + 1) + (1 − G4 (1 − δ)) E yˆi,t+1 − E kˆi,t+1 − G4 δ ′ (Z)ZE zˆi,t+1 ˆ K = ubc (i, t) λ i,t ϕb′ (i, t) = 0 (AF) ) 1 ′ 1 I ( kˆi,t+1 = kˆi,t − δ (Z)Z zˆi,t + ˆıi,t − kˆi,t G2 G2 K ( ) ubc (i, t) − ϕb′ (i, t) = E ubc (i, t + 1) + (1 − G4 (1 − δ)) E yˆi,t+1 − E kˆi,t+1 ′′ I

ϕ ϕb′ (i, t) = − ′K ϕ K ˆ λ = ubc (i, t)

−G4 δ ′ (Z)ZE zˆi,t+1 − G4 G2 E ϕb′ (i, t + 1) ( ) kˆi,t − ˆıi,t

i,t

18

(TB) ) 1 ′ 1 V1 ( vˆi,t,1 − kˆi,t kˆi,t+1 = kˆi,t − δ (Z)Z zˆi,t + G2 G2 K J 1∑ Iˆıi,t = Vj vˆi,t,j J j=1

vˆi,t+1,j = vˆi,t,j+1

( ) ˆ K = (1 − G4 (1 − δ)) E ubc (i, t + 1) + E yˆi,t+1 − E kˆi,t+1 λ i,t ′ ˆk +G4 (1 − δ)E λ ˆi,t+1 i,t+1 − G4 δ (Z)ZE z ˆV ˆ K − 1 ΛY ubc (i, t) = 1 ΛV λ ΛK λ i,t J G4 1 i,t−1,1 ˆ V − 1 ΛY ubc (i, t) = 1 ΛV λ ˆV ΛV1 λ i,t,1 J G4 2 i,t−1,2 ... 1 Y 1 V ˆV ˆV ΛVJ−2 λ bc (i, t) = Λ λ i,t,J−2 − Λ u J G4 J−1 i,t−1,J−1 ˆV ubc (i, t) = λ i,t,J−1

ϕb′ (i, t) = 0 (CU) zˆi,t = 0 (VU) ubc (i, t) + ϕb′ (i, t) + yˆi,t =

) ( δ ′′ Z ˆ K (i, t) zˆi,t + kˆi,t + λ 1+ ′ δ

(CM) ∑

πi (Y yˆi,t − Iˆıi,t − Cˆ ci,t ) = 0

i

ubc (i, t) = ubc (h, t) (TC) ∑

πi (Y yˆi,t − Iˆıi,t − Cˆ ci,t ) = 0

i

ubc (i, t) + τi′′ (0) (Y yˆi,t − Iˆıi,t − Cˆ ci,t ) = ubc (h, t) + τh′′ (0) (Y yˆh,t − Iˆıh,t − Cˆ ch,t )

19

(BM) ∑

πiˆbi,t = 0

i

ubc (i, t) − E ubc (i, t + 1) = ubc (h, t) − E ubc (h, t + 1) C I yˆi,t + ˆbi,t = cˆi,t + ˆıi,t + G3ˆbi,t+1 Y Y TFP process b t = Ωb a at−1 + εbt

B.6 B.6.1

Derivation of one-good-per-country models Models

Household problem Each representative agent living in i solves

max E0

∞ ∑

βt

( )1−γ ψ Ci,t (1 − Li,t )1−ψ 1−γ

t=0

(B33)

subject to ( Ki,t+1 = (1 − δ)Ki,t + ϕ

Ii,t Ki,t

) Ki,t

(B34)

where ϕ is capital adjustment friction function as explained above. The budget constraint is one of the following. Complete market case Pi,t (Ci,t + Ii,t ) +



Ptb (st+1 )Bi,t+1 (st+1 )

st+1

= Bi,t + Pi,t (Wi,t Li,t + Ri,t Ki,t ) .

(B35)

where Pi,t is final good price, Wi,t is real wage, Ri,t is real rental rate, Bi,t+1 (st+1 ) is state contingent claim in i for rewarding a unit of currency, and Ptb (st+1 ) is the price of the claim (for each state at t + 1). Transversality conditions: 0 = E0 lim

t→∞

t ∑ ∏

Pkb (sk+1 )Bi,k+1 (sk+1 ).

k=0 sk+1

20

(B36)

Non-state contengent bond case Household budget constraint is ηtb b b P (Bi,t )2 − Ti,t 2 t = Bi,t−1 + Pi,t (Wi,t Li,t + Ri,t Ki,t ) . Pi,t (Ci,t + Ii,t ) + Ptb Bi,t +

(B37)

where Ptb is world price of non-state contingent bond, Bi,t is amount of bond holdings, ηtb is bond holdings adjustment tax parameter (which is time-dependent for having stationarity in transformed b is lump-sum transfer financed by bond holding adjustment tax. Also, correspondeconomy) and Ti,t

ing transversality condition is imposed: 0 = E0 lim

t→∞

t ∏

Pkb Bi,t .

(B38)

k=0

A generalization of financial autarky Period-by-period trade balance assumption restricts possibility of asset trading that is balanced: Pi,t (Ci,t + Ii,t ) = Pi,t (Wi,t Li,t + Ri,t Ki,t ) .

(B39)

Final goods producer problem Final goods producer in i solves max Pi,t Xi,t −

N ∑

pj,i,t xj,i,t

(B40)

j=1

subject to

Xi,t

1  θ N ∑ θ υj,i xj,i,t  =

(B41)

j=1

where pj,i,t is the price of an intermediate product xj,i,t in country j. Intermediate goods producer max pi,t xi,t − Pi,t Wi,t Li,t − Pi,t Ri,t Ki,t

(B42)

α 1−α xi,t (st ) = Ai,t Ki,t Li,t

(B43)

subject to

21

Market clearing Followings are market clearing conditions of the economy: N ∑

πj xi,j,t = πi xi,t

(B44)

j=1

Country’s resource constraint: Ci,t + Ii,t = Xi,t

(B45)

Market clearing of claims if there are state contingent claims: 0=

N ∑

πi Bi,t+1 .

(B46)

i=1

Non-state contingent bond case: 0=

N ∑

πi Bi,t .

(B47)

i=1

and lump-sum transfer is financed by bond holding adjustment tax: ηtb b b Pt (Bi,t )2 = Ti,t . 2

(B48)

Terms of trade

E Pi,t

  θ−1 θ θ ∑ 1 θ−1 θ−1   υi,j pi,j,t = /Pi,t .

(B49)

j̸=i

Similarly, the price index of the importing goods is

I Pi,t

  θ−1 θ 1 θ ∑ θ−1 θ−1 = υj,i pj,i,t  /Pi,t .

(B50)

j̸=i

The terms of trade, defined as the relative price of exports to imports, is E I T oTi,t (st ) = Pi,t /Pi,t .

(B51)

Detrending Let variables with tilde ˜ as detrended variables. It is defined, for a case of Xi,t , ˜ i,t = Xi,t /g1t X

22

(B52)

Other cases are summarized in the table: Detrending factor

Value

Variables

ga

ga

Ai,t

1 1−α

g1

ga

Xi,t , Ci,t , Ii,t , Ki,m,t , xi,j,t , Bi,t , Wi,t , exj,i,t , Yi,t , xi,t

g3

uL,i,t

g4

ψ(1−γ) g1 ψ(1−γ)−1 g1

1



Li,t , Ri,t , Pi,t , pi,j,t , ej,i,t , pi,t

Λi,t , uC,i,t

Also, let ηtb = η b g1−t . B.6.2

Transformed economy equilibrium conditions α ˜ 1−α ˜ i,t x ˜i,t = A˜i,t K Li,t

( ϕ˜i,t = ϕ

I˜i,t ˜ i,t K

( ϕ˜′i,t = ϕ′

I˜i,t ˜ i,t K

) (B54)

)

˜ i,t+1 = (1 − δ)K ˜ i,t + ϕ˜i,t K ˜ i,t g1 K

˜ i,t X

(B53)

1  θ N ∑ θ   υj,i x ˜j,i,t =

(B55)

(B56)

(B57)

j=1

πi x ˜i,t =



πj τ˜i,j,t x ˜i,j,t

(B58)

j

p˜i,t (1 − α)

uL,i,t x ˜i,t ˜ i,t = P˜i,t −˜ = P˜i,t W li,t u ˜C,i,t

(B59)

[ ( )] ˜ii,t+1 u ˜C,i,t 1 ′ ˜ i,t+1 + = βg4 Et u ˜C,i,t+1 R 1 − δ + ϕ˜i,t+1 − ϕ˜i,t+1 ϕ˜′i,t ϕ˜′i,t+1 k˜i,t+1

(B60)

˜ i,t − C˜i,t − I˜i,t , 0=X

(B61)

23

If complete market u ˜C,i,t P˜i,t /µi = u ˜C,j,t P˜j,t /µj

(B62)

If incomplete market, 0=

N ∑

˜i,t B

(B63)

i=1

(

[

)

˜i,t = βg4 Et P˜b t 1 + η b B

] u ˜C,i,t+1 /P˜i,t+1 . u ˜C,i,t /P˜i,t

[ ] [ ] ˜i,t = B ˜i,t−1 + P˜i,t W ˜ i,t L ˜ i,t + R ˜ i,t K ˜ i,t . P˜i,t C˜i,t + I˜i,t + P˜b t B

(B64)

(B65)

If financial autarky, ˜ i,t = W ˜ i,t L ˜ i,t + R ˜ i,t K ˜ i,t X B.6.3

(B66)

Non-stochastic steady state

Normalization of the price Setting P¯N = 1 as normalization. Rental rate and capital labor ratio ¯ K) ¯ = I/ ¯K ¯ and ϕ′ (I/ ¯ K) ¯ = 1. From Euler equation, By assumption, ϕ(I/ ¯i = R ¯ = 1 − 1 + δ. R βg4

(B67)

Capital-labor ratio (denoting κi ) is expressed by ¯i ¯i K α W κ ¯i = ¯ = ¯ . 1−α R Li

(B68)

¯ i = I¯i , (g1 − 1 + δ)K

(B69)

¯i α W ¯ I¯i = (g1 − 1 + δ) ¯ Li , 1−α R

(B70)

Investment Capital accumulation implies:

or

24

Absorption From household budget constraint and resource constraint, ¯i = W ¯ iL ¯i + R ¯K ¯i X ¯ ¯ iL ¯i + R ¯ α Wi ¯li = W ¯ 1−α R 1 ¯ ¯ = Wi Li 1−α

(B71)

With resource constraint and investment condition, α 1 − (g1 − 1 + δ) R ¯ ¯ ¯ Wi Li = C¯i . 1−α

(B72)

¯ ¯ i = 1 − ψ Ci , W ¯i ψ 1−L

(B73)

α 1 − (g1 − 1 + δ) R ¯ ¯ ¯ Wi Li = C¯i . 1−α

(B74)

Labor Combining two equations

to obtain ψ ¯= L

1−ψ ¯ 1 − (g1 − 1 + δ)α/R 1−α

. +

(B75)

ψ 1−ψ

¯i = W ¯ , etc. Consider the symmetric situation so that P¯i = P¯ = 1, W Wage and price level 1 From   θ−1 θ N −1 θ ∑ θ−1 θ−1 P¯i =  υj,i p¯j,i  ,

(B76)

j=1

p¯j,i = p¯j τ¯j,i and ¯αW ¯ 1−α , p¯j αα (1 − α)1−α A¯j = P¯j R j

25

(B77)

Let ¯ α α−α (1 − α)−[1−α] . Ψ≡R

(B78)

  θ−1 θ N ) θ −1 ( ∑ θ−1 θ−1 −1 ¯ ¯ 1−α ¯ ¯   Pi = υj,i ΨAj Pj Wj τ¯j,i ,

(B79)

To obtain

j=1

or 





∑  ¯ ¯ 1−α τ¯j,i  P¯i = Ψ  Pj Wj 1 θ ¯ Aj υj,i j

θ θ−1

 θ−1 θ  

.

(B80)

Under the symmetry, 





∑ ¯ 1−α Ψ   τ¯1 j,i  1=W  θ ¯ υj,i Aj j

θ θ−1

 θ−1 θ  

.

(B81)

¯. This gives W Consumption and absorption ¯ and L, ¯ Given W ψ ¯ ¯ W (1 − L), 1−ψ ¯L ¯ Z¯ = (1 − α)W

C¯ =

(B82) (B83)

Capital-labor ratio, marginal utility, absorption

κ ¯=

¯ α W ¯. 1−α R

(B84)

¯ I¯ = (g1 − 1 + δ)¯ κL,

(B85)

¯ (1−ψ)(1−γ) , u ¯C = ψ C¯ ψ(1−γ)−1 [1 − L]

(B86)

¯, u ¯L = −¯ uC W

(B87)

26

Check ¯ Z¯ = C¯ + I.

(B88)

Goods production, exporting, and relative price The price of goods in j is p¯j =

1 ¯−1 −α ¯ ¯ A κ ¯ WP. 1−α

(B89)

Then, the price at country i is p¯j,i = p¯j τ¯j,i .

(B90)

[ ] 1 1−θ z¯j,i = P¯ Z¯ 1−θ υj,i p¯−1 . j,i

(B91)

implying

Output and investment z¯i =



πj τ¯i,j z¯i,j /πi

(B92)

j

Y¯ = Z¯

(B93)

ex ¯ j,i = πi p¯j,i z¯j,i

(B94)

∑ ¯ i= 1 IM ex ¯ j,i /P¯i πi

(B95)

∑ ¯ i= 1 EX ex ¯ i,j /P¯i πi

(B96)

Trade values

j̸=i

j̸=i

 P¯iI = 



 θ−1 −1 θ−1

θ θ−1

υj,i p¯j,i

j̸=i

27

θ



/P¯i ,

(B97)

 P¯iE = 



 θ−1 −1 θ−1

θ θ−1

υi,j p¯i,j

θ



/P¯i

(B98)

j̸=i

B.6.4

Log-linearized equations

The economy’s dynamics is analyzed by first order log-linearized economy. • # number of equations • ♡ combining to reduce number of variables • ♢ redundant conditions (not used) ˆi,t is log-deviations from the stead state, e.g., All the variables excluding B Cˆi,t = log(Ci,t /C¯i )

(B99)

Bond holding is linear approximation (not log-linear approximation): ¯ ˆi,t = Bi,t − Bi = Bi,t . B Y¯i Y¯i

(B100)

¯i L ˆ (#N ) : 0 = −ˆ uC,i,t + (ψ(1 − γ) − 1)Cˆi,t − (1 − ψ)(1 − γ) ¯ i Li,t 1−L

(B101)

HH problem

ˆ i,t + Cˆi,t + (#N ) : 0 = −W

¯i L ˆ ¯ i Li,t 1−L

¯ tR ˆ i,t+1 − βg4 g1 Et ϕˆi,t+1 (#N ) : 0 = −ˆ uC,i,t + ϕˆi,t + Et u ˆC,i,t+1 + βg4 RE

(B102)

(B103)

( ) ˆ i,t (#N ) : 0 = −ϕˆi,t − ηϕ Iˆi,t − K

(B104)

ˆ i,t+1 + (1 − δ)K ˆ i,t + (g1 − 1 + δ)Iˆi,t (#N ) : 0 = −g1 K

(B105)

Final goods producer ¯ iθ X ˆ i,t + (#N ) : 0 = −X

∑ j

28

υj,i x ¯θj,i x ˆj,i,t

(B106)

¯X ˆ i,t + (#N ♢) : 0 = −P¯ Pˆi,t − X



p¯j,i x ¯j,i (ˆ pj,i,t + x ˆj,i,t )

(B107)

j

ˆ i,t + (θ − 1)ˆ (#N 2 ♡) : 0 = −ˆ pj,i,t + Pˆi,t + (1 − θ)X xj,i,t

(B108)

Intermediate goods producer and trade ˆ i,t + (1 − α)L ˆ i,t (#N ) : 0 = −ˆ xi,t + Aˆi,t + αK

(B109)

ˆ i,t − Pˆi,t + pˆi,t + x ˆ i,t (#N ) : 0 = −W ˆi,t − L

(B110)

ˆ i,t − Pˆi,t + pˆi,t + x ˆ i,t (#N ) : 0 = −R ˆi,t − K

(B111)

(#N ) : 0 = −πi x ¯i x ˆi,t +



πj τ¯i,j x ¯i,j x ˆi,j,t

(B112)

j

(#N 2 ♡) : 0 = −ˆ pi,j,t + pˆi,t

(#N ♢) : 0 = −πi p¯i x ¯i (ˆ pi,t + x ˆi,t ) +



πj p¯i,j x ¯i,j (ˆ pi,j,t + x ˆi,j,t )

(B113)

(B114)

j

Resource constraints ¯X ˆ i,t − C¯ Cˆi,t − I¯Iˆi,t (#N ) : 0 = X

(B115)

(#1) : 0 = PˆN,t

(B116)

(#N − 1) : 0 = −ˆ uC,i,t + Pˆi,t + u ˆC,j,t − Pˆj,t

(B117)

Price normalization

Complete market case

Incomplete market case ( ) ¯B ˆi,t Et u ˆC,i,t+1 − u ˆC,i,t − Et Pˆi,t+1 + Pˆi,t − η b P¯ b X ( ) ¯B ˆj,t + Et u ˆC,j,t+1 − u ˆC,j,t − Et Pˆj,t+1 + Pˆj,t − η b P¯ b X

(#N − 1) : 0 = −

29

(B118)

¯X ˆ i,t − P¯ b X ¯B ˆi,t + X ¯iB ˆi,t−1 (#N ) : 0 = − P¯ X ( ) ( ) ¯ iL ¯ W ˆ i,t + L ˆ i,t + P¯ R ¯K ¯ R ˆ i,t + K ˆ i,t + P¯ W

(# : 1♢) : 0 =



ˆi,t πi B

(B119)

(B120)

i

Financial autarky case (One of N equation is not used.) ) ( ) ( ∑ ˆ i,m,t + kˆi,m,t . (B121) ¯ ˆ i,t + L ˆ i,t + P¯ R ¯X ˆ i,t + P¯ W ¯L ¯ W k¯i,m R (#N − 1(+1♢)) : 0 = −P¯ X m

Shock process (#N ) : Aˆi,t = ρa Aˆi,t−1 + σε εi,t

(B122)

(#N ) : εi,t ∼ N (0, 1)

(B123)

# of state variables, equations, and total variables ˆ i,t , Aˆi,t • State variables (#2N ): K ˆ i,t is predetermined • K • # of equations: 11N + N 2 • # of variables: 11N + N 2 ˆ i,t , Iˆi,t , X ˆ i,t , W ˆ i,t , R ˆ i,t , Pˆi,t , x • (#N × 7) : u ˆC,i,t , Cˆi,t , L ˆi,t , pˆi,t , ϕˆi,t • (#N 2 × (2 − 1)) : zˆi,j,t , pˆi,j,t (by ♡, pˆi,j,t is dropped.) • Exogenous shocks: εˆi,t ˆi,t , N additional equations. • Incomplete market case: N additional state variables, B Remarks • One of the #N equations is redundant. • pˆj,i,t can be dropped from the system.

30

Additional variables of interests ( ) ( ) ¯ iL ¯i W ˆ i,t + L ˆ i,t + R ¯K ¯i R ˆ i,t + K ˆ i,t Y¯i Yˆi,t = W

(B124)

ec xi,j,t = pˆi,j,t + x ˆi,j,t

(B125)

∑ 1 ex ¯ i,j ec xi,j,t − Pˆi,t ¯ i πi P¯i EX

(B126)

∑ 1 ex ¯ j,i ec xj,i,t − Pˆi,t ¯ i πi P¯i IM

(B127)

d i,t = EX

j̸=i

d i,t = IM

j̸=i

¯ i + EX ¯ i EX d i,t − IM ¯ i − IM ¯ i IM d i,t EX d N X i,t = Y¯i + Y¯i Yˆi,t θ ∑ −1 θ θ − 1 ( ¯I ¯ ) 1−θ θ−1 θ−1 I Pˆi,t = υj,i p¯j,i pˆj,i,t − Pˆi,t Pi Pi θ

(B128)

(B129)

j̸=i

θ ∑ −1 θ θ − 1 ( ¯E ¯ ) 1−θ θ−1 θ−1 E ˆ υi,j Pi,t = Pi Pi p¯i,j pˆi,j,t − Pˆi,t θ

(B130)

j̸=i

E I Td oT i,t = Pˆi,t − Pˆi,t

(B131)

ˆ i,t − (1 − α)L ˆ i,t T[ F P i,t = Yˆi,t − αK

(B132)

31

C

Robustness Tables

Following tables and figures are full versions of Table 1 and figures in the main text.

32

33

0.57 5.20 0.32 1.19

0.18 15.82 0.64 4.01 0.47 −0.01 0.99 0.25 0.91 0.91 0.79 0.91 0.80 −0.54 0.67 −0.97 −0.83 −1.00

0.81 0.04 0.99 0.22 0.91 0.91 0.80 0.91 0.80 −0.01 0.51 −0.05 −0.04 −0.05

−0.54 0.67 −0.97 −0.83 −1.00

0.91 0.91 0.81 0.91 0.80

0.97 0.38 0.96 0.08

B 0.9

A 0.1

20 0.05 of output 0.19 13.94 0.59 3.51

0.18 0.58 0.31 0.26 0.32

0.91 0.91 0.79 0.91 0.80

0.53 −0.00 0.99 0.24

0.18 15.47 0.63 3.92

C 0.1

−0.50 0.65 −0.79 −0.73 −0.81

0.91 0.91 0.80 0.91 0.80

0.95 0.25 0.96 0.11

0.48 7.39 0.39 1.78

D 0.8

−0.06 0.53 −0.12 −0.11 −0.12

0.91 0.91 0.80 0.91 0.80

0.80 0.04 0.99 0.21

0.20 13.84 0.58 3.49

E 0.1

0.37 0.28 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.93 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.77 0.75 0.74 −0.36

0.91 2.60 1.04 0.61

Data

Table A1.

N = 19, {{0.1} × 9, {0.01} × 10}. Cross-country correlations are of first two countries. The data (median of G7 countries) is taken from

large (D) countries. Cross-country correlations are of the two small countries (C), and the large and one of the small countries (D). E:

moments are for the first (A) and second (B) countries. C, D: N = 3, {0.1, 0.1, 0.8}. Intra-country moments are for the small (C) and

N and size patterns: The first five columns represent models of symmetric size. Sizes are 1/N . A, B: N = 2, {0.1, 0.9}. Intra-country

N 2 3 5 10 Size 0.5 0.33 0.2 0.1 Standard deviation relative to standard deviation Consumption 0.29 0.24 0.22 0.20 Investment 13.21 13.56 13.75 13.87 Labor 0.56 0.57 0.58 0.58 Net exports 3.33 3.42 3.47 3.50 Correlation to output Consumption 0.73 0.75 0.77 0.80 Investment 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.04 Labor 0.97 0.98 0.99 0.99 Net exports 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.22 Autocorrelation Output 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Consumption 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Investment 0.79 0.79 0.80 0.80 Labor 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Net exports 0.80 0.80 0.80 0.80 Cross-country correlation Output −0.72 −0.36 −0.17 −0.06 Consumption 0.64 0.60 0.56 0.53 Investment −0.99 −0.50 −0.25 −0.11 Labor −0.96 −0.48 −0.23 −0.10 Net exports −1.00 −0.50 −0.25 −0.11

Table C2: Business Cycle Moments of Baseline Model

34

B 0.9 1.84 6.60 1.25 0.46 0.28 0.34 0.26 0.11 0.86 0.93 0.91 0.92 0.92 −0.49 0.94 −0.20 0.57 −1.00

A 0.1 0.66 5.18 0.85 1.65 −0.06 −0.09 0.84 0.69 0.91 0.93 0.88 0.92 0.92 −0.49 0.94 −0.20 0.57 −1.00

0.20 0.91 0.24 0.59 0.32

0.92 0.93 0.87 0.92 0.92

0.00 0.03 0.87 0.62

0.58 5.23 0.79 1.55

C 0.1

−0.47 0.92 −0.27 0.44 −0.81

0.88 0.93 0.90 0.92 0.92

0.39 0.30 0.30 0.17

1.47 6.03 0.97 0.72

D 0.8

−0.08 0.84 −0.03 0.16 −0.12

0.92 0.93 0.87 0.92 0.92

0.37 0.17 0.87 0.47

0.50 5.37 0.64 1.37

E 0.1

0.37 0.28 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.93 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.77 0.75 0.74 −0.36

0.91 2.60 1.04 0.61

Data

from Table 1.

E: N = 19, {{0.1} × 9, {0.01} × 10}. Cross-country correlations are of first two countries. The data (median of G7 countries) is taken

large (D) countries. Cross-country correlations are of the two small countries (C), and the large and one of the small countries (D).

moments are for the first (A) and second (B) countries. C, D: N = 3, {0.1, 0.1, 0.8}. Intra-country moments are for the small (C) and

N and size patterns: The first five columns represent models of symmetric size. Sizes are 1/N . A, B: N = 2, {0.1, 0.9}. Intra-country

N 2 3 5 10 20 Size 0.5 0.33 0.2 0.1 0.05 Standard deviation relative to standard deviation of output Consumption 1.01 0.75 0.60 0.51 0.48 Investment 5.68 5.46 5.39 5.37 5.37 Labor 0.87 0.75 0.69 0.65 0.64 Net exports 1.38 1.38 1.38 1.38 1.38 Correlation to output Consumption 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.37 Investment 0.06 0.10 0.13 0.16 0.17 Labor 0.63 0.75 0.82 0.86 0.88 Net exports 0.56 0.52 0.50 0.48 0.47 Autocorrelation Output 0.90 0.91 0.91 0.92 0.92 Consumption 0.93 0.93 0.93 0.93 0.93 Investment 0.89 0.88 0.87 0.87 0.87 Labor 0.92 0.92 0.92 0.92 0.92 Net exports 0.92 0.92 0.92 0.92 0.92 Cross-country correlation Output −0.76 −0.40 −0.19 −0.07 −0.02 Consumption 0.93 0.90 0.88 0.85 0.84 Investment −0.38 −0.22 −0.10 −0.02 0.02 Labor 0.27 0.20 0.19 0.19 0.19 Net exports −1.00 −0.50 −0.24 −0.11 −0.05

Table C3: Business Cycle Moments of Backus et al. (1992) Model

35

0.83 1.77 0.12 0.11

1.18 3.12 0.44 1.05 0.84 0.73 0.01 −0.30 0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.48 −0.05 −0.24 0.55 −1.00

0.94 0.89 −0.34 −0.64 0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.37 0.13 0.07 0.06 −0.05

0.48 −0.05 −0.24 0.55 −1.00

0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90

1.00 0.99 0.94 −0.54

B 0.9

A 0.1

20 0.05 of output 1.21 3.09 0.29 0.84

0.41 0.15 0.13 0.56 0.32

0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90

0.86 0.76 −0.04 −0.35

1.19 3.11 0.41 1.01

C 0.1

0.46 −0.03 −0.21 0.36 −0.81

0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90

0.99 0.98 0.83 −0.61

0.87 1.91 0.11 0.19

D 0.8

0.38 0.11 0.04 0.00 −0.12

0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90

0.94 0.89 −0.30 −0.62

1.19 3.01 0.28 0.81

E 0.1

0.37 0.28 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.93 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.77 0.75 0.74 −0.36

0.91 2.60 1.04 0.61

Data

Table 1.

N = 19, {{0.1} × 9, {0.01} × 10}. Cross-country correlations are of first two countries. The data (median of G7 countries) is taken from

large (D) countries. Cross-country correlations are of the two small countries (C), and the large and one of the small countries (D). E:

moments are for the first (A) and second (B) countries. C, D: N = 3, {0.1, 0.1, 0.8}. Intra-country moments are for the small (C) and

N and size patterns: The first five columns represent models of symmetric size. Sizes are 1/N . A, B: N = 2, {0.1, 0.9}. Intra-country

N 2 3 5 10 Size 0.5 0.33 0.2 0.1 Standard deviation relative to standard deviation Consumption 1.00 1.07 1.14 1.19 Investment 2.40 2.65 2.86 3.02 Labor 0.22 0.25 0.27 0.28 Net exports 0.56 0.67 0.75 0.81 Correlation to output Consumption 0.95 0.94 0.94 0.94 Investment 0.89 0.88 0.88 0.89 Labor 0.16 −0.04 −0.18 −0.29 Net exports −0.43 −0.51 −0.57 −0.62 Autocorrelation Output 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Consumption 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Investment 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Labor 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Net exports 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Cross-country correlation Output 0.46 0.43 0.41 0.38 Consumption −0.08 0.01 0.07 0.11 Investment −0.32 −0.14 −0.03 0.04 Labor −0.37 −0.17 −0.05 0.02 Net exports −1.00 −0.50 −0.24 −0.11

Table C4: Business Cycle Moments of Baxter and Crucini (1995) Model

36

B 0.9 0.81 1.69 0.13 0.04 1.00 1.00 0.99 −0.57 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.46 0.19 0.07 0.93 −1.00

A 0.1 0.94 2.16 0.18 0.43 0.96 0.92 0.35 −0.41 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.45 0.19 0.07 0.93 −1.00

0.39 0.22 0.18 0.91 0.32

0.91 0.90 0.90 0.91 0.90

0.97 0.94 0.34 −0.46

0.95 2.16 0.17 0.41

C 0.1

0.44 0.19 0.08 0.92 −0.81

0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90

1.00 1.00 0.98 −0.65

0.83 1.74 0.12 0.08

D 0.8

0.37 0.22 0.17 0.76 −0.12

0.91 0.90 0.90 0.91 0.90

0.99 0.97 0.36 −0.72

0.96 2.17 0.10 0.32

E 0.1

0.37 0.28 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.93 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.77 0.75 0.74 −0.36

0.91 2.60 1.04 0.61

Data

Table 1.

N = 19, {{0.1} × 9, {0.01} × 10}. Cross-country correlations are of first two countries. The data (median of G7 countries) is taken from

large (D) countries. Cross-country correlations are of the two small countries (C), and the large and one of the small countries (D). E:

moments are for the first (A) and second (B) countries. C, D: N = 3, {0.1, 0.1, 0.8}. Intra-country moments are for the small (C) and

N and size patterns: The first five columns represent models of symmetric size. Sizes are 1/N . A, B: N = 2, {0.1, 0.9}. Intra-country

N 2 3 5 10 20 Size 0.5 0.33 0.2 0.1 0.05 Standard deviation relative to standard deviation of output Consumption 0.88 0.91 0.93 0.96 0.97 Investment 1.91 2.02 2.10 2.17 2.20 Labor 0.13 0.12 0.11 0.11 0.10 Net exports 0.23 0.27 0.30 0.33 0.34 Correlation to output Consumption 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 Investment 0.98 0.97 0.97 0.97 0.97 Labor 0.73 0.60 0.48 0.36 0.30 Net exports −0.50 −0.59 −0.66 −0.71 −0.74 Autocorrelation Output 0.90 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Consumption 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Investment 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Labor 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Net exports 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Cross-country correlation Output 0.45 0.42 0.39 0.37 0.36 Consumption 0.19 0.20 0.21 0.22 0.23 Investment 0.06 0.11 0.14 0.17 0.18 Labor 0.86 0.83 0.80 0.77 0.74 Net exports −1.00 −0.50 −0.24 −0.11 −0.05

Table C5: Business Cycle Moments of Baxter and Farr (2005) Model

37

B 0.9 0.55 2.63 0.38 0.01 0.91 0.96 0.91 0.06 0.90 0.91 0.89 0.88 0.95 0.13 0.74 −0.58 −0.59 −0.34

A 0.1 0.56 4.12 0.36 0.23 0.93 0.86 0.92 −0.58 0.90 0.91 0.88 0.89 0.88 0.14 0.74 −0.57 −0.59 −0.34

0.18 0.68 −0.07 −0.27 0.30

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 0.89

0.92 0.92 0.93 −0.61

0.51 3.64 0.39 0.14

C 0.1

0.17 0.68 −0.31 −0.25 −0.23

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 0.96

0.90 0.97 0.93 0.15

0.50 2.75 0.40 0.01

D 0.8

0.55 0.72 0.46 0.43 0.16

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 0.93

0.93 0.98 0.97 −0.33

0.43 2.92 0.43 0.01

E 0.1

0.37 0.28 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.93 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.77 0.75 0.74 −0.36

0.91 2.60 1.04 0.61

Data

Table 1.

N = 19, {{0.1} × 9, {0.01} × 10}. Cross-country correlations are of first two countries. The data (median of G7 countries) is taken from

large (D) countries. Cross-country correlations are of the two small countries (C), and the large and one of the small countries (D). E:

moments are for the first (A) and second (B) countries. C, D: N = 3, {0.1, 0.1, 0.8}. Intra-country moments are for the small (C) and

N and size patterns: The first five columns represent models of symmetric size. Sizes are 1/N . A, B: N = 2, {0.1, 0.9}. Intra-country

N 2 3 5 10 20 Size 0.5 0.33 0.2 0.1 0.05 Standard deviation relative to standard deviation of output Consumption 0.55 0.50 0.47 0.44 0.41 Investment 3.24 3.22 3.20 3.19 3.22 Labor 0.38 0.40 0.42 0.43 0.43 Net exports 0.10 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.05 Correlation to output Consumption 0.91 0.90 0.91 0.92 0.93 Investment 0.91 0.94 0.96 0.97 0.98 Labor 0.91 0.93 0.95 0.96 0.97 Net exports −0.55 −0.62 −0.65 −0.67 −0.69 Autocorrelation Output 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Consumption 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.92 Investment 0.88 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.89 Labor 0.88 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.89 Net exports 0.88 0.89 0.90 0.90 0.90 Cross-country correlation Output 0.17 0.19 0.27 0.41 0.57 Consumption 0.81 0.73 0.69 0.69 0.74 Investment −0.57 −0.22 0.01 0.24 0.47 Labor −0.60 −0.27 −0.03 0.21 0.45 Net exports −1.00 −0.50 −0.21 0.05 0.33

Table C6: Business Cycle Moments of Backus et al. (1994) Model

38

B 0.9 0.80 1.67 0.14 0.07 1.00 1.00 0.98 −0.44 0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.51 −0.05 0.30 0.84 −0.57

A 0.1 0.86 1.90 0.12 0.10 0.99 0.98 0.84 −0.53 0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.32 0.26 0.13 0.69 0.73

0.33 0.30 0.24 0.63 0.25

0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90

1.00 0.99 0.91 −0.61

0.85 1.87 0.12 0.08

C 0.1

0.36 0.27 0.19 0.72 −0.53

0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90

1.00 1.00 0.98 −0.53

0.80 1.68 0.14 0.06

D 0.8

0.60 0.60 0.58 0.62 0.20

0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.90

1.00 1.00 0.98 −0.69

0.80 1.71 0.14 0.03

E 0.1

0.37 0.28 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.93 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.77 0.75 0.74 −0.36

0.91 2.60 1.04 0.61

Data

Table 1.

N = 19, {{0.1} × 9, {0.01} × 10}. Cross-country correlations are of first two countries. The data (median of G7 countries) is taken from

large (D) countries. Cross-country correlations are of the two small countries (C), and the large and one of the small countries (D). E:

moments are for the first (A) and second (B) countries. C, D: N = 3, {0.1, 0.1, 0.8}. Intra-country moments are for the small (C) and

N and size patterns: The first five columns represent models of symmetric size. Sizes are 1/N . A, B: N = 2, {0.1, 0.9}. Intra-country

N 2 3 5 10 20 Size 0.5 0.33 0.2 0.1 0.05 Standard deviation relative to standard deviation of output Consumption 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82 Investment 1.81 1.83 1.83 1.84 1.85 Labor 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.12 0.12 Net exports 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.04 Correlation to output Consumption 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Investment 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 Labor 0.97 0.97 0.98 0.98 0.98 Net exports −0.52 −0.65 −0.74 −0.82 −0.85 Autocorrelation Output 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Consumption 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 0.91 Investment 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Labor 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Net exports 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 Cross-country correlation Output 0.38 0.35 0.39 0.49 0.62 Consumption 0.31 0.31 0.36 0.47 0.61 Investment 0.13 0.20 0.29 0.43 0.59 Labor 0.66 0.56 0.53 0.58 0.67 Net exports −0.96 −0.49 −0.21 0.05 0.32

Table C7: Business Cycle Moments of Arvanitis and Mikkola (1996) Model

39

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 – 0.62 0.78 0.53 0.49 –

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 – 0.50 0.75 0.35 0.27 –

0.29 0.81 −0.22 −0.50 –

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.88 – 0.48 1.00 0.97 −0.49 –

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 –

0.96 0.97 0.91 –

0.94 0.98 0.96 –

0.93 0.98 0.95 –

0.30 0.75 −0.03 −0.20 –

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 –

0.92 0.97 0.92 –

0.54 2.63 0.38 –

0.63 2.27 0.30 –

0.93 0.96 0.90 –

C 0.1

B 0.9

10 20 A 0.1 0.05 0.1 deviation of output 0.49 0.46 0.58 2.72 2.78 2.51 0.39 0.41 0.35 – – –

0.31 0.76 −0.06 −0.26 –

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 –

0.95 0.97 0.91 –

0.60 2.40 0.33 –

D 0.8

0.52 0.71 0.41 0.35 –

0.90 0.91 0.89 0.89 –

0.94 0.98 0.96 –

0.46 2.78 0.40 –

E 0.1

0.37 0.28 0.23 0.23 −0.02

0.93 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.91

0.77 0.75 0.74 −0.36

0.91 2.60 1.04 0.61

Data

of G7 countries) is taken from Table 1.

small countries (D). E: N = 19, {{0.1} × 9, {0.01} × 10}. Cross-country correlations are of first two countries. The data (median

small (C) and large (D) countries. Cross-country correlations are of the two small countries (C), and the large and one of the

country moments are for the first (A) and second (B) countries. C, D: N = 3, {0.1, 0.1, 0.8}. Intra-country moments are for the

N and size patterns: The first five columns represent models of symmetric size. Sizes are 1/N . A, B: N = 2, {0.1, 0.9}. Intra-

N 2 3 5 Size 0.5 0.33 0.2 Standard deviation relative to standard Consumption 0.63 0.57 0.53 Investment 2.29 2.51 2.63 Labor 0.30 0.35 0.38 Net exports – – – Correlation to output Consumption 0.95 0.93 0.93 Investment 0.97 0.97 0.97 Labor 0.90 0.91 0.93 Net exports – – – Autocorrelation Output 0.90 0.90 0.90 Consumption 0.91 0.91 0.91 Investment 0.89 0.89 0.89 Labor 0.89 0.89 0.89 Net exports – – – Cross-country correlation Output 0.61 0.47 0.43 Consumption 0.92 0.84 0.77 Investment 0.20 0.12 0.20 Labor −0.14 −0.08 0.07 Net exports – – –

Table C8: Business Cycle Moments of Heathcote and Perri (2002) Model

Figure C1: Cross-country Correlations and Number of Countries in the Baseline Model

Cross−country correlations

1

0.5

←Y ←C ←I, L ←NX

0

Output Consumption Investment Labor Net exports

−0.5

−1 2

5

8 11 14 Number of countries

17

20

The solid lines show the model’s cross-country correlations, given the number of countries in the model. The filled symbols represent positive values whereas the open symbols negative values. The interrupted lines represent data values taken from Table A1. The multi-country versions of King et al. (1988), with no shock diffusion and complete market.

40

Figure C2: Cross-country Correlations and Number of Countries in Baxter and Farr (2005) Model

Cross−country correlations

1

0.5

←Y ←C ←I, L ←NX

0

Output Consumption Investment Labor Net exports

−0.5

−1 2

5

8 11 14 Number of countries

17

20

The solid lines show the model’s cross-country correlations, given the number of countries in the model. The filled symbols represent positive values whereas the open symbols negative values. The interrupted lines represent data values. The multi-country versions of Baxter and Farr (2005), with no shock diffusion and a bond only market.

Figure C3: Cross-country Correlations and Number of Countries in Arvanitis and Mikkola (1996) Model

Cross−country correlations

1

0.5

←Y ←C ←I, L ←NX

0

Output Consumption Investment Labor Net exports

−0.5

−1 2

5

8 11 14 Number of countries

17

20

The solid lines show the model’s cross-country correlations, given the number of countries in the model. The filled symbols represent positive values whereas the open symbols negative values. The interrupted lines represent data values. The multi-country versions of Arvanitis and Mikkola (1996), no shock diffusion and a bond only market.

41

D

Impulse Response Functions and Intuition

Impulse response functions (IRFs) of the baseline single-good model illustrate the mechanisms behind the moment results. Figures D4 and D5 are IRFs of output, consumption, investment, labor, net exports and TFP. The X axis represents the model time period, with the shock hitting the economies at period 0. The vertical axis shows the percentage deviations of the variables from the steady state values. Both models use baseline single-good technology, a complete market assumption and a shock that excludes the cross-country diffusion component (ωih = 0). The figures are drawn from correlated shocks; at period 0, a 1% positive TFP shock hits Country 1 and a 0.12% positive TFP shock hits Country 2. Other countries in the ten-country model do not experience shocks. Figure D4 is derived from a two-country model, and Figure D5 from a ten-country model. The upper and lower panels in Figure D4 show IRFs for countries 1 and 2, respectively. Similarly, The upper and middle panels in Figure D5 are the IRFs of Country 1 and Country 2, respectively. Since the remaining countries are completely symmetric, the lower panel of Figure D5 shows IRFs of the remaining countries. Figure D4 indicates that, after the positive productivity shock in the two-country model, Country 1 experiences a boom and Country 2 a recession; a large positive TFP shock stimulates investment in Country 1; and the investment spike leads to a higher labor supply in Country 1. Output rises since capital stock, labor and TFP increase. Country 2 also experiences a positive productivity shock (TFP line of Country 2). Nonetheless, in the two-country model, investment in Country 2 decreases, since the higher marginal return to investment in Country 1 attracts investment away from Country 2 to Country 1, as indicated by large changes in net exports. The reduction in investment leads to a decrease in the labor supply in Country 2. The output then decreases, despite the positive TFP shock, because of a large decline in input. The complete market assumption ensures consumption increments in both countries and the consumption correlation is strongly positive. The implications are drastically different in a ten-country model. As in the two-country model, Country 1 experiences a boom (the upper panel of Figure D5), by inducing investments from other countries. In addition, the correlated shocks in the ten-country model lead to a boom in the secondhighest TFP country. The middle panel of Figure D5 shows that, in Country 2, there is a slight rise in investment in the ten-country model. Other variables also increase, although the magnitude of the increments is smaller than in the case of Country 1. In the ten-country model, the diminishing marginal returns for capital in the highest TFP country (Country 1) lead to an investment inflow to the second-highest TFP country (Country 2). As a result, cross-country correlations of investment, labor and output are positive between Countries 1 and 2. At the same time, internal investments decrease in Countries 3 to 10 (the lower panel of Figure D5). Cross-country correlations among these 28 (= 8 × 7/2) pairs are positive because all these countries experience reductions in output, investment and labor. This particular correlated shock delivers two types of positive cross-country correlations of investment: one increasing pair and 28 decreasing pairs. The other 16 (= 10 × 9/2 − 1 − 28) combinations are negatively correlated.

42

Figure D4: Impulse Response Functions (Two-country Model) (+1% TFP shock to Country 1, +.12% TFP shock to Country 2.) Country 1

Deviations from the steady state

4 3 2 1 Output Consumption Investment Labor Net expopts TFP

0 −1 −2 −5

0

5 Period

10

15

Country 2

Deviations from the steady state

4 Output Consumption Investment Labor Net expopts TFP

3 2 1 0 −1 −2 −5

0

5 Period

43

10

15

Figure D5: Impulse Response Functions (Ten-country Model) (+1% TFP Shock to Country 1, +.12% TFP Shock to Country 2, No Shock to Others) Country 1

Deviations from the steady state

4 3 2 1 Output Consumption Investment Labor Net expopts TFP

0 −1 −2 −5

0

5 Period

10

15

Country 2

Deviations from the steady state

4 Output Consumption Investment Labor Net expopts TFP

3 2 1 0 −1 −2 −5

0

5 Period

10

15

Country 3, ..., Country 10

Deviations from the steady state

4 Output Consumption Investment Labor Net expopts TFP

3 2 1 0 −1 −2 −5

0

5 Period

44

10

15

References Anderson, Gary S. (2008) “Solving Linear Rational Expectation Models: A Horse Race,” Computational Economics, Vol. 31, No. 2, pp. 95–113, March. Arvanitis, Athanasios V. and Anne Mikkola (1996) “Asset-Market Structure and International Trade Dynamics,” American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 2, pp. 67–70, May. Backus, David K., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Finn E. Kydland (1992) “International Real Business Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, No. 4, pp. 745–775, August. (1994) “Dynamics of the Trade Balance and the Terms of Trade: The J-Curve?” American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 1, pp. 84–103, March. Baxter, Marianne and Mario J. Crucini (1993) “Explaining Saving-Investment Correlations,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 3, pp. 416–436, June. (1995) “Business Cycles and the Asset Structure of Foreign Trade,” International Economic Review, Vol. 36, No. 4, pp. 821–854, November. Baxter, Marianne and Dorsey D. Farr (2005) “Variable Capital Utilization and International Business Cycles,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 65, No. 2, pp. 335–347, March. Baxter, Marianne and Robert G. King (1999) “Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time Series,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 81, No. 4, pp. 575–593, November. Ghironi, Fabio and Mark J. Melitz (2005) “International Trade and Macroeconomic Dynamics with Heterogeneous Firms,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 120, No. 3, pp. 865–915, August. Heathcote, Jonathan and Fabrizio Perri (2002) “Financial autarky and international business cycles,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49, No. 3, pp. 601–627, April. Heston, Alan, Robert Summers, and Bettina Aten (2008) “Penn World Table version 6.2,” Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Hodrick, Robert J. and Edward C. Prescott (1997) “Postwar US Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 29, No. 1, pp. 1–16, February. King, Robert G., Charles I. Plosser, and Sergio T. Rebelo (1988) “Production, Growth and Business Cycles I: The Basic Neoclassical Model,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 21, No. 2/3, pp. 195–232, March-May. Kollmann, Robert (1996) “Incomplete Asset Markets and the Cross-country Consumption Correlation Puzzle,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 20, No. 5, pp. 946–961, May. Kydland, Finn and Edwar Prescott (1982) “Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica, Vol. 50, No. 6, pp. 1345–1370, November.

45

Separate Appendix (Not for publication) to “The World ...

Feb 18, 2014 - in the system of the baseline model are Ai,t, Ki,t for all i = 1, ..., N. In an ... where Ai,t is the country-specific total factor productivity (TFP) and Ii,t is ...

231KB Sizes 1 Downloads 112 Views

Recommend Documents

Not"for"Publication Appendix to XOptimal Asymptotic ...
which implies that rank [*/$%$(%#,$#)*!(#,!)] φ K. S for (A.1) to be true. Thus, after imposing that φ #, the reduced system of distance functions */$0 [7%,3(#,!)] will first#order identify ! at !#. (ii) Since the transformation from $ to ( ,!) is

Not"for"Publication Appendix to XOptimal Asymptotic ...
Let the Jacobians of the inverse transformation be given by. *( ,!) φ д3( ,!) д( /,!/)φ [ * ( ,!) *!( ,!) ]. 1As noted by Peñaranda and Sentana (2012), it is possible to ...

Not-for-Publication Appendix to “An International Dynamic Term ...
data YT , calculate estimates for ft as E(ft|YT ,φ(n)). To this end, notice that the ... Thus, we can safely apply our inter-battery factor analysis to de- meaned data.

NOT FOR PUBLICATION Online Appendix to “Can ...
Nov 3, 2009 - Online Appendix to “Can Higher Prices Stimulate Product Use? ..... partially determines the degree of price sensitivity in the purchase decision.

Not for Publication Appendix for: Interest Rate Rules ...
Sep 26, 2011 - it+1 = ρcsC it + (1 − ρc)cit. .... is not the case for high degree of deep habit formation. ... the higher degree of deep habits will drive the markups ...

Not for Publication Appendix for: Interest Rate ... - Banque du Canada
demand also causes marginal product of capital to rise. This higher expected rate of return on capital leads to more investment. This rise in both consumption ...

Not-for-Publication Appendix: On Fiscal Multipliers ...
Jan 23, 2013 - As mentioned above, the tax rate processes are assumed to be persistent. The tax rate elasticities to debt are assumed to have a gamma distribution with a mean of 0.5 and a standard deviation of 0.2, which is similar to. Forni, Montefo

Not-for-Publication Appendix to: What Is the Importance ...
Dec 22, 2010 - Phone: (919) 660-1801. Phone: (613) ... State and local net interest payments to persons ... net taxes are added to the baseline VAR. That is ...

Not-for-Publication Appendix to: What Is the Importance ...
Dec 22, 2010 - Email: [email protected]. Email: [email protected] .... ply (M1) following the benchmark recursive identification schemes ...

Appendix B Available online – Not for publication B.1 ...
This online appendix fully solves the model of duopolistic (Cournot and Bertrand) down- .... supply network g when all wholesale prices are equal to c are. Ddca.

Online Appendices - Not for publication Optimal price ...
the last price change (see Online Appendix B-2.2.2 for details). For future ..... paper, it is easy to show that the value function is homogenous of degree 1 − η. In this case we ...... Fabiani, S., C.S. Loupias, F.M.M. Martins, and R. Sabbatini.

NOT FOR PUBLICATION UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS ...
Feb 23, 2018 - Appeal from the United States District Court for the Eastern District of California. Erica P. Grosjean, Magistrate Judge, Presiding. Submitted ...

Online Appendices - Not for publication Optimal price ...
square root formula gives a good approximation, so that second order costs of observation gathering give .... the last price change (see Online Appendix B-2.2.2 for details). ..... Lippi (2009) for a saving and portfolio problem for households. As in

Online Appendix: What's Not to Trust? Rubrics of ...
from the class-based coalition, Central de los Trabajadores (CTA); vocational school students from the working-class districts of Vicente López and General San ...

NOT FOR PUBLICATION UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS ...
Jan 23, 2015 - decision because all of the dates described below run from that date, not from the date you receive this notice. Mandate (Fed. R. App. P. 41; 9th ...

NOT FOR PUBLICATION UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS ...
Jan 23, 2015 - 10; JANES DOES 1-10; DOE ... CORPORATIONS 1-10; DOE ENTITIES .... http://cdn.ca9.uscourts.gov/datastore/uploads/forms/Form%2010%20 ...

Online Appendices - Not for publication Optimal price ...
have solved for the expected values, and we have also subsumed the choice of the price into the function v. We can ..... the last price change (see Online Appendix B-2.2.2 for details). For future ...... “Menu Costs and the Neutrality of Money.”.

Not for publication until 11 May 2015 To: Mr ... - Access Info Europe
May 11, 2015 - Commission to take strong and urgent action to create a high-quality and ... a better balance between corporate and public interest groups in.

Not for publication until 11 May 2015 To: Mr ... - Access Info Europe
Vice President European Commission cc. Michelle Sutton, Deputy Head of Cabinet. Rue de la Loi 200,. 1049 Brussels. Belgium. 11 May 2015. Dear First ...

1 Not For Publication Online Materials The Impact of ...
1. Not For Publication. Online Materials. The Impact of Financial Education for Youth in Ghana. James Berry, Dean Karlan, and Menno Pradhan ... (higher = lower discount rate of the future). (0.070). (0.076). (0.089). Financial Literacy Index. -0.038.

Coordinating Separate Markets for Externalities
Mar 27, 2018 - 2.1 The PJM Electricity Market. The Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland (PJM) Interconnection operates the world's largest wholesale electricity market as the regional transmission organization (RTO) for the area that encompasses all or p

Separate tests for Electronics, Electrical, Civil ... - MOBILPASAR.COM
Mechanical Engineering: Thermodynamics, Fluid Mechanics, Theory of Machines, Kinematics of. Machines, I.C. Engines & Compressors, SOM, Engineering material, Meteorology. Electronics Engineering: Microprocessor & Microcontrollers, Digital Electronics,