Supplementary Appendix to: Perpetual Learning and Apparent Long Memory Guillaume Chevillon ESSEC Business School & CREST

Sophocles Mavroeidis University of Oxford

April 13, 2017

Contents 1 Proof of Lemma 6 1.1

1.2

2

Preliminary results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

2

1.1.1

Proof of Lemma S.1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

2

1.1.2

Proof of Lemma S.2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3

Proof of Lemma 6 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

5

2 Proof of Lemma 7

7

3 Proof of Lemma 8

7

1

1

Proof of Lemma 6

1.1

Preliminary results

To derive our results we first need the following lemmas, S.1 and S.2. Lemma S.1. Let f a spectral density with f, f 0 and f 00 bounded, f > 0 in a neighborhood of the origin and f 0 (0) = 0. Let δ ∈ (0, 1) and define the sequence (  −δ f 2π T j j , j ≤ T; aj = f (0) j −δ , j > T. Then {aj } is of pure bounded variation, defined as

P∞

j=n |∆aj |

(S–1)

= O (an ) as n → ∞ (Yong,

1974, Definition I-4).  Lemma S.2. For δ ∈ (0, 1) , as T ω, ω −1 → (∞, ∞) T X

aj cos jω ∼

πf (0) ω δ−1 ; 2Γ (δ) cos δπ 2

aj sin jω ∼

πf (0) ω δ−1 , 2Γ (δ) sin δπ 2

j=1 T X j=1

where {aj } is defined in Lemma S.1. 1.1.1

Proof of Lemma S.1

When j ≤ T, the difference ∆aj can be decomposed into h i f (ωj ) (j − 1)δ − j δ f (ωj ) − f (ωj−1 ) ∆aj = + , δ δ j (j − 1) (j − 1)δ where a Taylor expansion yields   1 f (ωj ) − f (ωj−1 ) = f 00 (ωj−1 ) (∆ωj )2 + o (∆ωj )2 , 2 and h i f (ωj ) (j − 1)δ − j δ

h = f (ωj )

j δ (j − 1)δ

i (1 − 1/j)δ − 1 (j − 1)δ

−δ = f (ωj ) 1+δ + o j

Since f and f 00 are bounded, there exist m0 , m2 > such that m2 m0 δ |∆aj | ≤ 1+δ + δ j 2j



2π T

2 .

2



1 j 1+δ

 .

When j > T, the latter expression also holds with m2 = 0 so for all j :   m0 δ m2 2π 2 |∆aj | ≤ 1+δ + δ 1{j≤T } , T j 2j where 1{·} is the indicator function. Now consider N ≥ T ≥ n, then N X

|∆aj | =

j=n

T X

N X

|∆aj | +

j=n

|∆aj | ,

(S–2)

j=T +1

since for j ≤ T, T −2 ≤ j −2 , the previous expression rewrites as  N N T  X X X 2π 2 m2 m0 δ + + |∆aj | |∆aj | ≤ j 1+δ j 2+δ j=n

j=n

j=T +1

i h i 2π 2 m h 2 n−1−δ − (T + 1)−1−δ . ≤ m0 n−δ − (N + 1)−δ + 1+δ Letting N → ∞, there exists M such that   ∞ X M 2π 2 m2 1 −δ + δ+1 , |∆aj | ≤ n m0 + 1+δ n T j=n

and then if an 6= 0, h m0 +

P∞

j=n |∆aj |

an



f

i

2π 2 m2 + n−δM 1+δ T δ+1  2π T min {n, T }

.

We now use the fact that f is bounded above zero in a neighborhood of the origin so for  −δ δ+1 → ∞ as n → ∞. Therefore, there T large enough, f 2π T n > 0. Also for n ≤ T, n T P∞ |∆aT,j | ≤ M0 , i.e. exist (n0 , M0 ) such that for all n ≥ n0 with an 6= 0 and for T ≥ n, j=nan P∞ j=n |∆aj | = O (an ) . P −δ = a so Now assume that T ≤ n, the previous expressions yield ∞ n j=n |∆aj | ≤ f (0) n the results also hold. 1.1.2

Proof of Lemma S.2

Introduce the Dirichlet kernel: T

DT (ω) =

1 X sin (T + 1/2) ω + cos jω = , 2 2 sin ω2 j=1

where |DT (ω) − 1/2| ≤ πω −1 for 0 < ω ≤ π (Yong, 1974, p.39). Then, for all ω > 0 and T < N, N X j=T +1

aj cos jω = f (0)

N X

j −δ cos jω.

j=T +1

3

Then X N −δ j cos jω j=T +1 NX       −1  −δ 1 1 1 + N −δ DN (ω) − − T −δ DT (ω) − = Dj (ω) − j − (j + 1)−δ 2 2 2 j=T N −1 X 1 1 1 −δ −δ −δ −δ ≤ j − (j + 1) Dj (ω) − + N DN (ω) − + T DT (ω) − . (S–3) 2 2 2 j=T

 −δ  h −δ  −1 We notice that j −δ − (j + 1)−δ = j −δ 1 − 1 + j −1 ∈ j δj − so j −δ − (j + 1)−δ ≤ δj −δ−1 . It follows that

δ(δ+1) 2j 2



, j −δ δj −1

i

X   N −δ ≤ δπω −1 T −δ − N −δ + N −δ πω −1 + T −δ πω −1 j cos jω j=T +1 = (1 + δ) πω −1 T −δ + (1 − δ) πω −1 N −δ . Hence letting N → ∞, for all T, ω > 0, X ∞ X T −δ −δ ≤ (1 + δ) πω −1 T −δ . j cos jω − j cos jω j=1 j=1

(S–4)

Now, Yong (1974), Theorem III-17, states that for δ ∈ (0, 1) since {aj } is of pure bounded variation ∞ X

aj cos jω

j=1



ω→0+

πf (0) ω δ−1 . δπ 2Γ (δ) cos 2

  Hence, in expression (S–4), as T, ω −1 → (∞, ∞): ω −1 T −δ = o ω δ−1 if ω −1 = o (T ) , in which case T X j=1

aj cos jω

∼ (T ω,ω)→(∞,0)

πf (0) ω δ−1 . 2Γ (δ) cos δπ 2

P −δ sin jω < When the summation involves a sine function, the proof is similar: ∞ j j=T +1

(1 + δ) πω −1 T −δ using the conjugate Dirichlet kernel:  T X cos ω2 − cos T + 21 ω DT (ω) = sin jω = , 2 sin ω2 j=1

with DT (ω) ≤ πω −1 (also Yong, 1974, p. 39). Then an equivalent of expression (S–4) holds for the summation involving sine functions and we also refer to Theorem III-17 of Yong. 4

1.2

Proof of Lemma 6

First, if k = 0,

PT

j=1 j

−δ f

 (ωj ) = O T 1−δ since f (ωT ) = f (0) 6= 0 so for δ 6= 1 the results

follows. We now assume k 6= 0. Lemma S.2 implies as (k, T /k) → (∞, ∞) that for δ ∈ (0, 1) , T

δ

T X f (ωj ) cos (jωk ) j=1



πf (0) ∼ 2Γ (δ) cos δπ 2

  k δ−1 δ 2π T . T

(S–5)

Now, let δ ∈ (−1, 0) . We use a procedure similar to integration by part to express (S–5) P in terms of Tj=1 j −(δ+1) fx (ωj ) sin (jωk ) where δ + 1 ∈ (0, 1) which allows to work alongside the previous results. Start with (j + 1)−δ sin ((j + 1) ωk ) − j −δ sin (jωk )   = (j + 1)−δ − j −δ sin ((j + 1) ωk ) + j −δ {sin ((j + 1) ωk ) − sin (jωk )} ,  where (j + 1)−δ − j −δ = −δ (j + 1)−δ−1 + o j −δ−1 and sin ((j + 1) ωk ) − sin (jωk ) = sin (jωk ) (cos (ωk ) − 1) + cos (jωk ) sin (ωk ) . Hence T h X

i (j + 1)−δ sin ((j + 1) ωk ) − j −δ sin (jωk )

j=1

=

T n  o X −δ (j + 1)−δ−1 + o (j + 1)−δ−1 sin ((j + 1) ωk ) j=1

+ sin (ωk )

T X

j −δ cos (jωk ) + (cos (ωk ) − 1)

j=1

T X

j −δ sin (jωk ) ,

j=1

i.e. since k 6= 0 : T X

j −δ cos (jωk ) = (T + 1)−δ

j=1

sin (T + 1) ωk −1−δ sin (ωk )

T T +1 X cos (ωk ) − 1 X −δ δ j sin (jωk ) + j −(1+δ) sin (jωk ) sin (ωk ) sin (ωk ) j=1 j=1 ! PT +1 −(1+δ) sin (jωk ) j=2 j +o . sin (ωk )



Similarly, since cos ((j + 1) ωk ) − cos (jωk ) = cos (jωk )) (cos (ωk ) − 1) − sin (jωk ) sin ωk , we can express: 5

T X

j −δ sin (jωk ) = − (T + 1)−δ

j=1

cos ωk cos (T + 1) ωk + (1 + δ) sin (ωk ) sin ωk

T T +1 X cos (ωk ) − 1 X −δ δ + j cos (jωk ) − j −(1+δ) cos (jωk ) sin (ωk ) sin (ωk ) j=1 j=1 ! PT +1 −(1+δ) cos (jωk ) j=2 j +o . sin (ωk )

Plugging

PT

j=1 j

−δ

sin (jωk ) in the expression for

(cos (ωk ) − 1)2 1+ sin2 (ωk )

!

T X

PT

j=1 j

−δ

cos (jωk ) yields:

j −δ cos (jωk )

j=1

sin (ωk ) sin [(T + 1) ωk ] + (cos (ωk ) − 1) cos [(T + 1) ωk ] = (T + 1)−δ sin2 (ωk )   cos (ωk ) − 1 − (1 + δ) 1 + cos ωk sin2 (ωk ) T +1 T +1 X δ cos (ωk ) − 1 X −(1+δ) j −(1+δ) sin (jωk ) + δ j cos (jωk ) sin (ωk ) sin2 (ωk ) j=1 j=1   ! PT +1 −(1+δ) T +1 X j sin (jω ) cos (ωk ) − 1 k j=2 +o + o j −(1+δ) cos (jωk ) . 2 sin (ωk ) sin (ωk ) j=2

+

 Using Lemma S.2, this leads, as T ωk , ωk−1 → (∞, ∞) , and since 1 + δ ∈ (0, 1) to: T X j=1

j

−δ

  1 1 cos (jωk ) = δ sin [(T + 1) ωk ] − (1 + δ) 1 + 2 T ωk δπf (0)

+

2Γ (δ + 1) cos   + o ωkδ−1 ,

(δ+1)π 2

ωkδ−1

  where T −δ ωk−1 = O ωkδ−1 k −δ . Hence T X

j −δ cos (jωk ) =

j=1

which simplifies to T δ−1

δπf (0) 2Γ (δ + 1) cos PT

j=1 j

−δ

  δ−1 δ−1 ω + o ω , k (δ+1)π k 2

cos (jωk )  k δ−1 .

6

(S–6)

2

Proof of Lemma 7

For δκ ∈ (0, 1) , δκ − 2 ∈ (−2, −1). Yong (1974), Theorems III-24 and -27, show that for δκ ∈ (0, 1) , if there exists a function S slowly varying at infinity such that aj = j δκ −2 S (j) , then ∞ X j=1 ∞ X

aj cos (jω) −

∞ X j=1

aj sin (jω)

j=1



ω→0+



π

1−δκ

ω 2Γ (2 − δk ) cos (2−δ2k )π   π 1 1−δκ . ω S (2−δk )π ω 2Γ (2 − δk ) sin 2 aj

ω→0+

  1 S ω

Define, for x ≥ 1, S (x) = κbxc / bxcδκ −2 , where bxc is the integer part of x. Then as x → ∞ and for δ ≥ 1/x, κbδxc bxcδκ −2 → 1, κ bxc bλxcδκ −2  so S is slowly varying with S ω1 → cκ as ω → 0. This implies, using κj = j δκ −2 S (j) for P j ≥ 1 and ∞ j=0 κj = κ (1) = 1, that " #  πcκ 1 1 −iω κ e −1 ∼ − +i ω 1−δκ , πδκ πδκ ω→0+ 2Γ (2 − δκ ) cos 2 sin 2   πcκ 1 ∗ i.e. the result holds for Re κ eiω − 1 setting c∗κ = 2Γ(2−δ πδκ such that cκ cκ > 0. Also, κ) S (δx) /S (x) =

cos

using

2

2     −1 1 πδκ −2 sin πδκ −2 πδκ +i sin = , = cos cos πδ2κ 2 2 2 sin πδ2κ and Γ (1 + z) = zΓ (z) together with Γ (1 − z) Γ (z) =

π sin πz ,

we obtain

2 2  1 − κ eiω 2 ∼ cκ Γ (δκ ) ω 2(1−δκ ) , (1 − δκ )2

and c∗∗ κ =

3

c2κ Γ(δκ )2 (1−δκ )2

(S–7)

> 0.

Proof of Lemma 8

Consider fy (ω) − fy (0) =

(fx (ω) − fx (0)) (1 − β)2

(1 − β)2 |1 − β + β (1 − κ (e−iω ))|2    2 2β (1 − β) Re 1 − κ e−iω + β 2 1 − κ e−iω − fx (0) , (1 − β)2 |1 − β + β (1 − κ (e−iω ))|2 7

since      1 − β + β 1 − κ e−iω 2 = (1 − β)2 − 2β (1 − β) Re κ e−iω − 1 − β 2 κ e−iω − 1 2 . Under Assumption B, |fx0 (0)| < ∞ (see Stock, 1994), so fx (ω) − fx (0) = O (ω). Now if δκ > 0, under constant learning, κj ∼ cκ j δκ −2 for some cκ 6= 0. Lemma 6 implies that there exist c∗κ 6= 0, with cκ c∗κ > 0, and c∗∗ κ > 0 such that fy (ω) − fy (0) ∼

ω→0+





ω→0+

2(1−δκ ) −2β (1 − β) fx (0) c∗κ ω 1−δκ + β 2 fx (0) c∗∗ κ ω (1 − β)4

(S–8)

2βfx (0) c∗κ 1−δκ ω . (1 − β)3

We first note that by definition of the population spectrum ( ) ∞ ∞ X 1 X 1 fy (ω) = γk e−iωk = γ0 + 2 γk cos ωk , 2π 2π k=−∞

k=1

where γk = Cov (yt , yt−k ) , is symmetric since yt is stationary. We assume for now that γk P is of bounded variation, then, for ω 6= 0, the series nk=1 γk cos ωk converges uniformly as n → ∞ (see Zygmund, 1935, Section. 1.23). It follows that the derivative of fy satisfies: fy0

∞ 1X (ω) = − kγk sin kω. π

(S–9)

k=1

We now use Theorem III-11 of Yong (1974) who works under the assumption that {ak }k∈N is a sequence of positive numbers that is quasi-monotonically convergent to zero (i.e. ak → 0  for all k ≥ k0 (M )) and that {ak } is and there exist M ≥ 0, such that ak+1 ≤ ak 1 + M k P∞ also of bounded variation, i.e. k=1 |∆ak | < ∞. The theorem states that for a ∈ (0, 1) , ak ∼ k −a S ∗ (k) as k → ∞, with S ∗ slowly varying, if and only if ∞ X k=1

π ak sin kω ∼ ω a−1 S ∗ 2Γ (a) sin πa 2

  1 as ω → 0+ . ω

We apply this theorem to (S–9), using expression (S–8) that fy0 (ω) ∞ 1X − kγk sin kω π k=1



ω→0+



2βfx (0) c∗κ −δκ ω . (1 − β)3

We let a = 1 − δκ in the theorem of Yong above, defining ak =

kγk (1 − β)3 . π 2βfx (0) c∗κ 8



ω→0+



x (0)cκ −δκ − 2βf ω (1−β)3

This implies that ak ∼ γk ∼

π 2Γ(a) sin

πa 2

κ) k −(1−δκ ) , with Γ (1 − δκ ) sin π(1−δ = 2

2πβfx (0) c∗κ Γ (δκ ) sin πδ2κ (1 − β)

3

π 2Γ(δκ ) sin

πδκ 2

, i.e.

k −(2−δκ ) .

(S–10)

To apply Theorem III-11 of Yong (1974), we check that ak thus defined is a quasi-monotonic sequence with bounded variation. The first holds since ak+1 /ak ∼ (1 + 1/k)−(1−δκ ) < 1, so choose M such that ak+1 /ak < 1 for k > M. Also kγk is clearly of bounded variation since it is asymptotically positive and   ∆ (kγk ) = O k −(2−δκ ) is summable. Finally, we check the uniform convergence condition in Zygmund (1935):  |∆γk | = O k −(3−δκ ) so γk is of bounded variation.

References Yong, C. H. (1974). Asymptotic Behaviour of Trigonometric Series. Chinese University of Hong Kong. Zygmund, A. (1935). Trigonometrical Series. Warsaw: Monografje Matematyczne V.

9

Supplementary Appendix to: Perpetual Learning and Apparent Long ...

Apr 13, 2017 - Perpetual Learning and Apparent Long Memory. Guillaume Chevillon. ESSEC Business School & CREST .... T large enough, f (2π. T n) > 0. Also for n ≤ T, n−δTδ+1 → ∞ as n → ∞. Therefore, there exist (n0 ..... where ⌊x⌋ is the integer part of x. Then as x → ∞ and for δ ≥ 1/x,. S (δx)/S (x) = κ⌊δx⌋ κ⌊x⌋.

220KB Sizes 0 Downloads 193 Views

Recommend Documents

Supplementary Appendix to: Perpetual Learning and Apparent Long ...
Apr 13, 2017 - Perpetual Learning and Apparent Long Memory. Guillaume Chevillon. ESSEC Business School & CREST. Sophocles Mavroeidis. University of ...

Perpetual Learning and Apparent Long Memory
Apr 14, 2017 - of the literature has focused on persistence at business cycle frequencies, .... defined as the solution to the minimization problem: ... The above learning algorithms can be all expressed as linear functions of past values of ..... On

Supplementary Appendix
product differentiation), Firm 2's net profit is negative (gross profit is zero, but the costs are positive). If σ = 0, the profit is zero. Moreover c2(0) = 0, which implies π2(0)−qc2(0) = π2(0) > 0. Therefore, Firm 2's net profit is increasing

Supplementary Appendix
through the institution, the pivotal member signals support, the audience supports x, and ..... For the pivotal member, there are two cases to check. Recall that D ...

Supplementary Appendix
Substitution of (43) and (44) for m ∈ {s ,0} in (23) gives: dV dp . = −(. Я(8 − 2Я − 3Я2). 8(2 − Я)(4 − Я2)(1 − Я2)2 − (1 − Я). Я(2 − Я2). (4 − Я2)2(1 − Я2)2 \E i {[E{θ |s } − θ ]2}. = −Я. 8(4 − Я2

Supplementary Appendix
Nov 15, 2017 - (a2) E∗ (BV ∗ n ) = n. ∑ i=2. (vn i−1. )1/2. (vn i ). 1/2 . (a3) V ar∗ (. √. nRV ∗ n )=2n n. ∑ i=1. (vn i ). 2 . (a4) V ar∗ (. √. nBV ∗ n ) = (k. −4. 1. − 1)n n. ∑ i=2. (vn i )(vn i−1) + 2(k−2. 1. − 1)

Supplementary Appendix to “Asymptotic Power of ...
Jun 22, 2012 - e-nf(z)g(z)dz that corresponds to a portion of K1 close to its boundary point, which in our case is z0(h). To make our exposition self-contained, we sketch Olver's derivation; for details, we refer the reader to pages. 1Here and throug

Supplementary Appendix to Coevolution of Deception ...
supplementary analysis we relax the assumption of perfect observability in matches ... Given a configuration (µ, b) and two incumbent types θ, θ , we define.

Bootstrapping high-frequency jump tests: Supplementary Appendix
Bootstrapping high-frequency jump tests: Supplementary Appendix. ∗. Prosper Dovonon. Concordia University. Sılvia Gonçalves. University of Western Ontario. Ulrich Hounyo. Aarhus University. Nour Meddahi. Toulouse School of Economics, Toulouse Uni

Appendix to Two-sided Learning and Short-Run ...
rn t = r + ut. (3) ut = ρuut-1 + εu t. (4) wt = ρwwt-1 + εw t. (5) where all the ..... can be used to solve for Γ1,t and Γ2,t; we use Sims'(2001) Gensys program for.

Supplementary Appendix of Strategic Disclosure of ...
Strategic Disclosure of Demand Information by. Duopolists: Theory and Experiment. Jos Jansen. Andreas Pollak. Aarhus University. MPI, Bonn. University of Cologne. July 2015. Supplementary Appendix: not for publication. Here we give missing proofs and

Online Appendix to: “Learning from Prices: Public ...
demand is relatively high, which generates an expansion of labor supply. The effect ..... interest rate in the financial market does not provide any new information to the workers and that the .... The following proposition accounts for all equilibri

Supplementary On-Line Appendix for “International ...
Supplementary On-Line Appendix for “International Institutions .... Std. Dev. Min. Max. No. of Obs. Source. PTA Negotiation. 0.02. 0.12. 0. 1. 4460. Authors. LeaderChange. 0.14. 0.34. 0. 1. 4460. Archigos (2009) ..... of Foreign Affairs and Trade,

APPENDIX I. VOCABULARY RELATED TO CRIME AND ...
APPENDIX I. VOCABULARY RELATED TO CRIME AND PUNISHMENT.pdf. APPENDIX I. VOCABULARY RELATED TO CRIME AND PUNISHMENT.pdf. Open.

Finding Perpetual Beta.pdf
fundamental changes in networked society,. business, and education. Harold Jarche. R E F L E C T I O N S. ON THE NETWORK ERA. finding perpetual beta.

Demonstrations, experiments and supplementary notes to motivate ...
predictive and modeling aspects of differential equations. Our institution is the ... We try to make the course very relevant to the students. 2. The experiments.

Demonstrations, experiments and supplementary notes to motivate ...
after making those “unrealistic assumptions” the model still yielded important ... Experimental setup: We bought a spring from our local Pep-Boys (auto shop) ...

Online Appendix to
Online Appendix to. Zipf's Law for Chinese Cities: Rolling Sample ... Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, eds. V. Henderson, J.F. Thisse, 4:2341-78.

Online Appendix to
The model that controls the evolution of state z can be written as zt. = µz .... Members of survey A think of the signal θA as their own, but can observe both.

Online Appendix to
Sep 27, 2016 - data by applying the pruning procedure by Kim et al. .... “Risk Matters: The Real Effects of Volatility Shocks,” American ... accurate solutions of discrete time dynamic equilibrium models,” Journal of Economic Dynamics &.

Online Appendix to
Nov 3, 2016 - 0.03. 0.03. 0.03. 0.02. 0.04. 0.04. 0.04. 0.04. Note . Robust standard errors b et w een paren theses, r ob us t-standard-error-based. p-v alues b et w een brac k ets. ∆. Cr e d is the gro w th rate of real lending b y domestic banks

Perpetual Preservation System
name indicates the macro elements are needed in much larger quantities by ... are and accordingly we dose the micronutrients separately and usually in much ...

Goats, birds, and emergent diseases: apparent and ...
INTRODUCTION. A wide array of anthropogenic pressures including .... unpublished data), and this large-scale sampling allowed us to confirm that the ... Transects were separated by sufficient distance (!500 m) to avoid ..... other continental species